Next Article in Journal
R&D Investment, Internal Control and Enterprise Performance—An Empirical Study Based on the Listed Companies in China of the Core Industry of the Digital Economy
Next Article in Special Issue
Long-Term Leases vs. One-Off Purchases: Game Analysis on Battery Swapping Mode Considering Cascade Utilization and Power Structure
Previous Article in Journal
Thermal Comfort Improvement with Passive Design Strategies in Child Development Centers in Thailand
Previous Article in Special Issue
Research on Extension Design of Emergency Cold Chain Logistics from the Perspective of Carbon Constraints
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Optimal Recycling Channel Selection of Power Battery Closed-Loop Supply Chain Considering Corporate Social Responsibility in China

1
Business School, Hohai University, Nanjing 211100, China
2
College of Economics and Management, Nanjing University of Aeronautics and Astronautics, Nanjing 211106, China
3
College of Economics and Management, Guangxi Normal University, Guilin 541004, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2022, 14(24), 16712; https://doi.org/10.3390/su142416712
Submission received: 14 November 2022 / Revised: 10 December 2022 / Accepted: 11 December 2022 / Published: 13 December 2022

Abstract

:
With economic development and societal progress, the supply chain should not only focus on profitability, but also environmental protection, as well as undertake corresponding corporate social responsibility (CSR). The operational decisions of the closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) in the power battery industry should rather consider the impact of CSR. Thus, this paper studies the optimal recycling channel selection and coordination of CLSC in the power battery industry under the consideration of CSR efforts and uncertain demand. By considering the CSR efforts taken by the manufacturer, decentralized and coordination decision-making models under different recycling modes (including manufacturer recycling, retailer recycling and third-party recycling) are constructed to analyze the optimal decision of CLSC. After that, the models were validated through numerical and sensitivity analysis, followed by discussion and management insights. It is found that when consumers are sensitive to the level of CSR effort, CSR effort has a positive impact on the profits of participants in CLSC. Additionally, the coordination decision-making model always outperforms the decentralized decision-making model under the same recycling mode, so reasonable profit-sharing contracts are developed to ensure the implementation of coordination decision-making. Moreover, transfer price plays different roles in different decision situations and recycling modes, while recycling cost is critical to the overall profit of the supply chain and influences the choice of recycling channel.

1. Introduction

Consumer demand for upgraded products is leading to faster product iteration and a shorter product life cycle. As a result, it causes a vast amount of waste products, introducing severe resource and environmental issues to society. Therefore, how to effectively deal with waste products is of increasing concern. To break through the limitation of resources and to relieve environmental pressure, the closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) has emerged, which has received strong support from governments and communities across many countries. Remanufacturing is an important part of CLSC management, and effective remanufacturing technology could save up to 70% of raw materials and 60% of energy usage in industrial enterprises [1], maximizing the usage of waste products, improving resource utilization, and alleviating the pressure between resources, the environment, and economic benefits [2,3]. Governments have designed policies to guide enterprises to implement CLSC management, such as the Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE) introduced in Europe and other WEEE-like legislations launched in Japan and Canada [4]. Meanwhile, many companies have participated in recycling and remanufacturing activities of waste products, such as Apple [5], Fuji Xerox [6], Dell, Sony [7], GM and Ford [8].
In China, to meet the need for sustainable development, in recent years, the Chinese government intensively designed a series of policies related to recycling waste products, such as the “Circular Development Leads Action” released in 2017 (NDRC, 2017) [9] and policies targeting on recycling specific types of products. Through these efforts, the Chinese government expected to promote the establishment of recycling systems in various industries and motivate more enterprises to carry out recycling responsibility actions, especially for emerging industries. As one of the typical representatives of emerging industries, the new energy vehicle (NEV) industry in China is booming. The NEV ownership exceeded 7.991 million at the end of 2021, achieving a year-on-year growth of 62%, and it might exceed 32 million in 2025 by prediction, according to the data from the China Association of Automobile Manufacturers. Currently, the majority of NEV are electronic vehicles (EVs). As the power battery is one of the curial components of EVs, its market demand also grows rapidly. According to a report by the China Automotive Battery Innovation Alliance, the loading capacity for power batteries in China exceeded 154 GWh in 2021, and the estimated capacity may reach 770 GWh in 2025. Currently, the lifespans of power batteries are around five to seven years, and for safety and efficiency reasons, the general requirement is that the capacity of power batteries needs to be kept above 80% of the original capacity [10,11]. With the continuous surge in the number of EVs, the sharp increase in the number of retired power batteries is foreseeable, and some predicted that the retired power batteries in the Chinese market may reach 7.08 million tons by 2030 [12]. Unlike many other products, the improper disposal of waste power batteries can pose a serious threat to water, soil and human beings, which means the recycling of power batteries is closely related to environmental pollution and resource consumption issues. Thus, to deal with the power battery retirement tide, it is essential to establish suitable modes for waste power battery recycling and remanufacturing, which requires the common efforts of supply chain participants.
At present, there are different recycling models in China’s EV power battery market. For example, by merging Brunp Recycling, which is a Chinese company with leading battery automatic recovery technology and equipment, the power battery giant manufacturer CATL selects the direct recycling method for power batteries. As another example, by utilizing the sales network of retailers across China, BYD cooperates with retailers, assigning retailers to conduct recycling testing of waste power batteries, and remanufacturing qualified waste power batteries by BYD itself. In addition, some other power battery manufacturers choose to collaborate with professional recycling companies such as China Tower, Tele Recycle and GEM, entrusting these third parties with recycling waste power batteries. The interests of the whole supply chain and participants are associated with the recycling models [13]. Additionally, the recycling price, recovery rate, and retail price of power batteries may differ under different recycling models, which could affect the recycling and remanufacturing activities and interests of participants and the whole supply chain. Moreover, in practice, most participants often put their own interests as priority, so it is prone to inconsistencies in the benefit allocation among participants. In turn, it could affect the efficiency of the power battery supply chain and even the smooth running of recycling activities. Based on these facts, it indicates that the Chinese power battery industry faces problems such as a disorderly recycling system and the low efficiency of recycling, and there is an imperative need to establish a more efficient and sustainable power battery recycling system. Therefore, the choice of model to maximize the overall interests of the supply chain and ensure the interests of all participants is key to decision-making.
In additional to factors such as sales volume and recovery rate, some other factors might also affect recycling and remanufacturing activities of the supply chain. In recent years, problems of corporate social responsibility (CSR) deficiency have aroused widespread public concern, as environment pollution, non-conforming products and safety risks have occurred frequently [14]. Years ago, the revealing of the unethical labor problems and business activities of Nike and Adidas caused consumer boycotts and reputation damage [15]. In this context, CSR received growing attention from both academics and industries, so an increasing number of enterprises started to be involved in socially responsible activities [16], and integrated CSR into their own supply chains such as Nike, Gap, and McDonald’s [17]. In China, since the manufacturing and recycling of EV power batteries are closely related to environmental issues, the CSR performances of related enterprises receive significant attention from the society. In fact, some Chinese power battery manufacturers are implementing CSR activities. For example, CATL spent hundreds of millions of CNY on CSR activities in the first half of 2022, such as promoting industrial development in Qinghai, supporting education revitalization and scientific cooperation with Sichuan University, and contributing to social welfare activities through poverty alleviation and tree planting (according to CATL 2022H1 Report). However, there has been disagreement about the impact of CSR on enterprises, not to mention how the CSR activities carried by power battery manufacturing companies will have an impact on CLSC. Thus, incorporating CSR into the decision-making model of CLSC is a meaningful research direction.
This study focuses on the CSR effort in CLSC of power battery industry and considers product recycling in different situations to analyze the optimal decision when the CSR effort is carried out by manufacturers. Therefore, the following questions need to be addressed:
(a) The impact of recycling models on the decisions and benefits of CLSC, and what is the optimal recycling model? (b) What are the critical factors hindering optimal decisions, and how to determine the optimal decision? (c) How does the CSR impact the CLSC, and in the context of CSR activities, how does the CSR effort carried by manufacturers affect the outcome of equilibrium?
This paper tries to solve the above research questions and provide an effective idea for the implementation of recycling activities of CLSC in the Chinese power battery industry and might be valuable for the implementation of recycling activities in other industries.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature and describes the main work of this paper. Section 3 constructs decentralized decision-making models and coordination decision models under different recycling modes and provides a comparative analysis of the models. Section 4 contains the numerical and sensitivity analysis. Section 5 introduces the discussion and management insights. Section 6 concludes the main findings of this paper and discusses limitations and future research directions.

