1. Introduction
Since the 1998 reform of the housing institution in China, investment in real estate has increased, particularly since 2003. Investment by real estate development enterprises rose from 361.4 billion RMB in 1998 to 1015.3 billion RMB in 2003, and subsequently sharply increased to 9503.6 billion RMB by 2014 (Data source: China Statistic Yearbooks of 2004 and 2015.). In addition to real estate development enterprises (suppliers), individuals and institutions (customers) also contributed to the real estate investment increase; because of the expectation that there would be a dramatic rise in housing demand, the housing prices accompanying urbanization development also spiked. Real estate was a desirable investment financially because of a lack of investment goods in China. More and more funds from customers were invested in real estate in search of house price appreciation profits, such as the Wenzhou house speculation groups. Such investments, particularly speculative demand, led to an overheated real estate industry thus further boosting the housing price upswing.
There was also excessive investment in real estate in Japan during the 1980s and the United States during the 2000s; however, the Chinese real estate market is unique. The Chinese real estate market behaves differently than the US or UK markets because of differences in the political environment, legal systems, and culture, as Wang and Wang point out [
1]. One important difference is that all urban land in China is owned by the state, and local governments have a strong power on the real estate market by controlling land release and granting development rights. Liu et al. [
2] state that, in recent years, local governments in China have significantly increased their land development by acquiring land from farmers and leasing it on a large scale to industrial and commercial developers. They argue that local land development has contributed to an investment-driven growth in China that is not sustainable in the long run. Based on panel data covering all provinces from 1998 to 2005, they find that the impact of public land leasing stimulated local fiscal revenue and gross domestic product. Liu et al. [
3] also point out that the local state-dominated model of administrative urbanization in China differs markedly from the urban growth model in Western nations. Land-based urban development can rapidly produce dramatic economic and urban outcomes, but whether these are beneficial to the urban and rural residents is not clear. Both the investment-driven growth of Liu et al. [
2] and the administrative urbanization of Liu et al. [
3] are based on land and are led by local government. It seems that local government-led land-based investment or development accompanying urbanization drove growth in China. Lai [
4] asserts that there was very excessive infrastructure and real estate investment in China from 2003 because of the inappropriate growth strategy. Under this complex and unique context, it is relevant to discuss how funds are invested in real estate, and the leading role of local government in the process. Various studies have discussed the importance of local government in land leasing; however, most do not clearly distinguish and connect the “land fiscal revenue” and “land finance” of local government, and are limited to descriptive analysis. This paper will clarify the “land fiscal revenue” and “land finance” process of local government by institutional analysis and then empirically evidence it.
In addition to the state-owned land system, other unique characteristics contribute to the high investment in the real estate industry. Cary [
5] asserts that the revenue sharing system, a weak banking framework and the lack of investment opportunities also drove the overheated economy in China. Zhang and Sun [
6] point out that the real estate situation included risks of real estate credit exposure, government guarantees, and maturity mismatches and suggested advancing banking reform, encouraging local government rationality and strengthening the regulation of foreign capital flows in and out of the Chinese real estate industry. Hence, besides local government, the banking sector, the private sector (individuals), and the foreign sector all played important roles. The banking sector provides loans to the local government, real estate development enterprises and individuals, while the private sector and foreign sector funds speculate on real estate. As Su and Tao [
7] highlight, the financial ties between local governments, real estate developers, and banks that share the common goal of city expansion have forged a strong growth coalition in China’s local landscape. Thus, it is worth studying the various roles of different participants in the process of investment in real estate. Some studies [
8,
9,
10,
11] discuss the influence of bank credit and foreign funds on housing prices in China; however, how these funds are invested in real estate is not fully known and there are few empirical studies on the effect of private funds (funds from individuals) on housing prices. Thus, this paper is a tentative study in this field.
If housing prices decrease, local governments will be trapped in a serious debt crisis, and banks, real estate enterprises, and speculations from private and foreign sectors that withdraw late from the market would face huge losses. The situation in China at present is very similar to developments in 1980s Japan—a very risky and unsustainable position. This paper aims to address some urgent issues that have not yet been clearly studied. How are funds being invested in real estate? What roles do the different economic participants play in this process, particularly the leading role of local government? What are their influences on housing prices? By studying these issues, this paper tries to clarify different investments in real estate and thus understand speculative demand, and propose some policy suggestions by testing the efficiency and effectiveness of current local government development strategies. As Wang and Wang [
1] emphasize, China is an ideal laboratory to study the influence of speculative demand versus fundamentals on property prices.