2. Literature Reviews

In recent years, sustainability has become one of the biggest problems for businesses globally. Due to the non-sustainability of many resources and environmental complexity, the sustainability of the business environment has received great attention. A variety of sustainable development practices have occurred, such as green procurement, green manufacturing, environmental design, pollution control, remanufacturing and recycling, where recycling plays an essential role in waste management [17]. CLSC integrates the remanufacturing and concept of sustainability into the supply chain and remanufactured products through certain technologies for reusing end-life products, realizing a closed-loop structure of “product—consumption—recycling and remanufacturing—product” [18]. Several scholars elaborated on the concept and characteristics of the CLSC [19]. The CLSC consists of two channels, the forward channel provides new products to meet customer needs, and the reverse channel recycles waste products for remanufacturing [20]. In fact, the reverse channel is a unique feature of CLSC, and it is also an effective way to accomplish circular economy objectives [21]. Remanufacturing has become a major concern for businesses and academics, with a focus on collection and reuse.
Existing research on CLSC has mainly focused on pricing decisions, the power structures of the channel and the choice of recycling channel [1]. Pricing is a key issue in the field of CLSC research, and channel participants who become leaders often receive more interest [22]. Ranjbar et al. [23] explored optimal pricing and recycling decisions for CLSC in the retail channel under different channel leaders, where retailers and third-party participants competed to recycle waste products. The choice of recycling channel may significantly affect the profit of the channel participants [24]. Savaskan et al. [25] first proposed that the reverse channel structure included manufacturer recycling, retailer recycling and third-party recycling, so that in the CLSC manufacturers can recycle waste products by themselves or assign recycling works to retailers or third parties. Some of the literature suggested that manufacturer recycling could generate more profits, and when the earnings of the recycling process were higher, manufacturers preferred direct recycling [26]. Zheng et al. [27] discussed the decision-making for the solo choice of recycling channel in a dual-channel CLSC and proved that it was optimal for manufacturers to recycle by themselves. However, some other literature proposed the opposite view, arguing that retailers or third parties had advantages in recycling waste products [28]. For example, Savaskan et al. [25] indicated the better overall performance of CLSC when retailers recycle waste products. Hong et al. [29] constructed a CLSC model of three recycling channels, and their findings were consistent with Savaskan et al. [25]. Moreover, influenced by factors such as economies of scale and fixed investment, in practice, the cost of recycling waste products by manufacturers or retailers was often higher than the cost of third-party recyclers. Therefore, the third-party recycling channel was indispensable and common in practice [8].
For the CLSC system, depending on the decisive factors, the choice of either manufacturer recycling or retailer recycling may be the best option. Miao et al. [30] built up a decision model of CLSC for retailer recycling and manufacturer recycling and showed that the retailer recycling model was optimal in the view of the interests of retailers, while the manufacturer recycling model was optimal in the view of the interests of manufacturers and the overall system. Hong et al. [29] indicated that, in terms of the recovery rate, the profit of manufacturers and the overall channel, retailers did not always perform better than third parties when they were in charge. In addition, there were other studies on the decision-making of recycling channels, such as quality management [31], dual-channel CLSC [32] and CSR.
As increasing numbers of consumers have become concerned about CSR, the level of CSR has become a new area of competitiveness for enterprises [33]. Bowen [34] first proposed the concept of CSR and stated that enterprises should not only pursue economic benefits, but also focus on their own behaviors. CSR was defined as assuming corporate responsibility beyond shareholder value to satisfy the expectations of broader stakeholders and society [9,16]. For the supply chain, supply chain social responsibility has been intensively studied by researchers from the perspectives of recovery rates, rebate mechanisms and sales incentives [35]. Some others discussed whether CSR activities could affect enterprise performance through pathways such as brand value, reputation and customer awareness [36]. There has been disagreement about the impact of CSR on enterprises. Some researchers suggested that the market value of enterprises could increase by reducing the costs and risks and enhanced reputation when enterprises engaged in CSR activities [37]. However, some others argued that engaging in CSR activities could weaken the financial performance of enterprises due to wasted resources [38]. Related research showed that whether an enterprise undertaking CSR has a significant impact on consumers’ product choices [39]. Performing CSR activities could lead to positive consumer responses and feedback [40], and could imply a higher standard of product quality and service [41]. The CSR efforts of enterprises could increase their short-term costs. However, in the long run, the level of their CSR efforts would spread in public opinion, which could affect their reputation and the demand for products directly, leading to a positive impact on their profits [9]. Taking an active role in CSR would not distract the efforts of enterprises. On the contrary, it could help increase the value of enterprises [42]. Indeed, CSR practices could not only affect the operation of the forward supply chain, but also have a positive impact on waste recycling in the reverse supply chain [1].
In the CLSC network, there were many independent decision-makers who were at different streams in the supply chain and involved in different business activities. The decisions that those decision-makers made were on behalf of their own business interests [43]. In the meantime, the profit distribution of the channel was not only related to factors such as channel leadership and market demand, but also depended on the cost and efficiency of waste products recycling [44]. Game theory was treated as a mathematical tool to study the complex relationship between rational participants in the competitive environment [45]. It has been widely used in supply chain management to make equilibrium decisions in recent years [46]. Ma et al. [47] compared the optimal decision-making under four different recycling models after expanding the recycling channels for waste products. Ghasemzadeh et al. [48] used a game theory model to select the optimal path of recycling by analyzing a two-level reverse supply chain consisting of one manufacturer and one retailer. By applying fuzzy theory and game theory approaches, Karimabadi et al. [49] studied the optimal decision-making of wholesale price, optimal price and direct price under the centralized decision-making model and decentralized decision-making model, respectively, without considering third-party recycling.
It has been observed that the profit of the supply chain can be higher under a centralized decision-making model than that under a decentralized decision-making model, and how to appropriately coordinate participants in the supply chain is a challenge of the supply chain management [50]. Different supply chain systems try to develop certain strategies to achieve the coordination of members, such as pricing strategy, sales rebates, or revenue-sharing contract [51]. Ghosh studied the coordination in pricing strategy of two participants in a two-echelon supply chain, and showed that the joint decision of the manufacturer and retailer brought a higher profit of the supply chain and lowered the sales price [52]. The revenue-sharing contract was also treated as a common coordination mechanism of the supply chain [53], which could improve the profits of all members in the supply chain through reasonable revenue-sharing contracts [54,55]. Zhou studied the coordination issue of the green supply chain and showed that the revenue-sharing contract could improve the greenness and the market demand [56]. Li studied how the profitability of enterprises was affected by revenue-sharing and cost-sharing contracts, and found that the value ranges were highly dependent on the parameter setting [57]. In additional, the coordination of members in the supply chain may also improve the CSR efforts of the overall supply chain [58]. Hosseini-Motlagh studied the coordination in a manufacturer–retailer supply chain through the cost-sharing contract, in which the manufacturer undertook the social responsibility and invested in CSR activities [59].
In fact, in most cases, manufacturers are in the leading position for the channel and have higher market powers than other participants, so they are capable of affecting the decisions of others in the supply chain, but they also bear more pressure of CSR as core enterprises [60]. In practice, CSR efforts are often carried out by manufacturers. At the same time, the presence of many participants in the supply chain, the existence of diverse recycling models, the extreme dispersion of end users and the huge amount of information mean that the recycling cost is one of the decisive factors for recycling activities. Moreover, since there is still disagreement on the impact of manufacturers’ CSR efforts on the decision-making of CLSC, scientific recycling methods are needed for the power battery industry to solve recycling problems.
This paper studies a CLSC consisting of one manufacturer, one retailer and one third-party recycler. By considering CSR effort and uncertain demand, under three recycler recycling modes, six decision-making models are constructed in decentralized and centralized decision situations. By applying the idea of game theory, optimal decisions and the optimal level of CSR effort of all models are obtained. After that, through the numerical and sensitivity analysis, the decision-making models are verified and discussed. From the perspectives of the overall profit of the supply chain and the interests of individual participants, the optimal recycling model is discussed, and management insights are suggested. Moreover, social responsibility decisions made by the manufacturer via CSR efforts are analyzed as well.

3. Models

Based on the decision objectives and behaviors of the participants in CLSC recycling practice, for three recycler recycling modes, in the decentralized and centralized decision situations, the corresponding decentralized decision-making model and coordination decision-making model are constructed, respectively; specifically, as shown in Figure 1, for manufacturer recycling, Model M and Model M-C represent the models under decentralized and centralized decision situations, respectively. For retailer recycling, Model R and Model R-C represent the models under decentralized and centralized decision situations, respectively. For third party recycling, Model TP and Model TP-C represent the models under decentralized and centralized decision situations, respectively. In the decentralized decision situation, each participant in CLSC is seen as an independent decision-maker. In contrast, in the centralized decision situation, all of the participants in CLSC are considered to be one decision-maker, and the common target is to maximize the overall profit. In addition, to study the optimal decisions of these six models, this paper also compares the optimal decisions of models with CSR efforts and without CSR efforts. For clarity, the major notations used throughout this paper are summarized in Table 1 before analysis.

3.1. Model Assumptions

There are three problems that need to be solved. Firstly, it is necessary to explore how the reverse channel selection affects the wholesale price, retail price and total profit of CLSC. Secondly, it is essential to discover how the recovery rate of waste products is affected by the structure of CLSC. Thirdly, how optimal decisions are affected by CSR activities. It requires some constraints before model construction. Therefore, the necessary model assumptions are proposed as follows:
Assumption 1.
The unit cost of producing a new product from waste products is less than the unit cost of producing a new product directly from raw materials, namely C r < C n , C r = C n Δ . At the same time, for the manufacturer, there is b Δ , which means that the unit recycling cost should not be higher than the unit cost saved by processing a waste product into a new product.
Assumption 2.
Let τ denote the recovery rate of waste products from consumers, where 0 τ 1 . Here, τ is a function of the product recycling effort, and the recycling effort is defined as the investment scale, denoted as I. This assumes that τ = I / C L , where CL is the scale parameter.
According to Assumption 2, the total recovery cost function is: C ( τ ) = I + A j τ D ( p , e ) = C L τ 2 + A j τ D ( p , e ) .
Assumption 3.
The demand function D ( p , e ) = ϕ β p + λ e is a function of sales price and the level of CSR effort, where ϕ is the potential market demand, ϕ > 0 , β > 0 , and ϕ > β p , ensuring that the market demand is non-negative. The manufacturer is often the core enterprise in the power battery supply chain with considerable capital and scale. Additionally, the potential environmental and social hazards of power batteries mainly come from the production practices of the manufacturer, and the remanufacturing activities of power batteries are operated by the manufacturer regardless of the recycling models. Therefore, the CSR effort is undertaken by the manufacturer, and the cost of investment in CSR is 1 2 θ e 2 [61,62].
Assumption 4.
Assuming that a supply chain is composed of one manufacturer and one retailer and that one third-party recycler will be involved when needed. If a retailer conducts waste product recycling, the retailer can determine the amount of recycled waste products based on the recycling price of the waste products. Moreover, the active level of the retailer regarding recycling waste products will directly affect the average cost of the product.
Assumption 5.
In all of the supply chain models, the manufacturer has the sufficient capacity of channels to select the recycler, and no information asymmetry exists within any participant in the supply chain.
Assumption 6.
Parameter CL is assumed to be large enough so that τ < 1 ; that is, 4 C L > β θ ϕ β C n Δ A j + β 2 θ Δ A j 2 4 β θ 2 λ 2 . This assumption is to ensure that the cost of recycling will be huge when the manufacturer recycles all of its products.

3.2. Model Construction in Different Decision Situations When the Manufacturer Recycling

3.2.1. Decentralized Decision-Making Model—Model M

In Model M, the manufacturer undertakes the recycling of waste products directly from the consumers and takes CSR so that the manufacturer determines the wholesale price w, the unit cost of recycling and the storage of waste product A M , recovery rate τ, and level of CSR effort e. In this situation, the manufacturer is the dominator of the supply chain; the goal is to maximize its own profit. As a follower of the CLSC, the retailer determines the retail price p. Thus, the profit functions of participants in the CLSC are:
R M = ϕ β p + λ e p w
M M = ϕ β p + λ e w C n + τ Δ τ A M C L τ 2 1 2 θ e 2
The steps of the calculation are in Appendix A (a), and the optimal decisions are:
w M = 4 ϕ θ C L + 4 β C n θ C L ϕ β θ Δ A M 2 2 C n C L λ 2 8 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2          e M = 2 λ C L ϕ β C n 8 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2           τ M = β θ ϕ β C n Δ A M 8 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2
p M = 6 ϕ θ C L + 2 β C n θ C L ϕ β θ Δ A M 2 2 C n C L λ 2 8 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2
Bringing the above optimal decision results into Equations (1) and (2), we can obtain the optimal profit for the retailer, the manufacturer and the whole supply chain in Model M:
M M = θ C L ϕ β C n 2 8 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2          R M = 4 β θ 2 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 8 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2 2
T M = θ C L 12 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2 ϕ β C n 2 8 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2 2

3.2.2. Coordination Decision-Making Model—Model M-C

Unlike Model M, Model M-C is a coordination decision-making model. Although the manufacturer and retailer assume the same roles, these two participants are treated as one decision-maker in this situation. Here, the goal is to maximize the overall profit of the supply chain, and the profit function of the overall supply chain in this model is:
T j C = ϕ β p + λ e p C n + τ Δ τ A j C L τ 2 1 2 θ e 2
The steps of calculation are in Appendix A (b). Here, in Model M-C, A j = A M , j C = M C , so that the optimal decisions are:
p M C = 2 ϕ θ C L + 2 β C n θ C L ϕ β θ Δ A M 2 2 C n C L λ 2 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2        e M C = 2 λ C L ϕ β C n 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2
τ M C = β θ ϕ β C n Δ A M 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2
Bringing the above optimal decision results into Equation (5), we can obtain the optimal profit of the overall supply chain in Model M-C:
T M C = θ C L ϕ β C n 2 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2
Comparing Equations (4) and (7), it is found that T M C > T M , which means in the view of overall profit of supply chain, with manufacturer recycling, the coordination decision-making model outperforms the decentralized decision-making one. The reason for that is decentralized decision-making can lead to double marginalization in CLSC so that the decision-making of each participant cannot achieve the optimum of CLSC. Therefore, it is essential to further explore the profit-sharing contract for the coordination decision-making model so that the profits of both participants can be reasonably distributed and the loss caused by the double marginalization can be eliminated. Furthermore, it can achieve the improvement of the overall profit of CLSC, while the profit of each participant can also be improved.
According to the idea of profit-sharing, in the situation of a coordination decision when the manufacturer is recycling, it assumes that the retailer shares 1 α 1 its profit with the manufacturer so that the proportion of the profit that the retailer keeps will be α 1 , where α 1 0 , 1 . In such a contract, the profit functions of the retailer and manufacturer are:
R M C = α 1 ϕ β p + λ e p w
M M C = ϕ β p + λ e w C n + τ Δ τ A M C L τ 2 1 2 θ e 2 + 1 α 1 ϕ β p + λ e p w
The steps of the calculation are in Appendix A (b), and the optimal decisions are:
w M C = 4 β C n θ C L 2 C n C L λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A M 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A M 2
R M C = 4 α 1 β θ 2 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A M 2 2
M M C = θ C L ϕ β C n 2 4 β θ C L 1 α 1 β 2 θ Δ A M 2 2 λ 2 C L 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A M 2 2
The following conditions need to be met: M M C > M M and R M C > R M , in order to ensure that both participants in the CLSC are willing to accept the contract above, and the corresponding value range of α 1 can be obtained.

3.3. Model Construction in Different Decision Situations When the Retailer Recycling

3.3.1. Decentralized Decision-Making Model—Model R

In Model R, the retailer sells new products to consumers and collects waste products from consumers. For wasted products recycled by the retailer, the manufacturer offers a transfer price b to buy back from the retailer, and b Δ . In this situation, the retailer determines the retail price p, the recovery rate τ, and the unit cost of recycling and storage of waste product A R , while the manufacturer determines the wholesale price w, the transfer price b, and the level of CSR effort e. Thus, the profit functions of the participants in CLSC are:
R R = ϕ β p + λ e p w + τ b τ A R C L τ 2
M R = ϕ β p + λ e w C n + τ Δ τ b 1 2 θ e 2
The steps of the calculation are in Appendix A (c), and the optimal decisions are:
w R = 4 θ C L ϕ + β C n 2 C n C L λ 2 + ϕ θ β b A R b + A R C n θ β 2 b A R 2 2 ϕ β Δ θ b A R 2 [ C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R b A R ]
e R = λ C L ϕ β C n C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R b A R
p R = C L 3 ϕ θ + β C n θ C n λ 2 ϕ θ β Δ A R b A R C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R b A R
τ R = θ β ϕ β C n b A R 2 [ C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R b A R ]
Bringing the above optimal decision results into Equations (11) and (12), we can obtain the optimal profit for the retailer and the manufacturer in Model R:
R R = β C L θ 2 ϕ β C n 2 [ 4 C L β b A R 2 ] 4 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R b A R 2
M R = θ C L ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R b A R
The profits of the manufacturer and retailer are the increasing functions of b, when b = A R , both parties reach their own maximum profits. Here, the optimal overall profit of the supply chain is:
T R = θ C L 12 β θ C L θ β 2 b A R 2 Δ + b 3 A R 2 C L λ 2 ϕ β C n 2 4 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R b A R 2

3.3.2. Coordination Decision-Making Model—Model R-C

Consistent with Model M-C, Model R-C is a coordination decision-making model, which means two participants are treated as one decision maker as well, so that the profit function of the overall supply chain is the same as Equation (5), and the steps of calculation are consistent with steps in Section 3.2.2 (which are in Appendix A (b)). Here, in Model R-C, A j = A R , j C = R C , so that optimal decisions are:
p R C = 2 ϕ θ C L + 2 β C n θ C L ϕ β θ Δ A R 2 2 C n C L λ 2 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A R 2 2 C L λ 2
e R C = 2 λ C L ϕ β C n 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A R 2 2 C L λ 2
τ R C = β θ ϕ β C n Δ A R 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A R 2 2 C L λ 2
T R C = θ C L ϕ β C n 2 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A R 2 2 C L λ 2
Comparing Equations (15) and (16), it is found that T R C > T R , which means in the view of overall profit of supply chain, consistent with manufacturer recycling, when retailer recycling, the coordination decision-making model outperforms the decentralized decision-making one. Therefore, it is also necessary to explore the profit-sharing contract in the case of retailer recycling, which makes a reasonable profit distribution between the manufacturer and the retailer.
In the situation of a coordination decision when the retailer performs recycling, similar to the coordination process in Section 3.2.2, here, it assumes that the retailer shares 1 α 2 of its profit with the manufacturer so that the proportion of profit that retailer keeps will be α 2 , where α 2 0 , 1 . In such a contract, the profit functions of the retailer and manufacturer are:
R R C = α 2 ϕ β p + λ e p w + τ b τ A R C L τ 2
M R C = ϕ β p + λ e w C n + τ Δ τ b 1 2 θ e 2                + 1 α 2 ϕ β p + λ e p w + τ b τ A R C L τ 2
The steps of the calculation are in Appendix A (b), and the optimal decisions are:
w R C = 4 β C n θ C L 2 C n C L λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A R 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2
b R C = A R
R R C = α 2 β θ 2 C L 4 C L β Δ A R 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 2
M R C = θ C L 4 β θ C L 1 α 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 1 α 2 2 λ 2 C L ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 2
The following conditions need to be met: M R C > M R , and R R C > R R , in order to ensure that both participants in CLSC are willing to accept the contract above, and the corresponding value range of α 2 can be obtained.

3.4. Model Construction in Different Decision Situations When the Third-Party Recycling

3.4.1. Decentralized Decision-Making Model—Model TP

In Model TP, the manufacturer commissions the professional third-party company to carry out the recycling task, and the manufacturer offers a transfer price b to third party. The investment scale of recycling decided by the third-party company can determine the recovery rate. Thus, in this situation, the third-party company determines the recovery rate τ and the unit cost of recycling and the storage of waste product A T P , while the manufacturer determines the wholesale price w, the transfer price b, and the level of CSR effort e. At this time, the retailer is the follower of CLSC, which can only determine the retail price p. Thus, the profit functions of the participants in CLSC are:
R T P = ϕ β p + λ e p w
T P T P = ϕ β p + λ e τ b A T P C L τ 2
M T P = ϕ β p + λ e w C n + τ Δ τ b 1 2 θ e 2
The steps of the calculation are in Appendix A (d), and the optimal decisions are:
w T P = C L 2 ϕ θ + 2 β C n θ C n λ 2 ϕ θ β Δ b b A T P C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ b b A T P
e T P = λ C L ϕ β C n C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ b b A T P
p T P = C L 3 ϕ θ + β C n θ C n λ 2 ϕ θ β Δ b b A T P C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ b b A T P
τ T P = β θ ϕ β C n b A T P 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ b b A T P
Bringing the above optimal decision results into Equations (20)–(22), we can obtain the optimal profit for the retailer, the third party, the manufacturer, and the overall supply chain in Model TP:
R T P = β C L 2 θ 2 ϕ β C n 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ b b A T P 2
T P T P = C L β 2 θ 2 ϕ β C n 2 b A T P 2 4 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ b b A T P 2
M T P = C L θ ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ b b A T P
T T P = θ C L ϕ β C n 2 12 β θ C L + θ β 2 b A T P 3 b 2 Δ A T P 2 C L λ 2 4 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ b b A T P 2
To maximize M T P , the denominator must be minimized, which means to maximize Δ b b A T P . When b = Δ + A T P / 2 , the profit of the manufacturer is the highest. If the manufacturer offers a higher b, it will motivate the third party to expand the scale of the recovery investment, thereby increasing the recovery rate. However, under this condition, the cost savings from recycling and remanufacturing of the manufacturer is reduced, that is, Δ b is reduced. Thus, only when b = Δ + A T P / 2 can the manufacturer and the third party both reach their own maximum profits through recycling and remanufacturing.
Based on the analysis above, there are different meanings of transfer price b in Model R and Model TP. In Model R, by controlling b, the final quantity demanded of the product can be determined. Whereas in Model TP, b is the direct cost to the manufacturer and supply chain. Therefore, the choice of the manufacturer determines with whom and how to share the cost savings from the remanufacturing of waste products, which is related to the pricing decision of the supply chain.

3.4.2. Coordination Decision-Making Model—Model TP-C

Consistent with Model M-C and Model R-C, Model TP-C is a coordination decision-making model, which means that the three participants are treated as one decision-maker as well. Thus, for Model TP-C, the profit function of the overall supply chain is the same as Equation (5), and the steps of calculation are consistent with steps in Section 3.2.2 (which are in Appendix A (b)). Here, in Model TP-C, A j = A T P , j C = T P C , so that the optimal decisions are:
p T P C = 2 ϕ θ C L + 2 β C n θ C L ϕ β θ Δ A T P 2 2 C n C L λ 2 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A T P 2 2 C L λ 2
e T P C = 2 λ C L ϕ β C n 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A T P 2 2 C L λ 2
τ T P C = β θ ϕ β C n Δ A T P 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A T P 2 2 C L λ 2
T T P C = θ C L ϕ β C n 2 4 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A T P 2 2 C L λ 2
Comparing Equations (24) and (25), it is found that T T P C > T T P , which means in view of the overall profit of the supply chain, consistent with manufacturer recycling and retailer recycling, when third-party recycling, the coordination decision-making model also outperforms the decentralized decision-making one. Therefore, it is also necessary to explore the profit-sharing contract in the case of third-party recycling, which makes a reasonable profit distribution between the manufacturer, retailer and third party.
In the situation of a coordination decision when third-party recycling, similar to the coordination process in Section 3.2.2 and Section 3.3.2, firstly, it assumes that the retailer shares 1 α 3 its profits with the manufacturer, so that the proportion of profit that the retailer keeps will be α 3 , where α 3 0 , 1 . Secondly, in this case, the manufacturer shares its profit with the third party. It assumes that the manufacturer shares 1 γ of its profit with the third party, so that the proportion of the profit that the manufacturer keeps will be γ , where γ 0 , 1 . In such a contract, the profit functions of the three participants are:
R T P C = α 3 ϕ β p + λ e p w
M T P C = γ ϕ β p + λ e w C n + τ Δ τ b + 1 α 3 ϕ β p + λ e p w 1 2 θ e 2
T P T P C = ϕ β p + λ e τ b A T P C L τ 2                + 1 + γ ϕ β p + λ e p C n + τ Δ τ b α 3 p + α 3 w 1 2 θ e 2
The steps of the calculation are in Appendix A (b), and the optimal decisions are:
w T P C = 4 β C n θ C L 2 C n C L λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A T P 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2
b T P C = A T P
R T P C = 4 α 3 β θ 2 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2
M T P C = 2 γ θ C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 β θ 1 α 3 λ 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2
T P T P C = θ C L ϕ β C n 2 4 β θ C L 1 α 3 1 γ 2 λ 2 C L 1 γ β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2
The following conditions need to be met: M T P C > M T P , R T P C > R T P , and T P T P C > T P T P , in order to ensure that the three participants in CLSC are willing to accept the contract above and that the corresponding value ranges of α 3 and γ can be obtained.