Section 2 analyzes the process of local government-led investment-driven growth in real estate prices. The roles of local governments, the banking sector, real estate development enterprises, individuals, and the foreign sector are discussed. Based on the theoretical model of real estate investment explained in
Section 2,
Section 3 empirically tests the role of local government in real estate investment and thus housing prices by a panel VAR model, and analyzes the dynamic effects of different investment types on housing prices by three other VAR models.
Section 4 outlines conclusions.
3. Empirical Test
Section 2 analyzed local government-led investment in real estate, and the roles of different participants in the process. To further grasp the importance of each participant, this section will empirically examine their effects on housing prices.
3.1. Data and Methodology
3.1.1. Data
With respect to local government-related variables, because of the lack of high frequency time series (quarterly or monthly) data, this study collected annual panel data for the 31 provinces/autonomous regions in China from 2003 to 2011 to fulfill empirical analysis. The area of land leased (AL) is used as a proxy of local governments’ land leasing level. Local government general fiscal revenue (GR) represents the fiscal revenue level, where extra-budgetary revenue is excluded. Since all leasing fees enter into extra-budgetary revenue, both are certainly positively connected and there is no need to include extra-budgetary revenue in the empirical analysis. The average commercialized building price (AP) in each province or autonomous region is adopted for the housing price level. These variables are expressed in logarithmic form and expressed as LAL, LGR and LAP, respectively. All the data are from [
12,
17,
18].
Panel provincial data are unavailable for funds-related variables, such as real estate development loans, housing purchasing loans, real estate trust products, and hot money; thus, this paper uses national quarterly time series data from 2003 to 2012 for empirical discussion. The AP is more consistent than the house price index (the method of calculating the housing price index was reformed twice—2005 and 2011—thus there are no consistent successive housing price index data from 2003 to 2012 in China [
24]); hence it is adopted to represent the housing price level. Real estate development outstanding loans from financial institutions (DL) and house purchasing outstanding loans (PL) compose the investment in real estate from bank credit. The values of issued real estate trust product (RT) are used as a proxy for private funds invested in real estate as there is no exact data on these. RTs are not only important for the financing of real estate development enterprises, but are also popular with speculative funds from individuals. These are the only data available among private funds invested in real estate. Moreover, there are no exact data for foreign funds invested in real estate, while FDI and hot money (abbreviated as “HM” in the model) are available or countable. Please note that Hot money is a term most commonly used in financial markets to refer to the flow of funds (or capital) from one country to another to earn a short-term profit on interest rate differences and/or anticipated exchange rate shifts. These speculative capital flows are called hot money because they can move very quickly in and out of markets, potentially leading to market instability [
25].
Martin and Morrison [
25] assert that because hot money flows quickly and is poorly monitored, there is no well-defined method for estimating the amount flowing into a country in a set period. Existing literature mainly uses two methods to approximate the amount of hot money: the direct method, the sum of specific variables that constitute hot money; and the indirect method that captures hot money as a residual of other variables (see
Table 9). Because of data limitation in China (The data for “Net flows of non-FDI, non-portfolio investment assets and liabilities held by entities other than the monetary authorities, general government, and banks”, “net flows of non-FDI, non-portfolio investment assets and liabilities held by banks”, and “Portfolio flows” are not available in the International Balance of Payments for China), we cannot follow the direct method of Loungani and Mauro [
26], Prasad and Wei [
27], and Cheung and Qian [
28]. The definitions of “excessive surplus of foreign trade” and “excessive current transfer” developed by Liu [
29] are also too comprehensive to identify, whereas the indirect method, “hot money = the change in foreign exchange reserves—foreign trade surplus (or deficit)—net flow of foreign direct investment (FDI)”, is more feasible as data is more readily available. (Please note that Zhang and Shen [
30] developed a definition for “normal surplus of foreign trade”, though it remains difficult to identify the “normal” part. The International Balance of Payments Analysis Group of the State Administration of Foreign Exchange [
31] approximate annual hot money; however, “investment yield” quarterly data are not available.) However, extant literature on China uses data from different departments to approximate hot money. For example, data on foreign exchange reserves are from the Administration of Exchange Control, on foreign trade surplus are from the Ministry of Commerce, and on FDI are from the Customs Administration. Although, for the same variable, details are distinct across departments. In fact, hot money is a cross-country fund flow, and the International Balance of Payments is the most accurate record of fund inflows and outflows. Therefore, this paper uses quarterly International Balance of Payments from the Finance Institution Database of the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences data to approximate hot money and FDI.