3.5. Model Comparison in Different Decision Situations

3.5.1. Comparison of Decision-Making Models with CSR Effort in CLSC

After obtaining the optimal product retail prices, the optimal wholesale prices, the optimal level of CSR effort, the optimal recovery rates and the maximum profit of all participants and the overall supply chain, the results of the six models are compared as shown in Table 2.
Based on analysis in Table 2, the following conclusions can be drawn:
1. In each recycling mode, the relationship of the overall profits of the supply chain satisfies: T M C > T M , T R C > T R ,   T T P C > T T P .
2. In each recycling mode, the relationship of the recovery rates satisfies: τ M C > τ M ,   τ R C > τ R ,   τ M C > τ M .
3. In each recycling mode, the relationship of the retail prices satisfies: p M C < p M ,   p R C < p R ,   p M C < p M .
4. In each recycling mode, the relationship of the levels of CSR effort satisfies: e M C > e M ,   e R C > e R ,   e T P C > e T P .
5. In three coordination decision-making models, the relationship of the overall profits of the supply chain satisfies: T T P C > T R C > T M C , the relationship of the recovery rates satisfies: τ T T P C > τ T R C > τ T M C , the relationship of the retail prices satisfies: p T T P C < p T R C < p T M C , the relationship of the levels of CSR effort satisfies: e T T P C > e T R C > e T M C , and the relationship of the wholesale prices satisfies: w T P C < w R C < w M C .
According to Conclusions 1–4, it can be found that in each recycling mode, the coordination decision-making model is better than the decentralized decision-making model. Specifically, in coordination decision-making models, retail prices are lower and the recovery rates, levels of CSR effort, market demands and the overall profits of CLSC are higher. These results confirm the previous analysis of the double marginalization existing under decentralized decision-making. The double marginalization causes the overall profit of CLSC to be impaired, while participants under coordination decision-making are treated as a whole and pursue the maximization of the overall benefit, which will promote the financial gain (from the perspective of profit) and environmental benefits (from the perspective of recovery rate) of the supply chain. In the situation of coordination decision, if a reasonable profit-sharing contract is established, the interests of all participants involved will also be guaranteed, resulting in a win–win situation for all participants and CLSC.
Based on Conclusion 5, under the condition of A T P < A R < A M , among the three coordination decision-making models, the overall profit of the supply chain and product recovery rate are highest with the third-party recycling. Furthermore, the retail price is lowest, and the level of CSR effort and the demand are greatest. From this result, it follows that the third-party recycling coordination decision-making model could improve not only the efficiency of waste products recycling, but also increase product volume sales.
Further analysis shows that the level of CSR effort has the same trend as the recovery rate and profit. When consumers are sensitive to the level of CSR effort, making higher CSR investments allows the manufacturer and other participants to earn extra financial gains, and the recovery rate of CLSC can be improved. In addition, among the three models under coordination decision-making, when third-party recycling, the cost saving from recycling activities is the highest, which is capable of keeping the wholesale price at the lowest level so that the retailer will have the incentive to maintain the retail price at the lowest relative level. It also indicates that the overall profits of the supply chain under coordination decision-making are affected by the magnitude of the cost differential for recyclers.

3.5.2. Comparison of Decision-Making Models with CSR Effort and without CSR Effort

It has so far yielded inconclusive results about whether the EV power battery in-dustry is positively affected by the CSR effort. Thus, this paper also constructs deci-sion-making models in CLSC without CSR effort and analyzes the optimal decision in this scenario. Limited by the length of the article, this paper only shows the model re-sults in Table 3.
Table 3 indicates that, without the consideration of CSR effort, from the perspec-tive of the overall profit of the supply chain, for each recycling mode, the centralized decision-making model outperforms the decentralized decision-making model, and the differences in the levels of overall profit between the centralized decision-making models depend on the levels of the unit recycling cost of the recyclers. As ATP < AR < AM, the third-party recycling centralized decision-making model is optimal, which is consistent with the result of models with CSR effort.
Comparing the models with and without CSR effort, according to the results in Table 2 and Table 3, for both decision-making models in each of the three recycling modes, the profits of the supply chain in models with CSR effort are higher than that of mod-els without CSR effort. Therefore, it implies that the profit of the supply chain could be improved by the manufacturer’s CSR effort when consumers are sensitive to the level of CSR effort.

4. Numerical and Sensitivity Analysis

4.1. Numerical Anaylsis

In this section, we conduct a numerical analysis to illustrate the developed models and the impacts of CRS efforts on the decisions and profits of the participants and the overall supply chain of the CLSC in the Chinese power battery industry. In recent years, the NEV industry has developed rapidly. Based on the analysis above, in the views of profit growth and market scale, the power battery recycling market possesses enormous potential. Therefore, this paper uses the Chinese power battery manufacturers as an example. Based on the prediction and estimation from research reports of the Chinese EV power battery industry and enterprises such as the CATL (The following research reports are referred to: (a) In-depth report of CATL, Deng, Y., Li, J., Guo, Y., Li, J., Wang, Y., Ye, T., MINSHENG Securities, 28 June 2022, retrieved from Wind Database; (b) In-depth report of New Energy and Car industries, Chen, X., Song, W., Niu, Y., HUAAN Securities, 18 May 2022, retrieved from Hibor Database; (c) In-depth report of Lithium recycling industry, Yin, Z., Hao, Q., Huang, S., EVERBRIGHT Securities, 6 April 2022, retrieved from iFinD Database; (d) In-depth report of NEV industry and Positive Electrode industry, Yuan, J., Wang, Z., Wu, W., Liu, P., Teng, G., CITIC Securities, 23 May 2022, retrieved from Wind Database.), it assumes that the market potential of power batteries in 2022 is around four million, and the unit cost of producing a 60 KWh power battery pack is around 58,000 CNY. By considering the difficulty in building a recycling network and the difference in the focus of the main business of enterprises [63] and real market estimated cost, it assumes that the unit costs of recycling and storage of waste power batteries for different recyclers are A T P = 16,000 CNY, A R = 20,000 CNY, and A M = 26,000 CNY, and the unit cost saving of processing a waste power battery into the new product is around 32,000 CNY. In addition, we consider the following parameter values: β = 44 ,   λ = 2 ,   θ = 10 ,   C L = 9 × 10 9 ,   α 1 = 0.33 , α 2 = 0.33 , α 3 = 0.24 , and γ = 0.56 , and the results are shown in Table 4.
(1)
Static analysis
As shown in Table 4, the results of the numerical analysis are consistent with the results of the models above. For each recycling mode, compared to the model in the decentralized decision situation, the recovery rate, the overall profit and the CSR effort of the supply chain in the model under coordination decision-making are higher, while the sale price and the wholesale price are lower. Among the three coordinated decision-making models, the sales price, recycling rate and the profit of the supply chain and all of the participants in Model TP-C (when third-party recycling) are better than those in the other two models.
(2)
Dynamic analysis
This paper also discussed the relationship between the changes in CSR effort and changes in the overall profit of the supply chain. In addition, the overall profits of the supply chain under different decision-making models (with and without CSR effort) are also compared. The results are shown in Figure 2. In Figure 2, Model i stands for the i recycling model with CSR effort, and Model i* stands for the i* recycling model without CSR effort. As shown in Figure 2, in both decision situations, when the sensitivity coefficient of consumers to the enterprise’s level of CSR effort is greater than zero, the overall profit of the supply chain could be improved by the manufacturer’s CSR effort. The profit growth rate increases with the increase in the sensitivity coefficient of consumers to CSR effort (λ) but decreases with the increase in the coefficient of the enterprise’s CSR effort cost (θ). For a comparison of the overall profits in models with and without CSR effort, the results are consistent with the results in Table 3; the overall profit of the supply chain in each recycling model with CSR effort outperforms that in the same recycling model without CSR in different situations.

4.2. Sensitivity Analysis

Affected by the business environment, in the practice of product recycling, decision makers of enterprises often change their decision intentions, which could change the decisions of pricing and choices of optimal recycling channels. Thus, decision-making outcomes need to have some robustness. In this section, this paper examines the sensitivity of some key parameters on the profits of the manufacturer and retailer for different models. To be noticed, we only examine the sensitivity in three coordination decision-making models, as in each recycling mode, the coordination decision-making model outperforms the decentralized decision-making model. When considering CSR in the CLSC, there are three key parameters. The first two parameters are β and λ in the demand function, where β determines the sensitivity of consumers to product prices, and λ determines the impact of CSR effort on product volume sales. The third one is the coefficient of CSR effort cost θ, which determines the CSR cost invested by enterprises.
(1)
Sensitivity with respect to β and λ
This paper discusses how the profits of the manufacturer and retailer are affected by the adjustments of parameters β and λ. Here, β ranges in the interval of [40,50], instead of β = 44; and λ ranges in the interval of [0, 5] instead of λ = 2. The result is shown in Figure 3. Figure 3 indicates that, from the perspective of the profits of the manufacturer and retailer, Model TP-C (third-party recycling) is always the optimal decision under coordination decision-making. Meanwhile, the lower the sensitivity of consumers to product prices, the higher the profits of the manufacturer and retailer. In addition, when consumers are sensitive to the level of CSR effort, the manufacturer and retailer both could gain profits when manufacturing carries CSR investment, and the higher the sensitivity of consumers to CSR effort, the higher the profits of the manufacturer and retailer. Therefore, our optimal decision is relatively stable.
(2)
Sensitivity with respect to θ and λ
Next, this paper discusses how the profits of the manufacturer and retailer are affected by the adjustments of CSR-related parameters θ and λ. Here, in addition to λ, θ ranges in the interval of [8,15] instead of θ = 10. The result is shown in Figure 4. Based on Figure 4, consistent with the sensitivity analysis above, Model TP-C always is the optimal decision under coordination decision-making from the perspective of profits of the manufacturer and retailer, which means this optimal decision is relatively stable. In addition, we also find that, under the premise of unchanged price sensitivity and CSR effort sensitivity, the lower the level of CSR effort, the higher profits of the manufacturer and retailer, which is reasonable, as higher levels of CSR effort will increase the costs of the manufacturer. However, in practice, the level of CSR effort may change consumers’ sensitivity to CSR effort; when enterprises spend a huge amount of money on CSR activities, consumers often prefer these socially responsible intense brands and their products. Additionally, based on the previous analysis, the increase in the sensitivity of consumers to CSR effort could improve the profitability of the manufacturer and retailer. For this reason, the manufacturer has the intention to bare its CSR cost so that it may increase consumers’ sensitivity and eventually gain more profit. However, it does not mean that no matter how heavy the investment the manufacturer spends, the higher profit it can earn. It is worth noting that the relationship between the fold-change of CSR investment cost coefficient (y) and fold-change of CSR sensitivity coefficient (x) must fulfill the following condition: y < x 2 , only if y < x 2 , the sensitivity of consumers to CSR effort could be increased by increasing CSR investment, leading to increased profits.
In summary, our analyses show that the optimal decision is consistent, and proposed decision-making models have relatively strong robustness.

4.3. Effectiveness Analysis of Coordination Contracts

In this part, the numerical analysis is used to analyze and examine the effectiveness of the coordination contracts of three recycling channel strategies developed in Section 3, and the parameters set for the numerical example here remains the same as those in Section 4.1. The development of profit-sharing contracts is critical to effectively implementing a recycling channel strategy under coordination decision-making, and changes in the allocation ratio of contracts will lead to changes in the profits of the participants in the supply chain. Inappropriate allocation ratios may not ensure that the profits of the participants under coordination decision-making are higher than their respective profits under decentralized decision-making, resulting in the failure of the contract signing. Thus, it is essential to study the reasonable value ranges of the allocation ratio in each recycling channel strategy in order to meet the needs of all participants.
Figure 5 shows the changes in the profits of the manufacturer and retailer caused by changes in parameters α 1 and α 2 , when manufacturer recycling and retailer recycling, respectively. To ensure the improvement of the profits of both the manufacturer and retailer, it should satisfy: M M C > M M , and R M C > R M ; when manufacturer recycling, and it should satisfy: M R C > M R , and R R C > R R when retailer recycling. Thus, through calculation, the value ranges of the allocation ratios in the two contracts can be obtained: in Model M-C, the value range of the allocation ratio satisfies: α 1 0.2377 , 0.4876 ; in Model R-C, the value range of the allocation ratio satisfies: α 2 0.2486 , 0.4987 . Based on the results above, when the allocation ratios fall within these two ranges, respectively, the profits of the manufacturer and the retailer in each of these two recycling channel strategies are both higher than their respective profits under decentralized decision-making (Model M or Model R). Here, it is possible for both participants to reach a contract that they are willing to accept through negotiation in Model M-C and Model R-C.
Figure 6 shows the changes in the profits of the three participants caused by changes in the two allocation ratios when third-party recycling. To ensure the improvement of profits of the manufacturer, the retailer and the third party, it should satisfy: M T P C > M T P , R T P C > R T P , and T P T P C > T P T P . Thus, through calculation, from the perspective of the manufacturer and retailer, to allow both participants to have higher profits than those under decentralized decision-making and ensure that the manufacturer possibly has profit margins to share with the third party, the value range of the allocation ratio needs to satisfy: α 3 0.1377 , 0.4185 . From the perspective of the manufacturer and the third party, to allow both participants to have higher profits than those under decentralized decision-making, the value range of the allocation ratio needs to satisfy: γ 0.2953 ,   0.6227 . Unlike the situations in the other two decision-making models, it is worth noting that the value range of parameter γ in Model TP-C is affected by the changes in parameter α 3 . The reason for that is that the overall profit of the supply chain is constant; the profits allocated to the manufacturer decrease with the increase in the allocation ratio ( α 3 ) of the retailer, squeezing the possible profit margin that the manufacturer can share with the third party. Therefore, in fact, as α 3 rises, the actual range of possible values of γ narrows. Based on this, under this recycling channel strategy, when the retailer and manufacturer are negotiating their profit-sharing contract, they also need to juggle the profit distribution issues of the manufacturer and the third party. By this effort, it may leave enough room for negotiation between the manufacturer and the third party, so that it is possible to achieve a win–win situation for all three participants and to facilitate a mutually acceptable profit-sharing contract.
From the above effectiveness analysis of the coordination contracts in different recycling channel strategies, it shows that in all three recycling channel strategies and profit-sharing contracts are enabled to achieve the coordination of CLSC. As long as the allocation ratios fall within the feasible range of values, it is capable of improving the benefits of the overall supply chain and all the participants at the same time. Therefore, the profit-sharing contracts developed in this paper are able to achieve the goal of coordinating the CLSC system and maximizing the interests of all participants, as well as reaching a win–win situation for the overall supply chain and all participants.

5. Discussion and Management Insights

5.1. Result Discussion

The above results show that the profit of each participant in CLSC is higher in coordination decision-making models, regardless of the selection of recycling channels.
Firstly, comparing three recycling channels under coordination decision-making models, the third-party recycling channel is optimal when the recycling cost of the third party is the lowest among the three recyclers and retains a lower level. Under an appropriate profit-sharing contract, the retailer is able to earn a higher level of profit from a higher level of market demand caused by a lower level of wholesale price and retail price. The manufacturer is able to achieve a higher level of financial gains from the profit-sharing by the retailer and have greater cost savings caused by a lower level of recycling cost. In addition, although the third party does not directly gain profits from the recycling activities, in this case, it can receive subsidies from the profit-sharing by the manufacturer. Additionally, the profit of the third party increases with the increased volume of waste products recycled, and the low level of retail prices further facilitates the market demands as well as recycling activities. Thus, a virtuous cycle is achieved in the CLSC.
Secondly, the recycling cost plays an important role in influencing the overall profit of the supply chain, and the choice of recycling channel is related to the differences in recycling costs. The cost of recycling is often lower for the third-party recycler than for the other two participants due to the professionalism in the recycling business and the extensive recycling network. When the recycling cost of the third party is lower than the retailer and the difference is large enough, selecting a third-party recycling channel strategy under coordination decision-making is capable of providing greater overall profits and sufficient room for profit distribution, which ensures improved profits for all participants compared to the profits in other recycling channel strategies. On the contrary, if the recycling costs between the third party and the retailer exhibit little difference, the overall profits under these two recycling channel strategies under coordination decision-making will tend to be relatively close. Here, there may be insufficient room for ensuring the balance of profit distribution between the three participants, leading to a higher risk of no consensus impacting the profit-sharing contract. As a result, it is highly likely that the manufacturer turns to select the retailer recycling channel, as it is easier to reach a consensus on a profit-sharing contract when only two participants are involved in the supply chain. In this situation, the third party is forced to exit the recycling market, while the choice of retailer recycling channel becomes optimal.
Thirdly, it is found that the recovery rate, retail price and the profits of the overall supply chain and the participants are affected significantly by the transfer price. However, there are variations in different decision situations. In the decentralized decision situation, since there is no profit-sharing contract, the levels of transfer price have direct effects on the recycling motivation and the recycling profit of the recycler commissioned by the manufacturer (the retailer or the third party). Thus, the manufacturer should try to raise the transfer price to increase the incentive for the recycler to collect waste products. However, the pricing decisions of transfer prices made by the manufacturer differ for different recyclers. By comparing Model R and Model M, it is found that, when the retailer recycling, the retailer generates profits from sales and recycling activities, so the higher the transfer price given to the retailer, the stronger the incentive for the retailer to recycle and the more willing it is to maintain a low level of the retail price. At this time, the manufacturer should increase the transfer price as much as possible, and based on the analysis in Section 3; it needs to pass on the cost savings of the processing waste product into new products to the retailer (namely b = Δ ) in order to control its own costs and maximize the incentive for the retailer to collect waste products. With third-party recycling, the maximum transfer price that a manufacturer can offer is smaller than the one offered to the retailer, as the optimal equilibrium here is the manufacturer shares the profit generated by the recycling activity equally with the third party (namely b = Δ + A T P / 2 ). Here, for the manufacturer, there is some sort of relationship between the recycling activity and the wholesale price. Thus, when the manufacturer shares the recycling profits equally with the third party, there is some room for wholesale price adjustment, allowing the manufacturer to maintain a relatively low level of the wholesale price, which can drive the retailer to maintain a relatively high level of market demand with a relatively low level of the retail price.
On the contrary, in the coordination decision-making models, with the existence of a profit-sharing contract, the transfer price paid by the manufacturer only needs to meet the requirement to cover the recycling cost of the recycler. The transfer price decreases with lower recycling costs, resulting in reduced total costs, and the overall profit of the supply chain is higher with the decrease in the recycling cost, so the total amount of profit distribution available to participants in CLSC increases as well.
Fourthly, for CSR effort, this paper finds that the CSR effort carried by the manufacturer has a positive impact on the CLSC. When the consumers’ sensitivity to CSR efforts increases, it is conducive to expanding market demand and improving the recovery rate of waste products. The CSR effort carried out by the manufacturer is beneficial to supply chain activities, no matter who determines the recycling activity. It indicates that the CSR effort carried out by the manufacturer could affect the financial gains of stakeholders, so it is the essential that the manufacturer needs to undertake heavier CSR in supply chain management.
Based on discussions above, in the situation of coordination decision-making, maximizing the overall benefits is the goal of the CLSC, while a lower level of the retail price and a higher level of the CSR effort keep the market demand at a higher level, and sales and recycling activities are both in the more active state, which minimizes the double marginalization.