All the above variables are expressed in logarithmic form, seasonally adjusted using the X11 method, and expressed as LDL, LPL, LRT, LFDI and LHM, respectively. Data are sourced from the State Statistical Bureau, the People’s Bank of China, the use-trust network, the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences Database and the Tsinghua Financial Database.
The sample period is from 2003: 2Q–2012: 4Q. The first year is chosen as 2003 because house prices started increasing sharply at that point. Liu [
28] finds that the financial reform since 2003 drastically promoted money supply, and thus greatly strengthened the influence of money on house prices. Further, data on loans to the real estate industry have only been available since 2003: 2Q.
3.1.2. Methodology
Sims [
35] proposed VARs to conduct a dynamic analysis of a system where changes to a particular variable are affected by changes to other variables, the lags of those variables, and the changes in its own lags. The VAR technique is broadly used in the analysis of financial factors and asset markets [
36,
37,
38,
39]. However, the traditional unrestricted VAR has inherent problems. As Pesaran and Shin [
38] contend, “the underlying shocks to the VAR model are orthogonalized using the Cholesky decomposition before impulse responses, or forecast error variance decompositions are computed. This approach is not, however, invariant to the ordering of the variables in the VAR”. Consequently, the structural VAR model is developed by Bernanke [
40], Blanchard and Quad [
41], Sims [
42], and Blanchard and Watson [
43]. Dekker et al. [
36] refer to “imposing a priori restrictions on the covariance matrix of the structural errors and the contemporaneous and/or long-run impulse responses to themselves”. Nevertheless, the number of restrictions positively relates to the number of variables, and it is sometimes difficult to impose a priori assumptions because of complex economic situations. The generalized approach to VAR was advanced by Koop et al. [
44] for nonlinear dynamic systems and by Pesaran and Shin [
33] for linear systems to overcome the above limitations. It is used in financial problem and real estate market studies, such as Dekker et al. [
36], and Ewing and Thompson [
45]. Guided by these scholars, this paper uses the generalized VAR technique.
An m-dimensional and p-order vector autoregressive model is presented as follows.
where
is an
vector of endogenous variables, jointly determined by its own lags and the lags of other variables.
is a
vector for the fixed effect,
are
coefficient matrices, and
is an
matrix of unobserved shocks (disturbances). The matrix form of
is presented below.
A panel VAR model has the same structure as a VAR model, in the sense that all variables are assumed to be endogenous and interdependent, but a cross-sectional dimension is added to the representation. A panel VAR of
p-order is
where
t = 1, 2, …,
T is the time index;
j = 1, …,
N indicates the generic term for the sectional dimension, such as countries, sectors, markets or combinations of these;
is an
vector for section
j with
m variables;
is a
vector for the section-specific;
are
coefficient matrices as shown in (2); and
is an
vector of random disturbances.
3.2. Modeling
As
Section 2 shows, local governments try to increase their fiscal revenue through disparate land supply strategies for different sectors, and through facilitating the investment in real estate and real estate prices. Therefore, to further examine the relationship between land leasing, local government revenues and housing price levels, a panel VAR model with data for LAL, LGR and LAP in 31 provinces/autonomous regions will be established.
Funds invested in real estate mainly come from the banking sector (bank credit), individuals (private funds), and the foreign sector (foreign funds). Thus, we will establish three VAR models for the three investment types to examine their respective effects on housing prices. We use quarterly time series data since 31 provinces’ panel data for most funds are not available. Series (1) is investment in real estate from bank credit with LDL, LPL and LAP data sets. Series (2) is investment from private funds with LRT and LAP variables. System (3) is investment from foreign funds using LFDI, LHM and LAP.