5.2. Management Insights

This paper expects to provide some valuable insights into the management of power battery recycling activities based on previous discussions.
Firstly, from the perspective of the overall benefits of the supply chain, the coordination decision-making model is the best solution for CLSC recycling and remanufacturing activities for managers, which may avoid the profit loss from double marginalization. Thus, it is necessary for enterprise managers to place the enhancement of financial gains of the overall supply chain at the top. In addition, it is worth noting that the benefits of all of the participants in the CLSC also need to be ensured, as profitability is also very important to each participant in the real business world. Based on this, it is necessary to make a proper coordination plan to avoid conflicts of interest between the overall supply chain and all of the participants, so that all participants need jointly develop a profit-sharing contract that all participants are willing to accept. As discussed before, the feasible allocation ratios fall within the certain range of values, and different values of allocation ratios cause changes in the profit of each participant. Thus, managers’ decisions can be pursued in two ways when negotiating profit-sharing contracts. On the one hand, when the bargain powers of participants are close, it is desirable to choose an allocation ratio that enable the magnitude of participant’s profit growth as relatively close to others when negotiating, so that all participants are more likely to take the initiative to fulfill the contract after it is signed, which can avoid default situations. On the other hand, if there is a highly dominant participant with strong bargaining power in the supply chain, then other participants should take this factor into consideration and make appropriate compromises with it, and try to meet the dominant’s profit demands while ensuring its own interests, which is easier to reach the consensus on profit-sharing contract.
Secondly, in the power battery industry, enterprises need to integrate the concept of reverse logistics into their business operation process. To achieve this, for manufacturers, firstly, they need to focus on the recyclability of products, the reusability of materials and reducing product costs through technological advances. In addition, when selecting the recycling channel, manufacturers should select the recycler that is more conducive to supply chain overall benefits and profits for all participants by situations. Based on the previous discussion, both the third-party recycling channel and the retailer recycling channel are possibly the optimal choice of channel, depending on the differences in the magnitudes of the difference in their recycling costs. When the recycling costs of the third party are lower than the retailer and the difference is large enough, it is capable of achieving higher recovery rates and overall profits of the supply chain, so the third-party recycling channel is the optimal choice. Conversely, it may be more advantageous to select the retailer recycling channel. Moreover, it is necessary for manufacturers to care about the cash flow issue of third parties when selecting a third-party recycling channel under coordination decision-making. Based on the analysis above, in this situation, third parties can barely profit directly from recycling activities, so that the third parties may still face financial risks such as a shortage in cash flow due to the issues of heavy upfront investment or a long payback period. Thus, manufacturers can take the initiative to provide solutions such as financial support, credit guaranty or shortened settlement cycle, according to the real situations and needs of the third parties, in order to prevent third parties from exiting the market due to the above problems. Beyond that, power battery manufacturers need to actively fulfill their CSR and bare the CSR effort costs, as this effort is more beneficial to all participants in the CLSC and stakeholders. Furthermore, it is also an effective way to achieve the optimal balance of the economic benefits of the CLSC and the environmental benefits to society.
For retailers, market demand is affected by the levels of the retail price, so retailers should find ways to stabilize the retail prices at relatively reasonable levels. For example, they may try to lower costs using approaches such as optimizing the sales network and cutting inefficient promotion expenditures, thereby increasing their profit margins as much as possible. Through these efforts, retailers may have more room to keep retail prices at a relatively low level so it is possible to maintain a high level of market demand and improve the overall profit of the supply chain. For third parties, there is a tight link between the levels of their recycling costs and their competitiveness in the recycling market. Therefore, to achieve the improvement of competitive ability and ensure their positions in CLSC, third parties need to continuously lower recycling costs and enhance recycling capacity by refining the layout of recycling networks and improving the extraction process of recycling materials.
Thirdly, the support and guidance from the government are also curial to the CLSC system. Firstly, to lower the production and recycling costs, the government could promote power battery enterprises to carry out technological innovation using methods of financial subsidies or incentives for new patented technologies. Through technological advances, enterprises may achieve sufficient cost saving and competitive advantage. Moreover, to improve the recovery rate, the government could take measures such as establishing certain reward and punishment mechanisms to guide companies. For example, by learning from the NEV double-point policy promulgated in 2018, the government may introduce a similar reward and punishment policy based on the current situation of power battery recycling in China and provides enterprises with corresponding incentives or punishments according to their actual recycling performances. In additional, to guide and support increasing numbers of power battery manufacturers taking CSR activities, the government could take both compulsory measures (such as regulatory policy making) and positive incentives (such as some forms of rewards). For example, China Securities Regulatory Commission may strengthen the review of CSR-related information disclosure by A-share listed power battery companies. Or local governments may coordinate closely with power battery manufacturers and jointly carry out projects for the public good, which matches the actual needs of local society. The government could also publicly commend or reward those manufacturers who attach importance to CSR, to set good examples for others.

6. Conclusions

The recycling and remanufacturing activities of the NEV power battery have received widespread concern due to energy and environmental pollution issues. However, there are various participants involving and different recycling models existing in recycling activities of CLSC, so that it is essential to investigate the optimal decision of the CLSC, in order to ensure the effectiveness of power battery CLSC implementation and the interests of all participants. In addition, CSR has received an increasing number of concerns among enterprises and society, and it has become an important component in global business practice. Therefore, by considering CSR investment and uncertain demand and introducing the idea of game theory, this paper studied recycling channel selection in the Chinese power battery industry and undertook the following research: six decision-making models were constructed under different recycling modes and in different decision situations, and the model results were compared and discussed; the corresponding numerical and sensitivity analyses were provided, followed by a discussion of the results and management insights.
This paper finds that, firstly, in terms of the overall benefits of supply chain and recycling effectiveness, coordination decision-making is better than decentralized decision-making. Under coordination decision-making, the choice of a third-party recycling channel or retailer recycling channel has a linkage to the magnitudes of the difference in the recycling costs between recyclers. When the recycling cost of the third party is the lowest and below the recycling cost of the retailer by a certain margin, the third-party recycling channel is the optimal choice. Here, the major problem is the coordination of interests. This paper finds that establishing a reasonable profit-sharing contract is capable of achieving a win–win situation for CLSC and all participants, which can ensure the effective implementation of the coordination decision-making in practice. Secondly, when manufacturers entrust other recyclers, the optimal profits of the overall supply chain are affected by the recycling costs of the recyclers and the transfer prices of the manufacturers. Thirdly, the CSR effort carried out by manufacturers allows the manufacturer, other participants, and the overall supply to earn financial gains when consumers are sensitive to the level of CSR effort.
This research may have values in terms of theoretical and practical contribution, which mainly are related to the decision variables and models constructed. It sheds new light on studies of CLSC management, providing theoretical support for recycling practices of power battery industry. From the perspective of demand uncertainty, it investigates the optimal decision of the power battery CLSC operations and choice of recycling channel, and studies how CSR effort affects the product demand and the equilibrium of supply chain. In addition, with regard to the profit-sharing, coordination contract is developed to achieve the effective implementation of the optimal decision of CLSC, which helps to carry out reverse logistics activities in Chinese power battery industry as well as other industries.
In practice, the decision-making environments are often uncertain, so that future research may construct a dynamic game theory decision-making model by considering the information asymmetries. In addition, further research may study the impacts of other participants’ CSR efforts on the decision-making of CLSC, as this paper only considers the situation of CSR activities taken by the manufacturer. Moreover, further research may also study a dual-channel and multi-period CLSC structure with the consideration of CSR.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, T.T., L.Y. and C.Z.; methodology, L.Y. and X.L.; formal analysis, T.T. and X.L.; writing—original draft preparation, T.T. and L.Y.; writing—review and editing, T.T., C.Z. and L.L.; supervision, C.Z. and L.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This study was supported by the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities of China-Specialized Project: Research on the interaction relationship between financial innovation and technology innovation (B200207034); Guangxi Philosophy and Social Science Research Project: Research on the transformation and upgrading path and countermeasures of Guangxi manufacturing industry under the Internet business ecological environment (21FYJ055).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

(a)
Calculation steps of Model M
Taking the first-order partial derivative of p for Equation (1), we can obtain: R M p = β p w + ϕ β p + λ e .
From 2 R M 2 p = 2 β < 0 , R M is a convex function of p, so that the optimal retail price p can be obtained: p M = ϕ β w + λ e 2 β .
Then, the market demand for the product is D ( w ) = ϕ β w + λ e 2 . Therefore, the desirability profit function of the manufacturer can be formulated as follows:
M M = ϕ β w + λ e 2 w C n + τ Δ τ A M C L τ 2 1 2 θ e 2 .
Taking the first-order partial derivative of w, e, τ:
M M w = ϕ β w + λ e 2 + β 2 w C n + τ Δ τ A M ,   M M e = λ 2 w C n + τ Δ τ A M θ e ,             M M τ = ϕ β w + λ e 2 Δ A M 2 C L τ .  
The manufacturer’s profit function has a unique optimal solution from the Hesse matrix. According to the first-order condition, the w, e, τ and p can be obtained, which is shown in Equation (3).
  • (b) Calculation steps of coordination decision-making model
Taking the first-order partial derivative of p, e, τ for Equation (5), we can obtain:
j C p = β p C n + τ Δ τ A j + ϕ β p + λ e ,   j C e = λ p C n + τ Δ τ A j θ e ,               j C τ = ϕ β p + λ e Δ A j 2 C L τ .  
The profit function of the overall supply chain j C has a unique optimal solution from the Hesse matrix, and from a first-order partial derivative equal to zero, the optimal decision can be obtained.
For Model j-C, under coordination contract, it should satisfy: p r = p m = p t , so we can obtain: R j C d p = M j C p = T j C p .
  • (c) Calculation steps of Model R
Taking the first-order partial derivative of p for Equation (11), we can obtain:
R R p = β p w + τ b τ A R + ϕ β p + λ e ,   R R τ = ϕ β p + λ e b A R 2 C l τ .  
From 2 R R 2 p = 2 β and 2 R R 2 p × 2 R R 2 τ 2 R R p τ 2 = 4 β C L β 2 b 2 > 0 , Equation (11) is the joint convex function of p and τ, and has a unique optimal solution. According to its first-order condition, the optimal response of the retailer can be obtained. Taking p R and τ R of the retailer into Equation (12), the desirability profit function of the manufacturer can be obtained:
M R = 2 C L ϕ β w + λ e w C n 4 C L β b A R 2 + ϕ β w + λ e b A R Δ b 4 C L β b A R 2 2 1 2 θ e 2 .
Taking its first-order partial derivative of w and e, we can obtain:
M R w = 2 C L ϕ 2 β w + λ e + β C n 4 C L β b A R 2 2 β ϕ β w + λ e b A R Δ b 4 C L β b A R 2 2 , M R e = 2 λ C L w C n 4 C L β b A R 2 + 2 ϕ β w + λ e b A R Δ b 4 C L β b A R 2 2 θ e .  
From 2 M R 2 w = 2 C L 2 β 4 C L β b A R 2 + 2 β 2 b A R Δ b 4 C L β b A R 2 2 < 0 , 2 M R 2 w × 2 M R 2 e 2 M R w e 2 > 0 , the desirability profit function of the manufacturer is the joint convex function of w and e, and has a unique optimal solution. According to its first-order condition, the optimal response of the manufacturer can be obtained.
  • (d) Calculation steps of Model TP
Taking the first-order partial derivative of p for Equation (20), we can obtain:
R T P p = β p w + ϕ β p + λ e .  
From 2 R T P 2 p = 2 β < 0 , R T P is a convex function of p, so that the optimal retail price p can be obtained: p T P = ϕ + β w + λ e 2 β . Taking it into Equation (21), we can obtain T P T P = ϕ β w + λ e 2 β τ b A T P C L τ 2 , then taking the first-order partial derivative of τ, we can obtain: T P T P τ = ϕ β w + λ e 2 β b A T P 2 C L τ . From 2 T P T P 2 τ = 2 C L < 0 , T P T P is the convex function of τ, so that the optimal retail price τ can be obtained: τ T P = ϕ + β w + λ e b A T P 4 C L . For a given p T P and τ T P , taking into Equation (22), we can obtain:
M T P = ϕ β w + λ e 4 C L w C n + ϕ β w + λ e b A T P Δ b 8 C L 1 2 θ e 2 .  
Taking its first-order partial derivative of w and e, we can obtain:
M T P w = 2 C L ϕ 2 β w + λ e + β C n β ϕ β w + λ e b A T P Δ b 4 C L , M T P e = 2 λ C L w C n + λ ϕ β w + λ e b A T P Δ b 4 θ e C L 4 C L .  
From 2 M T P 2 w = 4 β C L + β 2 b A T P Δ b 4 C L < 0 , 2 M T P 2 w × 2 M T P 2 e 2 M T P w e 2 > 0 , Equation (22) has a unique optimal solution.

References

  1. Liu, S.; Yao, F.; Chen, D. CSR investment decision and coordination strategy for closed-loop supply chain with two competing retailers. J. Clean Prod. 2021, 310, 127378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Xing, E.; Shi, C.; Cheng, S.; Lin, J.; Ni, S. Double third-party recycling closed-loop supply chain decision under the perspective of carbon trading. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 259, 120651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Guo, J.; Wang, G.; Wang, Z.; Liang, C.; Gen, M. Research on remanufacturing closed loop supply chain based on incentive-compatibility theory under uncertainty. Ann. Oper. Res. 2022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Govindan, K.; Soleimani, H.; Kannan, D. Reverse logistics and closed-loop supply chain: A comprehensive review to explore the future. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2015, 240, 603–626. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Wang, Z.; Wu, Q. Carbon emission reduction and product collection decisions in the closed-loop supply chain with cap-and-trade regulation. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2021, 59, 4359–4383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Wan, N.; Hong, D. The impacts of subsidy policies and transfer pricing policies on the closed-loop supply chain with dual collection channels. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 224, 881–891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Wang, W.; Zhang, P.; Ding, J.; Li, J.; Sun, H.; He, L. Closed-loop supply chain network equilibrium model with retailer-collection under legislation. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2019, 15, 199–219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Ma, Z.; Zhang, N.; Dai, Y.; Hu, S. Managing channel profits of different cooperative models in closed-loop supply chains. Omega-Int. J. Manag. Sci. 2016, 59, 251–262. [Google Scholar]
  9. Gong, R.; Xue, J.; Liu, R.; Zhou, J.; Zhao, L. A Closed-Loop Supply Chain Decision Model Considering Corporate Social Responsibility and Value-Added Services. Manag. Decis. Econ. 2022, 43, 1704–1720. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Gu, X.; Ieromonachou, P.; Zhou, L.; Tseng, M.-L. Developing pricing strategy to optimise total profits in an electric vehicle battery closed loop supply chain. J. Clean Prod. 2018, 203, 376–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Wang, T.; Jiang, Y.; Kang, L.; Liu, Y. Determination of retirement points by using a multi-objective optimization to compromise the first and second life of electric vehicle batteries. J. Clean Prod. 2020, 275, 123128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Wu, Y.; Yang, L.; Tian, X.; Li, Y.; Zuo, T. Temporal and spatial analysis for end-of-life power batteries from electric vehicles in China. Resour. Conserv. Recy. 2020, 155, 104651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Wu, X.; Zhou, Y. The optimal reverse channel choice under supply chain competition. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 259, 63–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Tan, C.; Li, B.; Zhou, L. Pricing decision making in logistics service supply chain considering corporate social responsibility. Comput. Integr. Manuf. 2021, 27, 2461–2475. [Google Scholar]
  15. Yan, Y.; Yao, F.; Sun, J. Manufacturer’s Cooperation Strategy of Closed-Loop Supply Chain Considering Corporate Social Responsibility. Rairo-Oper. Res. 2021, 55, 3639–3659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Zhu, M.; Yeung, A.C.L.; Zhou, H. Diversify or Concentrate: The Impact of Customer Concentration on Corporate Social Responsibility. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2021, 240, 108214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Dey, S.K.; Giri, B.C. Corporate Social Responsibility in a Closed-Loop Supply Chain with Dual-Channel Waste Recycling. Int. J. Syst. Sci-Oper. Logist. 2021, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Duan, C.; Yao, F.; Xiu, G.; Zhang, Y.; Zhang, X. Multi-Period Closed-Loop Supply Chain Network Equilibrium: Perspective of Marketing and Corporate Social Responsibility. IEEE Access 2021, 9, 1495–1511. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Hussain, M.; Malik, M. Organizational enablers for circular economy in the context of sustainable supply chain management. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 256, 120375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Yan, G.; Song, Q.; Ni, Y.; Yang, X. Pricing, carbon emission reduction and recycling decisions in a closed-loop supply chain under uncertain environment. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2022, 19, 224–245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Mokhtar, R.M.; Genovese, A.; Brint, A.; Kumar, N. Improving reverse supply chain performance: The role of supply chain leadership and governance mechanisms. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 216, 42–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. He, P.; He, Y.; Hu, H. Channel structure and pricing in a dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government subsidy. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 213, 108–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Ranjbar, S.; Sahebi, H.; Ashayeri, J.; Teymouri, A. A competitive dual recycling channel in a three-level closed loop supply chain under different power structures: Pricing and collecting decisions. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 272, 122623. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Chuang, C.-H.; Wang, C.X.; Zhao, Y. Closed-loop supply chain models for a high-tech product under alternative reverse channel and collection cost structures. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2014, 156, 108–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Savaskan, R.C.; Bhattacharya, S.; Van Wassenhove, L.N. Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Manage. Sci. 2003, 50, 239–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. De Giovanni, P.; Zaccour, G. A two-period game of a closed-loop supply chain. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2014, 232, 22–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Zheng, B.; Chu, J.; Jin, L. Recycling channel selection and coordination in dual sales channel closed-loop supply chains. Appl. Math. Model. 2021, 95, 484–502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Bai, S.; Yang, L.; Liu, Z. Optimal Decision and Coordination of Fresh E-Commerce Supply Chain Considering Double Loss. Discrete Dyn. Nat. Soc. 2022, 2022, 3781698. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Hong, I.H.; Yeh, J.S. Modeling closed-loop supply chains in the electronics industry: A retailer collection application. Transport. Res. E-Log. 2012, 48, 817–829. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Miao, Z.; Fu, K.; Xia, Z.; Wang, Y. Models for closed-loop supply chain with trade-ins. Omega-Int. J. Manage. S. 2017, 66, 308–326. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Modak, N.M.; Modak, N.; Panda, S.; Sana, S.S. Analyzing structure of two-echelon closed-loop supply chain for pricing, quality and recycling management. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 171, 512–528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. He, Q.; Wang, N.; Yang, Z.; He, Z.; Jiang, B. Competitive collection under channel inconvenience in closed-loop supply chain. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 275, 155–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Liu, W.; Wei, W.; Wang, M.; Tang, O.; Zhou, L. Pricing decision with conspicuous customers: Quick responses versus value-added services. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2020, 59, 1691–1713. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Ma, J.; Zhu, L.; Guo, Y. Strategies and stability study for a triopoly game considering product recovery based on closed-loop supply chain. Oper. Res-Ger. 2021, 21, 2261–2282. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Gong, Y.; Chen, M. Green Supply Chain Considering Fairness Preference and Corporate Social Responsibility. Control Decision. 2021, 36, 1743–1753. [Google Scholar]
  36. Hsu, B.-X.; Chen, Y.-M.; Chen, L.-A. Corporate Social Responsibility and Value Added in the Supply Chain: Model and Mechanism. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2022, 174, 121302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Yan, Y.; Yao, F. Pricing Strategy of Closed Loop Supply Chain Considering Different CSR Investment Modes. CSCNS2020 2021, 336, 09005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Krueger, P. Corporate Goodness and Shareholder Wealth. J. Financ. Econ. 2015, 115, 304–329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Pino, G.; Amatulli, C.; De Angelis, M.; Peluso, A.M. The Influence of Corporate Social Responsibility on Consumers’ Attitudes and Intentions Toward Genetically Modified Foods: Evidence from Italy. J. Clean Prod. 2016, 112, 2861–2869. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Jia, X.; Li, W.; Gao, W. The Effect of Supplier CSR Practices on Sales Performance with Major Customers in B2B Markets. Int. J. Logist-Res. Appl. 2021, 1–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Sun, Q.; Ma, C.; Bai, Q. Research on Social Responsibility Investment and Pricing Strategy of Supply Chain Enterprises Based on Risk Preference. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2021, 30, 47–53. [Google Scholar]
  42. Servaes, H.; Tamayo, A. The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Firm Value: The Role of Customer Awareness. Manag. Sci. 2013, 59, 1045–1061. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Yuan, Y.; Yang, J.; Li, Y.; Li, W. Necessary conditions for coordination of dual-channel closed-loop supply chain. Technol. Forecast. Soc. 2020, 151, 119823. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Li, Y.; Liu, S.; Yao, F. Pricing strategy of closed-loop supply chain considering manufacturer’s fairness preference under different recycling mode. Ferroelectrics 2021, 581, 156–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Wang, X.; Ma, D.Q.; Hu, J.S. Recycling Model Selection for Electronic Products Considering Platform Power and Blockchain Empowerment. Sustainability 2022, 14, 6136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Dey, S.K.; Giri, B.C. Analyzing a Closed-Loop Sustainable Supply Chain with Duopolistic Retailers under Different Game Structures. CIRP J. Manuf. Sci. Technol. 2021, 33, 222–233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Ma, P.; Li, K.W.; Wang, Z.J. Pricing decisions in closed-loop supply chains with marketing effort and fairness concerns. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2017, 55, 6710–6731. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  48. Ghasemzadeh, Z.; Sadeghieh, A.; Shishebori, D. A stochastic multi-objective closed-loop global supply chain concerning waste management: A case study of the tire industry. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2021, 23, 5794–5821. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Karimabadi, K.; Arshadi-khamseh, A.; Naderi, B. Optimal pricing and remanufacturing decisions for a fuzzy dual-channel supply chain. Int. J. Syst. Sci-Oper. 2020, 7, 248–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Li, M.; He, L.; Yang, G.; Lian, Z. Profit-Sharing Contracts for Fresh Agricultural Products Supply Chain Considering Spatio-Temporal Costs. Sustainability 2022, 14, 2315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Ghosh, P.K.; Manna, A.K.; Dey, J.K.; Kar, S. Supply chain coordination model for green product with different payment strategies: A game theoretic approach. J. Clean Prod. 2021, 290, 125734. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Ghosh, S.K.; Seikh, M.R.; Chakrabortty, M. Pricing Strategy and Channel Co-ordination in a Two-Echelon Supply Chain Under Stochastic Demand. Int. J. Appl. Comput. Math. 2020, 6, 1–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Liang, P.; Sima, M.; Huang, Y.; Sun, X. Assessing the Coordinated Revenue-Sharing Contract of China’s Farmer-Supermarket Direct-Purchase Model. Int. Food Agribus. Manag. Rev. 2022, 25, 229–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Chauhan, S.S.; Proth, J.M. Analysis of a Supply Chain Partnership with Revenue Sharing. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2005, 97, 44–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Sheu, J.-B. Marketing-Driven Channel Coordination with Revenue-Sharing Contracts under Price Promotion to End-Customers. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2011, 214, 246–255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Zhou, H.; Liu, L.; Jiang, W.; Li, S. Green Supply Chain Decisions and Revenue-Sharing Contracts under Manufacturers’ Overconfidence. J. Math. 2022, 2022, 1035966. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Li, T.; Zhang, R.; Zhao, S.; Liu, B. Low Carbon Strategy Analysis under Revenue-Sharing and Cost-Sharing Contracts. J. Clean Prod. 2019, 212, 1462–1477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Yang, M.; Yang, Z.; Li, Y.; Liang, X. Research on Corporate Social Responsibility Coordination of Three-Tier Supply Chain Based on Stochastic Differential Game. Front. Psychol. 2022, 13, 783998. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Hosseini-Motlagh, S.-M.; Pazari, P.; Nouri, M. Coordination of promotional effort, corporate social responsibility and periodic review replenishment decisions in a two-echelon socially responsible supply chain. J. Ind. Syst. Eng. 2018, 11, 60–83. [Google Scholar]