First, the stationarity of all series is examined. Two tests, the Levin, Lin and Chu test and the PP-Fisher Chi-square test, are applied to the panel data to ensure accuracy (
Table 10). All the first difference series DLAL, DLGR, DLAP refuse the null assumption of common unit root (Levin, Lin and Chu test) and that of individual unit root (both tests) at the 1% level. Therefore, the first difference series, DLAL, DLGR, DLAP, enters into the panel VAR model. For the time series data, the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test is adopted, as shown by
Table 11. All the series are I (1) at the 1% level. Thus, their first difference series, DLDL, DLPL, DLRT, DLFDI, DLHM and DLAP, enters into the VAR models.
A panel VAR model and three VAR models are established as follows. For local government-related analysis, the panel VAR consists of the first difference series of DLAL, DLGR, DLAP, with a two-lag length (the principles of LR, FPE and AIC suggest a two-lag length for the panel VAR model.). For fund-related models, bank credit is represented by Model (1), where the first difference series of DLDL, DLPL and DLAP are introduced. Private funds are explained by Model (2), comprised of the first difference series of DLRT and DLAP. Model (3) shows foreign funds and contains the first difference series of DLFDI, DLHM and DLAP. Model (1) hints at a two-lag length, and Model (2) and Model (3) have a one-lag length. The principles of LR, FPE, AIC and HQ hint a two-lag length for VAR models (1). The principles of LR, FPE, AIC, and HQ hint a one-lag length for VAR model (2). The principles of LR, FPE and AIC hint a one-lag length for VAR model (3).
The panel VAR model and all three VAR models described above are estimated using the EViews 6.0 software and successfully pass the AR root test, implying that they are stable. The impulse response analysis based on the estimated VARs could be used to trace the dynamic responses of each variable to the innovations in a particular variable in the system.
3.3. Results of Impulse Response Analysis
The generalized impulse response functions results of the panel VAR model are illustrated in
Figure 2. Following a 1% positive shock to DLAL (A 1% positive shock to “DLAL” or a 1% positive “DLAL” shock means a 1% positive shock in “DLAL”, that is, the one positive standard deviation innovation to the increment of logarithmic “area of land leased”; this holds for a shock to “DLGR”, “DLAP”, “DLDL”, “DLPL”, “DLTR”, “DLFDI” and “DLHM”), the DLGR response peaks at 2.14% in the second period, suggesting that land leasing could promote local government general fiscal revenue. This is consistent with the analysis in
Section 2.1 that local governments could increase tax revenue from the manufacturing sector and other land-related revenue through land leasing in budgetary revenue, in addition to land leasing fees. That is why local governments supply industrial land at a low price while limiting the commercial and residential land supply to raise leasing prices. After a 1% positive shock to DLAP, DLGR also responds positively and peaks at 1.77% in the second period. This implies that high housing prices could bring more fiscal revenue to local governments. Thus, local government is strongly incentivized to raise real estate price levels. With a 1% positive shock to DLAL, the DLAP response reaches a peak of −0.93% in the second period, showing that housing price levels would decrease by increasing land supply. Therefore, to raise the real estate price level and thus fiscal revenue, local governments limit the land supply to commercial and residential projects (as discussed in
Section 2.1). However, to control high housing prices, a suggested policy option would be to increase land supply.
The generalized impulse response functions results of model (1), bank credit, are shown in
Figure 3. Following a 1% positive shock to DLDL, DLAP has a very limited response at 0.23% in the first quarter and −0.14% in the third quarter. This suggests that the expansion of bank credit to real estate development enterprises would not decrease housing prices. This is because, in a seller’s market, local governments together with banks and real estate development enterprises forged a coalition to raise investment in real estate and real estate prices, as analyzed in
Section 2. When a 1% positive shock to DLPL occurs, DLAP respond at 2.11% in the first quarter, showing that expansion of house purchasing loans could increase the housing demand and thus housing prices.
Both DLDL and DLPL respond positively following a 1% positive DLAP shock, peaking at 0.80% in the second period and 1.57% in the third period, respectively, suggesting that upswings in housing prices encourage the expansion of bank credit to the real estate industry. With an increase in housing prices and high liquidity levels, banks consider real estate as prime collateral and drastically increase loans to the real estate industry.
The generalized impulse response functions results of model (2), private funds, are described in
Figure 4. The response of DLAP to a 1% positive DLRT shock is greatest at −0.81% in the second quarter, turning to 0.42% in the third quarter. In China, the issued real estate trust products were mainly based on the mortgage of real estate development projects. In other words, after real estate development enterprises mortgage their projects to trusts, the trusts collect funds from individuals by issuing real estate trust products, and these funds indirectly flow to the real estate development enterprises. Therefore, real estate products could help real estate development enterprises obtain funds to increase the housing supply, potentially decreasing housing prices. However, most private funds are used to purchase houses directly by individuals; this could increase the housing demand and thus housing prices.
Interestingly, DLRT peaks at 3.0% in the first quarter following a 1% positive DLAP shock. This illustrates that house price upswings greatly elicit speculation by individuals in real estate trust products, which is consistent with the discussion in
Section 2.5.
Figure 5 shows the generalized impulse response function results of model (3), foreign funds. When there is a 1% positive shock to DLFDI, the DLAP response peaks at 1.33% in the second quarter. Following a 1% positive DLHM shock, the strongest DLAP response of 0.73% is in the second quarter. These imply that foreign fund inflows including both FDI and hot money stimulate housing price increases. As Liu [
23] asserts, foreign funds not only directly buy land and houses, they also indirectly promote money supply and thus housing prices.
Noticeably, after a 1% positive shock to DLAP, the DLHM response is greatest at 3.62% in the second quarter. This shows that housing price rises strongly stimulate the speculation in real estate from hot money.
3.4. Discussion
Based on the above analysis, the panel VAR model shows that both land leasing (DLAL) and high housing price levels (DLAP) positively affect the general fiscal revenue of local governments (DLGR), at 2.14% and 1.77%, respectively. An increase in land supply (DLAL) would decrease housing prices (−0.93%). The three VAR models for the three different types of funds invested in real estate find that a house purchasing loan shock (DLPL) has the largest positive effect (2.11%) on housing prices (DLAP), while a real estate development loan shock (DLDL) has a very limited effect. Foreign funds also have important positive effects on housing prices. DLAP has a 1.3% response to a 1% positive DLFDI shock, and a 0.73% response to a 1% positive DLHM shock. Interestingly, a housing price shock (DLAP) has very large positive influences on bank loans (0.8% and 1.57% on DLDL and DLPL, respectively), private funds (3.00% on DLRT), and hot money (3.62% on DLHM).
These are consistent with the discussion in
Section 2 that local governments are incentivized to increase the supply of industrial land at a low price because of the offset from future tax revenue in general fiscal revenue and economic development, while limiting commercial and residential land supply to raise leasing prices and thus extra-budgetary revenue. Banks provide funds for the development of the real estate industry, and together with local governments and real estate development enterprises, facilitate real estate price appreciation. The increase in housing prices attracts heavy speculation in real estate from individuals, and the foreign sector that further raises the housing price level. This process is a local government-led investment-driven growth, although releasing land for industrial, rather than for residential or commercial uses, might be rational for regional economic growth in the long term. The subsequent high residential/commercial land leasing prices and thus soaring housing prices bring numerous speculation from various sectors, which is risky.
With the development boom of industrial parks and zones by land mortgage loans, local governments suffer from high debts. The National Audit Office reported their excessive debt repayment obligations in 2012 of 14.41%, 17.36% and 26.59% at provincial, city and county levels, respectively. There were already 358 existing LGFVs borrowed new loans to repay 2010 maturity loans which accounted for 55.2% of the total maturity loans of these LGFVs on average. With the expectation of real estate price appreciation, local governments still compete to expand their loans to develop industrial zones and parks, real estate enterprises still rush to reserve commercial and residential lands at sizable costs, individuals still run for purchasing houses, and banks still increasingly provide loans to them.
However, housing prices are already at high levels. According to the 2016 research report of R&D Institute of E-house China [
46], the average housing price income ratio in Chinese 35 large cities was 10.2 in 2015, of which Shenzhen occupied the first place with a high ratio of 27.7. These are much higher than the reasonable range of 6.0–7.0. Once housing prices decrease, local governments would face a serious debt crisis from declining land values, properties developed by real estate enterprises would be unsellable, individuals would bear enormous losses [
47,
48], and banks could not recover their loans, which might finally cause financial and even economic crisis. The outcome of developments in Japan in the 1980s is a valuable lesson.
4. Conclusions
This paper established the theoretical model of real estate investment from the main four sectors in China. Led by the local government, a combination of the banking sector, individuals, and the foreign sector excessively expanded investment in real estate which highly drove the growth in real estate prices. Based on the VAR (Vector Auto Regression) methodology, the dynamic effects of these four sectors on housing prices are empirically examined. The main findings are as follows.
First, because of their monopoly on land supply, in order to increase their total fiscal revenue, local governments provide industrial land at a low price (or even with subsidies) for future tax revenue and local economic development, while limiting the supply of commercial and residential land to raise leasing prices and thus extra-budgetary revenue. These are the essential contents of land revenue. Moreover, local governments obtain bank loans through their underlying local government financing vehicles (LGFVs) by land mortgage to develop industrial zones and parks that could attract industrial and thus commercial investment and further raise leasing prices. This process is known as land finance. Local governments tend to form coalitions for real estate investment where, together with banks and real estate development enterprises, they expand real estate development and raise real estate prices. Soaring real estate prices attract speculation from private and foreign funds, further increasing housing price levels. This is similar with the investment-driven growth of Liu et al. [
2] and the administrative urbanization of Liu et al. [
3], but we further analyzed the detailed process of local government-led investment in real estate, and clarified the roles played by different participants in the development model.
The panel VAR model proves that land leasing has a strong positive effect on local governments’ general fiscal revenue, explaining why local governments increase the supply of industrial land at low prices. Housing price increases also positively affect a local government’s general fiscal revenue, thus local governments are incentivized to facilitate investment in real estate and increase real estate prices. Land supply has a negative effect on the housing price level, explaining why local governments limit the commercial and residential land supplies. Consequently, local governments play a leading role in developing investment in real estate and increasing real estate prices. These proved the opinion of land revenue of Su and Tao [
7] and the different supply strategies of local governments towards different types of land [
13] through empirical analysis instead of descriptive analysis only.
Second, the banking sector provides the majority of funds invested in real estate. The VAR models on the different investment types showed that house purchase loans have the largest effect (2.14%) on housing prices, suggesting that the banking sector facilitates the investment in real estate and increases housing prices through its financial ties. Real estate development loans have a limited effect on housing prices because, in a seller’s market, real estate development enterprises translate high land leasing prices into high housing prices, and further raise housing prices to get more profit. The increase in housing prices also positively influences house purchase loans (1.57%) and real estate development loans (0.8%), suggesting that the banking sector expands credit to the real estate industry with housing price appreciation. This is consistent with the point made by Liang and Cao [
8], and we further discussed the credit expansion to both sides of supply and demand of real estate.
Third, many private funds also invest in real estate, most of which are used to purchase houses directly, which could increase housing demand and thus housing prices. The VAR model results for private funds show that an upswing in housing prices has a strong positive effect (3.00%) on real estate trust products. This implies that an increase in housing prices attracts heavy speculation from individuals. This is in agreement with Liu [
24] and Guo [
23], albeit by employing empirical tests in addition to citing speculative phenomena in real estate.
Finally, there is heavy foreign sector investment in real estate. The VAR model for foreign funds shows that both FDI and hot money have a strong positive influence on housing prices, at 1.30% and 0.73%, respectively. This implies that foreign fund speculation stimulates the growth in housing prices, which is consistent with the views of He and Zhu [
9], He et al. [
10] and Guo and Huang [
11]. Notably, the upswing in housing prices also has a significant positive effect (3.62%) on hot money, suggesting that housing price appreciation stimulates strong speculation from foreign funds. This provided empirical evidence to round out the solely descriptive discussion in the existing literature.
Of course, our study also suffers from some limitations. Owing to the data unavailability of provincial or city levels, such as house purchase loans, real estate development loans, real estate trust products and hot money, we limited to the general real estate investment pattern in the whole nation. With respect to a specific city or region, the pattern might be somewhat stronger or weaker than the general situation as a result of the local features. The regional differences among various provinces or cities on real estate investment could be a future research direction.