  60. Wang, Q.; Chen, K.; Wang, S.; Cao, X. Optimal Decisions in a Closed-Loop Supply Chain: Fairness Concerns, Corporate Social Responsibility and Information Value. Ann. Oper. Res. 2022, 309, 277–304. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Su, J.; Li, C.; Zeng, Q.; Yang, J.; Zhang, J. A Green Closed-Loop Supply Chain Coordination Mechanism Based on Third-Party Recycling. Sustainability 2019, 11, 5335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  62. Gong, Y.; Chen, M.; Zhuang, Y. Decision-Making and Performance Analysis of Closed-Loop Supply Chain under Different Recycling Modes and Channel Power Structures. Sustainability 2019, 11, 6413. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  63. Tang, Y.; Zhang, Q.; Li, Y.; Wang, G.; Li, Y. Recycling mechanisms and policy suggestions for spent electric vehicles’ power battery -A case of Beijing. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 186, 388–406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Six decision-making models of closed-loop supply chain.
Figure 1. Six decision-making models of closed-loop supply chain.
Sustainability 14 16712 g001
Figure 2. Changes in overall profits of the supply chain caused by changes in parameter θ and λ.
Figure 2. Changes in overall profits of the supply chain caused by changes in parameter θ and λ.
Sustainability 14 16712 g002
Figure 3. Changes in profits of the manufacturer and retailer caused by changes in parameter β and λ.
Figure 3. Changes in profits of the manufacturer and retailer caused by changes in parameter β and λ.
Sustainability 14 16712 g003
Figure 4. Changes in profits of the manufacturer and retailer caused by changes in parameter θ and λ.
Figure 4. Changes in profits of the manufacturer and retailer caused by changes in parameter θ and λ.
Sustainability 14 16712 g004
Figure 5. Changes in profits of two participants caused by changes in parameter α in Model M−C and Model R−C.
Figure 5. Changes in profits of two participants caused by changes in parameter α in Model M−C and Model R−C.
Sustainability 14 16712 g005
Figure 6. Changes in profits of three participants caused by changes in parameter α and γ in Model TP−C.
Figure 6. Changes in profits of three participants caused by changes in parameter α and γ in Model TP−C.
Sustainability 14 16712 g006
Table 1. Notations and definitions.
Table 1. Notations and definitions.
Notation Definition
C n The unit cost of manufacturing a new product.
C r The unit cost of remanufacturing a waste product into a new product.
pProduct retail price.
wWholesale price.
bTransfer price, which is the unit price offered by the manufacturer for buying back waste products collected by the recycler.
A j The unit cost of recycling and storage of waste product of recycler j, A T P < A R < A M .
D p , e Quantity demanded of a product as a function of price and level of CSR effort.
j i The profit of the participant j in model i.
T i Overall profit of the supply chain in model i.
τ Recovery rate of waste products from consumers.
CThe average unit cost of manufacturing products, C = C n 1 τ + C r τ .
eThe enterprise’s level of CSR effort.
βThe price sensitivity coefficient.
λThe sensitivity coefficient of consumers to level of CSR effort.
c e The enterprise’s CSR effort cost.
θThe coefficient of enterprise’s CSR effort cost.
ΔThe unit cost saving of processing waste product into new product.
j = M , R , T P represent the manufacturer, retailer, and third party, respectively. i = M , R , T P , M C , R C , T P C represent Model M, Model R, Model TP, Model M-C, Model R-C, and Model TP-C, respectively.
Table 2. Comparison of six decision-making models with CSR effort in CLSC.
Table 2. Comparison of six decision-making models with CSR effort in CLSC.
(a). Comparison of Manufacturer RECYCLING decision-Making Models in CLSC.
Manufacturer Recycling
Model MModel M-C
p 2 C L 3 ϕ θ + β C n θ C n λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A M 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L ϕ θ + β C n θ C n λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A M 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2
w 4 C L ϕ θ + β C n ϕ β θ Δ A M 2 2 C n C L λ 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2 4 β C n θ C L 2 C n C L λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A M 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A M 2
e 2 λ C L ϕ β C n 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 λ C L ϕ β C n 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2
τ β θ ϕ β C n Δ A M 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2 β θ ϕ β C n Δ A M 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2
M θ C L ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2 θ C L ϕ β C n 2 4 β θ C L 1 α 1 β 2 θ Δ A M 2 2 λ 2 C L 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A M 2 2
R 4 β θ 2 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 4 α 1 β θ 2 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A M 2 2
T θ C L 12 β θ C L θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 C L λ 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2 2 θ C L ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A M 2
(b). Comparison of retailer recycling decision-making models in CLSC.
Retailer recycling
Model RModel R-C
p C L 3 ϕ θ + β C n θ C n λ 2 ϕ θ β Δ A R 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 2 C L ϕ θ + β C n θ C n λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A R 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A R 2
w 4 θ C L ϕ + β C n 2 C n C L λ 2 ϕ θ β + C n θ β 2 Δ A R 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 4 β C n θ C L 2 C n C L λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A R 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2
e λ C L ϕ β C n C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 2 λ C L ϕ β C n 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A R 2
τ θ β ϕ β C n Δ A R 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 β θ ϕ β C n Δ A R 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A R 2
M θ C L ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 θ C L 4 β θ C L 1 α 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 1 α 2 2 λ 2 C L ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 2
R β C L θ 2 ϕ β C n 2 4 C L β Δ A R 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 2 α 2 β θ 2 C L 4 C L β Δ A R 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 2
T θ C L 12 β θ C L 3 θ β 2 Δ A R 2 2 C L λ 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 2 β 2 θ Δ A R 2 2 θ C L ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A R 2
(c). Comparison of third-party recycling decision-making models in CLSC.
Thrid-party recycling
Model TPModel TP-C
p C L 3 ϕ θ + β C n θ C n λ 2 0.25 ϕ θ β Δ A T P 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 0.25 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 C L ϕ θ + β C n θ C n λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A T P 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A T P 2
w 2 θ C L ϕ + β C n C n C L λ 2 0.25 ϕ θ β Δ A T P 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 0.25 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 4 β C n θ C L 2 C n C L λ 2 ϕ β θ Δ A T P 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2
e λ C L ϕ β C n C L 4 β θ λ 2 0.25 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 λ C L ϕ β C n 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A T P 2
τ β θ ϕ β C n Δ A T P 4 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 β θ ϕ β C n Δ A T P 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A T P 2
M C L θ ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 0.5 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 γ θ C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 β θ 1 α 3 λ 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2
R β C L 2 θ 2 ϕ β C n 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 0.25 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 4 α 3 β θ 2 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2
T P C L β 2 θ 2 ϕ β C n 2 Δ A T P 2 4 C L 4 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 θ C L ϕ β C n 2 4 β θ C L 1 α 3 1 γ 2 λ 2 C L 1 γ β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2
T θ C L ϕ β C n 2 12 β θ C L 0.25 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 C L λ 2 2 C L 4 β θ λ 2 0.5 β 2 θ Δ A T P 2 2 θ C L ϕ β C n 2 2 C L 2 β θ λ 2 θ β 2 Δ A T P 2
Table 3. Results of decision-making models without CSR effort in CLSC.
Table 3. Results of decision-making models without CSR effort in CLSC.
(a). Results of Models without CSR Effort.
Manufacturer Recycling
Decentralized Decision-Making Model
Retailer Recycling
Decentralized Decision-Making Model
p 3 ϕ + β C n 4 β ϕ β C n Δ A M 2 4 8 C L β Δ A M 2 3 C L β Δ A R 2 ϕ + β C L C n β 4 C L β Δ A R 2
w ϕ + β C n 2 β 1 2 Δ A M 2 ϕ β C n 8 C L β Δ A M 2 ϕ + β C n 2 β
e Δ A M ϕ β C n 8 C L β Δ A M 2 Δ A R ϕ β C n 8 C L 2 β Δ A R 2
τ ϕ β C n 2 / 8 β 1 β Δ A M ) 2 / 8 C L ϕ β C n 2 / 8 β 1 β Δ A R 2 / 4 C L
M ϕ β C n 2 / 16 β 1 β Δ A M 2 / 8 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 / 16 β 1 β Δ A R 2 / 4 C L
R 3 / 4 β Δ A M 2 / 16 C L ϕ β C n 2 / 4 β 1 β Δ A M 2 / 8 C L 2 3 / 4 ϕ β C n 2 / 4 β 1 β Δ A R 2 / 4 C L
T 3 / 4 β Δ A T P 2 / 64 C L ϕ β C n 2 / 4 β 1 β Δ A T P 2 / 16 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 / 4 β 1 β Δ A j 2 / 4 C L
(b). Results of models without CSR effort (continued).
Third-party recycling
decentralized decision-making model
Centralized decision-making models
p 3 ϕ + β C n 4 β ϕ β C n Δ A T P 2 4 16 C L β Δ A T P 2 ϕ + β C n 2 β 1 2 Δ A j 2 ϕ β C n 4 C L β Δ A j 2
w ϕ + β C n 2 β ϕ β C n Δ A T P 2 2 16 C L β Δ A T P 2 -
τ Δ A T P ϕ β C n 16 C L β Δ A T P 2 Δ A j ϕ β C n 4 C L β Δ A j 2
M ϕ β C n 2 / 8 β 1 β Δ A T P 2 / 16 C L -
R ϕ β C n 2 / 16 β 1 β Δ A T P 2 / 16 C L 2 -
T P C L ϕ β C n 2 / Δ A T P 2 16 C L β Δ A T P 2 2 -
T 3 / 4 β Δ A T P 2 / 64 C L ϕ β C n 2 / 4 β 1 β Δ A T P 2 / 16 C L 2 ϕ β C n 2 / 4 β 1 β Δ A j 2 / 4 C L
Table 4. Case results.
Table 4. Case results.
Model MModel M-CModel RModel R-CModel TPModel TP-C
p 82,55473,77280,98871,01282,04367,021
w 74,12256,47874,50050,93273,09542,914
e 168634592002401617904821
τ 0.1240.2540.2940.5890.1750.943
M 6.105 × 1098.178 × 1097.249 × 1099.714 × 1096.478 × 1091.082 × 1010
R 3.128 × 1094.343 × 1093.634 × 1094.824 × 1093.523 × 1096.137 × 109
T P ----2.755 × 1084.989 × 108
T 9.233 × 1091.252 × 10101.088 × 10101.454 × 10101.028 × 10101.745 × 1010
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Tian, T.; Zheng, C.; Yang, L.; Luo, X.; Lu, L. Optimal Recycling Channel Selection of Power Battery Closed-Loop Supply Chain Considering Corporate Social Responsibility in China. Sustainability 2022, 14, 16712. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142416712

AMA Style

Tian T, Zheng C, Yang L, Luo X, Lu L. Optimal Recycling Channel Selection of Power Battery Closed-Loop Supply Chain Considering Corporate Social Responsibility in China. Sustainability. 2022; 14(24):16712. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142416712

Chicago/Turabian Style

Tian, Tianle, Chuiyong Zheng, Liguo Yang, Xiaochun Luo, and Lin Lu. 2022. "Optimal Recycling Channel Selection of Power Battery Closed-Loop Supply Chain Considering Corporate Social Responsibility in China" Sustainability 14, no. 24: 16712. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142416712

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop