Next Article in Journal
POISE: Efficient Cross-Domain Chinese Named Entity Recognization via Transfer Learning
Next Article in Special Issue
Hesitant Fuzzy Sets Based Symmetrical Model of Decision-Making for Estimating the Durability of Web Application
Previous Article in Journal
Symmetric Identities for Carlitz’s Type Higher-Order (p,q)-Genocchi Polynomials
Previous Article in Special Issue
Fuzzy Model Identification Using Monolithic and Structured Approaches in Decision Problems with Partially Incomplete Data
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

On Application Oriented Fuzzy Numbers for Imprecise Investment Recommendations

by
Anna Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak
Institute of Economy and Finance, WSB University in Poznan, ul. Powstańców Wielkopolskich 5, 61-895 Poznań, Poland
Symmetry 2020, 12(10), 1672; https://doi.org/10.3390/sym12101672
Submission received: 17 September 2020 / Revised: 5 October 2020 / Accepted: 10 October 2020 / Published: 13 October 2020

Abstract

:
The subtraction of fuzzy numbers (FNs) is not an inverse operator to FNs addition. The family of all oriented FNs (OFNs) may be considered as symmetrical closure of all the FNs family in that the subtraction is an inverse operation to addition. An imprecise present value is modelled by a trapezoidal oriented FN (TrOFN). Then, the expected discount factor (EDF) is a TrOFFN too. This factor may be applied as a premise for invest-making. Proposed decision strategies are dependent on a comparison of an oriented fuzzy profit index and the specific profitability threshold. This way we get an investment recommendation described as a fuzzy subset on the fixed rating scale. Risk premium measure is a special case of profit index. Further in the paper, the Sharpe’s ratio, the Jensen’s ratio, the Treynor’s ratio, the Sortino’s ratio, Roy’s criterion and the Modiglianis’ coefficient are generalised for the case when an EDF is given as a TrOFN. In this way, we get many different imprecise recommendations. For this reason, an imprecise recommendation management module is described. Obtained results show that the proposed theory can be used as a theoretical background for financial robo-advisers. All theoretical considerations are illustrated by means of a simple empirical case study.

1. Introduction

Imprecision is a natural feature of financial market information. A widely accepted way of representing an imprecise number is a fuzzy number (FN). The notion of an ordered FN was intuitively introduced by Kosiński et al. [1]. It was defined as an FN supplemented by its orientation. A significant drawback of Kosiński’s theory is that there exists such ordered FNs that cannot be considered as FN [2]. This caused the original Kosiński’s theory to be revised by Piasecki [3]. At present, the ordered FNs defined within Kosiński’s original theory are called Kosiński’s numbers [4,5,6,7]. If ordered FNs are linked to the revised theory, then they are called Oriented FNs (OFNs) [6,7].
The family of all OFNs has a symmetry axis that is equal to the family of all real numbers. In Section 2, this axial symmetry is described in detail. The family of all OFNs may be defined equivalently with the use of the discussed axial symmetry as the symmetrical closure of all of the FNs family. Symmetry allows us to avoid problems related to the fact that FNs subtraction is not an inverse operator to FNs addition.
A robo-adviser is an internet platform providing an automated financial planning service. This service is always algorithm-driven. Therefore, no robo-adviser requires any human involvement. It implies a minimal operating cost for any robo-advisor. Due to using robo-advisers we can apply different finance models to develop algorithms editing financial advice. Implemented algorithms can inform investors of any change in the market within a short period of time. In this way, robo-advisers efficiently implement any investment strategy by using their built-in automated algorithms [8].
With the development of Fintech, robo-adviser becomes more popular. The fundamental theoretical background of robo-advisers is the classical mean-variance optimisation developed by Markowitz [9]. Nonetheless, this well-known approach is not good [10,11,12]. To obtain algorithms generating more profitable portfolios, researchers take into account an investors’ risk-aversion. Then they construct optimal portfolios by dealing with both conflicting objectives of minimising the risk and maximising the return together in a static manner [11,13,14] and dynamic case [12,15,16]. Since the financial data are imprecise, we can adapt robo-advisers using fuzzy logic [17,18] to financial practice. To the best of my knowledge, no financial robo-advisers using OFNs have been described so far.
To deal with information imprecision, researches develop portfolio selection models with fuzzy theory [19,20,21,22,23,24,25,26,27,28,29,30,31,32,33,34,35,36,37,38,39,40]. In all of the above-mentioned fuzzy models, an imprecision is included by the assumption of fuzzy rates of return from financial instruments given a priori. Then, return rate (RR) from portfolio can only be defined ex cathedra as a weighted sum of RRs assigned to its components. This approach is only justified by the mechanical generalisation of Markowitz’s portfolio theory to the fuzzy case. The proposed generalisation is not justified by a mathematical deduction. This greatly reduces the reliability of performed analyses. It is a significant drawback of all fuzzy portfolio publications stated above.
In general, a present value (PV) is equal to a current equivalent of a payment due at a fixed point in time [41]. PV understood in this way is an imprecise value. For this reason, we can also point out the PV imprecision as the cause of imprecision in the financial analysis. This approach is presented in papers [42,43,44,45,46,47,48,49,50]. Then, with the help of mathematical deduction we can prove that the RR from a portfolio is a linear combination of return rates of their components. This increases the credibility of the performed financial analysis.
Fuzzy PV was proposed by Ward [51] as a discounted fuzzy prediction of a future payment. Buckley [52] proposed fuzzy financial arithmetic. Greenhut [53], Sheen [54] and Huang [22] generalised the definition of Ward. They expanded this definition to the case of a future payment described by a fuzzy variable. In 2005, Tsao [44] generalised a fuzzy PV definition. He assumed that the future payment may be considered as a fuzzy probabilistic set. Those authors described a present value as a discounted, imprecisely evaluated future payment. Piasecki [45,46] proposed a different approach. In this case, PV was imprecisely assessed on the basis of a current asset price. Buckley [52], Gutierrez [55], Kuchta [56] and Lesage [57] showed the purposefulness of applying a trapezoidal FN (TrFN) for fuzzy arithmetic. For this reason, we determine an imprecise PV by means of TrFN. Piasecki [45] showed that if the PV is an FN, then its RR is a fuzzy probabilistic set [58]. Additionally, then the expected RR is an FN. It is a theoretical background for investment-making models described in [46]. Moreover, in [48] it is shown that the fuzzy expected discount factor (EDF) is a better tool for appraising the considered securities than the fuzzy expected RR. Therefore, we use an EDF as a premise for invest-making.
OFNs have already been used by many scientists to describe and analyse many decision-making [59,60,61,62,63,64], financial [65,66,67,68,69,70] and economic [71,72] problems. Among other things, there it is shown that
  • The use of FNs in financial analysis only leads to averaging the imprecision risk,
  • The application of OFNs in financial analysis may minimise imprecision risk.
Therefore, the main aim of this paper is an extension of the investment-making models described in [46] to the case of imprecise PV estimated by trapezoidal OFNs (TrOFNs). The first attempt of this subject was presented in [70]. Here, we use our experience gathered during our work on the other criteria. Therefore, here we present a revised approach to the considered extension.
The paper is drafted as follows. Section 2 presents OFNs with their basic properties and describes the imprecision evaluation by an energy and entropy measure. In Section 3, PV is assessed by TrOFNs. The oriented fuzzy EDF is determined in Section 4. Investment recommendations dependent on the oriented fuzzy EDF are discussed in Section 5. Profitability criteria for investments are extended in Section 6. In Section 7 we explore the management of a set of investment recommendations. Section 8 concludes the article and proposes some future research directions. In Appendix A, the optimisation algorithm used is described in detail.

2. Fuzzy Sets—Selected Facts

2.1. Fuzzy Sets

Fuzzy sets (FSs) [73] are a suitable tool that allows to describe and process imprecise values and information. In a given space X an FS A is distinguished by its membership function μ A [ 0 , 1 ] X in the following manner
A = { ( x , μ A ( x ) ) ; x X }
By ( X ) we denote the family of all FSs in a space X .
Multi-valued operations in the FSs family are defined by means of the following identities:
μ A   B ( x ) = μ A ( x ) μ B ( x ) = max   { μ A ( x ) , μ B ( x ) }
μ A   B ( x ) = μ A ( x ) μ B ( x ) = min   { μ A ( x ) , μ B ( x ) }
μ A C ( x ) = 1 μ A ( x )
FSs are widely used for modelling imprecise information. Following the work in [74], the imprecision is understood as a composition of ambiguity and indistinctness of. Ambiguity is defined a lack of a clear indication of one alternative among others. Indistinctness is defined as a lack of an explicit distinction between distinguished and not distinguished alternatives. More imprecise information is less useful. For this reason, it is sensible to assess the imprecision.
For the finite space X = { x 1 ,   x 2 , , x f } , the suitable tool for assessing the ambiguity of an FS A ( X ) is the energy measure d : ( X ) 0 + [75] given as follows:
d ( A ) = m ( A ) = i = 1 f μ A ( x i )
The proper tool for measuring the indistinctness is the entropy measure e : ( X ) 0 + [76,77] determined by the identity
e ( A ) = m ( A   A C ) m ( A   A C )

2.2. Fuzzy Numbers

The fuzzy number (FN) may be intuitively defined as FS in the real line . The most general FN definition is proposed by Dubois and Prade [78]. Any FN may be defined in an equivalent way as follows [79]:
Theorem 1.
For any FN there exists such a non-decreasing sequence ( a , b , c , d )   that ( a , b , c , d , L L , R L ) = ( ) is determined by its membership function μ L ( · | a , b , c , d , L L , R L ) [ 0 , 1 ] described by the identity
μ L ( x | a , b , c , d , L L , R L ) = {   0 ,                           x [ a , d ] , L L ( x ) ,             x [ a , b ] , 1 ,                             x [ b , c ] , R L ( x ) ,             x [ c , d ] .
where the left reference function L L [ 0 , 1 ] [ a , b ] and the right reference function R L [ 0 , 1 ] [ c , d ] are upper semi-continuous monotonic ones meeting the conditions:
L L ( b ) = R L ( c ) = 1
The family of all FNs is denoted by the symbol F .
The symbol denotes any arithmetic operation defined on . By the symbol we denote such extension of operation to F that it is coherent with Zadeh’s Extension Principle [80]. It means that, for each pair ( K , ) F 2 described by their membership functions μ K , μ L [ 0 , 1 ] , the FN
= K
is described by membership function μ M [ 0 , 1 ] determined by the identity:
μ M ( z ) = sup { min { μ K ( x ) , μ L ( y ) } :   z = x y , ( x , y ) } .
A special case of FNs is trapezoidal FNs (TrFNs). Due to their simplicity and ease of performing operations on them, they are often used in applications. A suitable definition of trapezoidal fuzzy numbers is given in [81]:
Definition 1.
For any non-decreasing sequence ( a , b , c , d ) , a trapezoidal FN (TrFN) is the FN T = T r ( a , b , c , d ) F defined by its membership functions μ T [ 0 , 1 ] in the following way
μ T ( x ) = μ T r ( x | a , b , c , d ) = {   0 ,                         x [ a , d ] , x a b a ,                 x [ a , b ] , 1 ,                         x [ b , c ] , x d c d ,                 x [ c , d ] .

2.3. Oriented Fuzzy Number

Ordered FN was defined by Kosiński et al. [1] as an extension of the FN concept. An important disadvantage of Kosiński’s theory is that there exists such ordered FNs that cannot be represented by a membership function [2]. On the other hand, ordered FNs’ usefulness is a result of their interpretation as FN supplemented by its orientation. The ordered FN orientation describes a forecast of the nearest future changes of FN. This caused Kosiński’s theory to be revised by Piasecki [3]. An ordered FN linked to the revised theory is called Oriented FN (OFN) [6,7]. In a general case, OFNs are defined as follows:
Definition 2
[3]. For any monotonic sequence ( a , b , c , d ) , the oriented fuzzy number OFN ( a , b , c , d , S L , E L ) = is a pair of an orientation a , d = ( a , d ) and a fuzzy set ( ) described by a membership function μ L ( | a , b , c , d , S L , E L ) [ 0 , 1 ] given by the identity
μ L ( x | a , b , c , d , S L , E L ) = {   0 ,                               x [ a , d ] [ d , a ] , S L ( x ) ,                 x [ a , b ] [ b , a ] , 1 ,                                 x [ b , c ] [ c , b ] , E L ( x ) ,               x [ c , d ] [ d , c ] ,
where the starting function S L [ 0 , 1 ] [ a , b ] and the ending function E L [ 0 , 1 ] [ c , d ] are upper semi-continuous monotonic ones meeting the condition
x [ a , d ]   :   μ L ( x | a , b , c , d , S L , E L )
The symbol K denotes the space of all OFNs. If a < d , then any ( a , b , c , d , S L , E L ) is a positively oriented OFN. Any positively oriented OFN may be interpreted as such FN, which can increase in the near future. The symbol K + denotes the space of all positively oriented OFN. If a > d , then any ( a , b , c , d , S L , E L ) is a negatively oriented OFN, which may be interpreted as decreasing FN. The symbol K denotes the space of all negatively oriented OFN. For a = d , ( a , b , c , d , S L , E L ) = a represents the unoriented crisp number a . Summing up, we see that
K +     K = K
Let us consider the mapping U : K K given by identity
U ( ( a , b , c , d , S L , E L ) ) = ( d , c , b , a , E L , S L )
This mapping meets following conditions:
K + U ( ) K
K U ( ) K +
U ( ) =
It shows that the mapping (15) is axial symmetry on the space K of all OFNs. Then the symmetry axis is identical with family of all real numbers. Moreover, Theorem 1 together with Definition 2 implies that the space F of FNs and the space K + of all positively oriented OFNs are isomorphic. Therefore, we can say that the space K may be determined as symmetry closure of the space F .
In the studies planned here, we limit discussion to a special kind of OFNs defined as follows.
Definition 3
[3]. For any monotonic sequence ( a , b , c , d ) , the trapezoidal OFN (TrOFN) T r ( a , b , c , d ) = T is the pair of the orientation a , d = ( a , d ) and a fuzzy set T ( ) determined by membership functions μ T [ 0 , 1 ] as follows
μ T ( x ) = μ T r ( x | a , b , c , d ) = {   0 ,                         x [ a , d ] [ d , a ] , x a b a ,                 x [ a ,   b ] [ b , a ] , 1 ,                         x [ b , c ] [ c , b ] , x d c d ,                 x [ c , d ] [ d , c ] .
The symbol K T r denotes the space of all TrOFNs.On the space K T r , a relation K . G E ˜ . was defined as follows
K . G E ˜ . T r O F N   K   i s   g r e a t e r   t h a n   o r   e q u a l   t o   T r O F N  
This is a fuzzy preorder G E ˜ ( K T r × K T r ) described by membership function ν G E [ 0 , 1 ] K T r × K T r described in detail in [6]. Due to these results, for any pair ( T r ( a , b , c , d ) , h ) K T r × we have:
ν G E ( T r ( a , b , c , d ) , h ) = {   0 ,                         h > max { a , d } , h max { a , d } max { b , c } max { a , d } ,                 max { a , d } h > max { b , c } , 1 ,                         max { b , c } h ,
ν G E ( h , T r ( a , b , c , d ) ) = {   0 ,                         h < min { a , d } , h min { a , d } min { b , c } min { a , d }                 min { a , d } h < min { b , c } , 1 ,                         min { b , c } h .

3. Oriented Present Value

The present value (PV) is defined as a current equivalent of a payment due at fixed point in time [41]. Therefore, we commonly accept that PV of future payments may be imprecise. This means that PV should be assessed with FNs. Such PV is called a fuzzy one. Buckley [52], Gutierrez [55], Kuchta [56] and Lesage [57] show the soundness of using TrFNs as an imprecise financial arithmetic tool. Moreover, PV estimation should be supplemented by a forecast of PV closest price changes. These price changes may be subjectively predicted. Moreover, closest price changes may be predicted with the help of the prediction tables presented in [82]. For these reasons, an imprecise PV should be evaluated by OFN [7,70]. Such PV is called an oriented PV (O-PV). Any O-PV is estimated by TrOFN
P V = T r ( V s ,   V f ,   V l ,   V e )
where the monotonic sequence ( V s ,   V f ,   P ˇ ,   V l ,   V e ) is defined as follows
  • P ˇ is a quoted price,
  • [ V s , V e ] + is the set of all possible values of PV,
  • [ V f , V l ] [ V s , V e ] is the set of all values that do not noticeably differ from the quoted price P ˇ .
If we predict a rise in price then O-PV is described by a positively oriented TrOFN. If we predict a fall in price, then O-PV is described by a negatively oriented OFN.
Example 1.
We observe the portfolio π composed of company shares included in WIG20 quoted on the Warsaw Stock Exchange (WSE). Based on a session closing on the WSE on 28 January 2020, for each observed share we assess its O-PV equal to TrOFN describing its Japanese candle [83]. Shares’ O-PVs, obtained in such a manner, are presented in Table 1. For each portfolio component S ^ , we determine its quoted price P ˇ s as an initial price on 29.01.2020.
CCC, CDR, CPS, DNP, JWS, KGH, LPP, OPL, PEO, PGE, PKO, PLY, PZU, SPL and TPE are evaluated by a positively oriented PV, which predicts a rise in a quoted price. Similarly, the stock companies ALR, LTS, MBK, PGN and PKN are evaluated by a negatively oriented PV, which predicts a fall in the quoted price.

4. Oriented Expected Discount Factor

We assume that duration t > 0 of an investment is fixed. Then, the considered security is determined by two values: a foreseen F V = V t and an estimated P V = V 0 . The benefits from owning this security are characterised by the simple return rate (RR) defined by the identity
r t = V t V 0 V 0
Variable FV is described by a relation
V ˜ t ( ω ) = P ˇ · ( 1 + r ˜ t ( ω ) )
where the simple RR r ˜ t : Ω is determined for PV assessed as the quoted price P ˇ . After Markowitz [9] we assume that the RR r ˜ rate is the gaussian probability distribution N ( r ¯ ,   σ ) .
In our case PV is determined as O-PV P V = T r ( V s ,   V f ,   V l ,   V e ) represented by its membership function μ P v [ 0 ; 1 ] given by the identity
μ P V ( x ) = μ T r ( x | V s ,   V f ,   V l ,   V e )
According to (10), the simple RR calculated for the O-PV is a fuzzy probabilistic set represented by membership function ρ ˜ [ 0 ; 1 ] × Ω given as follows
ρ ˜ ( r , ω ) = sup { μ P V ( x ) :   r = V t ( ω ) x x ,   x } = μ P V ( V t ( ω ) 1 + r ) = μ P V ( P ˇ · 1 + r ( ω ) 1 + r )
Then, the membership function ρ [ 0 ; 1 ] of the expected RR is computed in the following manner
ρ ( r ) = + μ P V ( P ˇ · 1 + y 1 + r ) d F r ( y ) = μ P V ( P ˇ · 1 + r ¯ 1 + r )
In [48] it is shown that the fuzzy expected discount factor (EDF) is a better tool for appraising any securities than the expected fuzzy RR. Therefore, we determine EDF for the case of O-PV. In general, for a given RR r t , the discount factor v t is explicitly determined by the identity
v t = 1 1 + r t
We consider the EDF v ¯ defined by the identity:
v ¯ = 1 1 + r ¯
In line with (28), the membership function δ [ 0 , 1 ] of an oriented fuzzy EDF (O-EDF) V K is given by the identity:
δ ( v ) = ρ ( 1 v 1 ) = μ P V ( P ˇ · 1 + r ¯ 1 + 1 v 1 ) = μ P V ( P ˇ · v v ¯ ) = μ T r ( v | V s · υ ¯ P ˇ , V f · υ ¯ P ˇ , V l · υ ¯ P ˇ , V e · υ ¯ P ˇ )
Then, O-EDF is given as follows:
V = T r ( V s P ˇ · υ ¯ , V f P ˇ · υ ¯ ,   V l P ˇ · υ ¯ , V e P ˇ · υ ¯ )
Example 2.
All considerations in the paper are run for the quarterly period of the investment time t = 1   q u a r t e r . We research the components of the portfolio π presented in Table 1. Using the one-year time series of quotations, for each portfolio component S ^ we calculate the following parameters:
  • Expected RR r ¯ s ,
  • CAPM directional factor β s ,
  • Variance σ s 2 ,
  • Downside semi variance ς s 2 .
With the application of (30) and (32), we calculated quarterly O-EDF for each component of the portfolio π . All evaluations obtained in this way are presented in Table 2.
The O-EDF of a security described in this way is a TrOFN with the identical orientation as the O-PV used for estimation. It is worth stressing that the maximum criterion of the expected RR can be equivalently replaced by the minimum criterion of the EDF.

5. Investment Recommendations

We understand an investment recommendation as a counsel given by the advisors to the investor. After evaluating the stocks, the advisor compares the obtained assessment with the current market value of the stocks. The difference between those values determines the potential of the investment return rate. Advisors give various recommendations depending on the volume of the return rate potential and its direction. Experts also define the potential of the return rate in different ways. We will here consider the collection of standardised recommendations, which are applied in [46]. The rating scale is given as the set A = { A + + ,   A + ,   A 0 ,   A ,   A } , where
  • A + + denotes the advice Buy suggesting that the expected price is well above the current quoted price,
  • A + denotes the advice Accumulate suggesting that the expected price is above the current quoted price,
  • A 0 denotes the advice Hold suggesting that the expected price is similar to the current quoted price,
  • A denotes the advice Reduce suggesting that the expected price is below the current quoted price,
  • A denotes the advice Sell suggesting that the expected price is well below the current quoted price.
The investor attributes each recommendation with the appropriate way of entering the transaction and the value of its volume. The way of entering the transaction describes the investment strategy. Investors can differ among one another by the implemented strategies.
Let fixed security S ˇ be represented by the pair ( r ¯ s ,   ϖ s ) , where r ¯ s is an expected RR on S ˇ and ϖ s is other parameter characterising S ˇ . The symbol S denotes the set of all considered securities. Adviser’s counsel depends on the expected RR. The criterion for a competent choice of advice can be presented as a comparison of the profit index g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) and the profitability threshold (PT) G ˇ , where g ( · | ϖ s ) : is an increasing function of the expected RR. The advice choice function Λ : S × 2 A was given in the following way [46]
A + + Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) > G ˇ ¬ g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) G ˇ
A + Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) G ˇ
A 0 Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) = G ˇ g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) G ˇ g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) G ˇ
A Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) G ˇ
A Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) < G ˇ ¬ g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) G ˇ
This way, the advice set Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) A was assigned. We interpret the advice set Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) as the investment recommendation given for the security S ˇ .
The security S ˇ may be equivalently represented by the ordered pair ( v ¯ s ,   ϖ s ) , where v ¯ s is the EDF determined by (30). Then the identity (30) implies
g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) G ˇ v ¯ s 1 1 + g 1 ( G ˇ | ϖ s ) = H s ( G ˇ )
g ( r ¯ s | ϖ s ) G ˇ v ¯ s H s ( G ˇ )
The value H s is used as a specific profitability threshold (SPT) appointed for the security S ˇ . Then, the advice choice function Λ : S × 2 A is equivalently described in the following way
A + + Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) ¬ v ¯ s H s ( G ˇ )
A + Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) v ¯ s H s ( G ˇ )
A 0 Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) v ¯ s H s ( G ˇ ) v ¯ s H s ( G ˇ )
A Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) v ¯ s H s ( G ˇ )
A Λ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) ¬ v ¯ s H s ( G ˇ )
We consider the case when the security S ˇ is characterised by the ordered pair ( V s ,   ϖ s ) where V s K T r is O-EDF calculated with use (32). Then the advice choice function Λ ˜ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) is FS described by membership function λ ( · | S ˇ , G ˇ ) : A [ 0 , 1 ] determined in line with (40)–(44) in the following way:
λ ( A + + | S ˇ , G ˇ ) = 1 ν G E ( V s , H s ( G ˇ ) )
λ ( A + | S ˇ , G ˇ ) = ν G E ( H s ( G ˇ ) , V s )
λ ( A 0 | S ˇ , G ˇ ) = min { ν G E ( H s ( G ˇ ) , V s ) ,   ν G E ( V s , H s ( G ˇ ) ) }
λ ( A | S ˇ , G ˇ ) = ν G E ( V s , H s ( G ˇ ) )
λ ( A | S ˇ , G ˇ ) = 1 ν G E ( H s ( G ˇ ) , V s )
where ν G E : K T r × K T r [ 0 , 1 ] is membership function of relation “less than or equal” (20). The required values of this function are computed with the use of (21) and (22).
From the point of view of invest-making, the value λ ( A | S ˇ , G ˇ ) is understood as a recommendation degree of the advice A A , i.e., a declared participation of the advisor’s responsibility in the case of a final invest-made according to the advice A A . It implies that the investment recommendation Λ ˜ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) is emphasised as a FS in the rating scale A .
In turn, the final decision is taken by the investors. Their personal responsibility for taking this investment decision decreases along with the increase in the recommendation degree related to the decision taken.
The increase in the ambiguity of the recommendation Λ ˜ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) ( A ) suggests a higher number of alternative recommendations to choose from. This is an increase in the risk of choosing an incorrect decision from recommended ones. This may result in obtaining a profit lower than maximal, that is with a loss of chance. Such risk is called an ambiguity risk. The ambiguity risk burdening the recommendation Λ ˜ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) ( A ) is assessed with an energy measure d ( Λ ˜ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) ) computed with the use of (5).
An increase in the indistinctness of the recommendation Λ ˜ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) ( A ) suggests that the explicit distinction between recommended and not recommended decisions is more difficult. This causes an increase in the indistinctness risk understood as risk of choosing a not recommended decision. The indistinctness risk burdening the recommendation Λ ˜ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) ( A ) is measured by the entropy measure e ( Λ ˜ ( S ˇ , G ˇ ) ) computed with the use of (6).
An imprecision risk is always determined as a combination of indistinctness and ambiguity risks combined.

6. The Profitability Criteria for Investments

We evaluate chosen securities traded on a fixed capital market. We always assume that there exists a risk-free bond instrument represented by the pair ( r 0 , 0 ) . Moreover, we distinguish the market portfolio represented by the pair ( r M , σ M ) .
Example 3.
We focus on the WSE. We take into account a risk-free bound instrument determined as quarterly treasure bonds with a risk-free RR r 0 = 0.0075 . The market portfolio is determined as the portfolio determining a stock exchange index WIG. The RR from WIG has the normal distribution N ( r M , σ M 2 ) = N ( 0.0200 ,   0.000025 ) .

6.1. Sharpe Ratio

The profit index is defined as Sharpe’s ratio estimating the amount of the premium per overall risk unit. Then Sharpe’s PT is equal to the unit premium of the market portfolio risk [84].
If the security S ˇ is represented by the pair ( r ¯ s , σ s ) , then, in line to Sharpe, the profit index g ( · | σ s ) : and the PT G ˇ are defined as follows:
g ( r ¯ s | σ s ) = r s r 0 σ s
G ˇ = r M r 0 σ M
We compute SPT H s with the use of (38) in the following manner:
H s = σ M σ s · ( r M r 0 ) + σ M · ( r 0 + 1 )
Example 4.
Using Equation (52), we compute an SPT H s for all components of the portfolio π described in Examples 1 and 2. Obtained SPT values are compared with O-EDFs in Table 3.
If we estimate PV by TrOFN presented in Table 1, then using the Sharpe criterion is simply comparing an imprecise O-EDF with the precise SPT. By means of Equations (45)–(49), we compute the values of the recommendation choice function presented in Table 4. Table 4 also presents information on the imprecision risk burdening individual recommendations. That information will be used to choose the recommendation.
Investment recommendations for ALR, CCC, OPL and PKN are burdened with the increased ambiguity risk. Moreover, the recommendations for CCC, OPL and PKN carry the indistinctness risk. For that reason, those recommendations are rejected. Eventually, only the following stocks are attributed with “Buy” or “Accumulate” recommendation: CDR, CPS, DNP, JSW, KGH, LTS, LPP, MBK, PEO, PGE, PGN, PKO, PLY, PZU, SPL and TPE. Thus, the disclosure of imprecision of PV estimations allows rejecting riskier recommendations.

6.2. Jensen’s Alpha

The profit index is defined as Jensen’s alpha [85], estimating the amount of the premium for market risk. The security S ˇ is represented by the pair ( r s ,   β s ) , where β s is the directional factor of the CAPM model assigned to this instrument. Then, the profit index g ( · | σ s ) : and the PT G ˇ are defined as follows:
g ( r ¯ s | β s ) = r s β s ( r M r 0 )
G ˇ = r 0
We calculate SPT H s with the use of (38) in the following manner
H s = 1 1 + r 0 + β s ( r M r 0 )
Example 5.
Using (55), we calculate a specific profitability threshold SPT H s for all components of the portfolio π described in Examples 1 and 2. The CAPM directional factors for each portfolio component are presented in Table 2. Evaluations obtained in this way are presented in Table 5.
If now we estimate PV with the use of TrOFN presented in Table 1 then using the Jensen’s alpha goes down to the comparison of an imprecise O-EDF with the precise SPT. By means of (45)–(49) we estimate the values of a recommendation choice function presented in Table 6.
Investment recommendations for ALR, CCC, CPS, OPL, PGE, PKN and TPE are burdened with the increased ambiguity risk. Moreover, the recommendations for ALR, CCC, CPS and PGE carry an indistinctness risk. For that reason, those recommendations are rejected. Eventually, only the following stocks are attributed with “Buy” or “Accumulate” advice: CDR, DNP, JSW, KGH, LTS, LPP, PEO, PGN, PKO, PLY, PZU and SPL. Advice “Sell” or “Reduce” were associated with MBK. Thus, the disclosure of imprecision of PV estimations allows rejecting riskier recommendations.

6.3. Treynor Ratio

The profit index is defined as the Treynor ratio [86], which estimates the amount of premium for the market risk. The security S ˇ is represented by the pair ( r s ,   β s ) , where β s is the directional factor of the CAPM model assigned to this instrument. Then the profit index g ( · | σ s ) : and the PT G ˇ are defined as follows:
g ( r ¯ s | β s ) = r s r 0 β s
G ˇ = r M r 0
We compute SPT H s with the use of (38) in the following manner
H s = 1 1 + r s + β s ( r M r 0 )
Example 6.
Using (58), we calculate SPT for all components of the portfolio π described in Examples 1 and 2. Evaluations obtained in this way are presented in Table 7.
If we estimate PV with the use of TrOFN presented in Table 1 then using the Treynor ratio criterion goes down to the comparison of an imprecise O-EDF with the precise SPT. By means of (45)–(49) we estimate the values of the recommendation choice function presented in Table 8.
Investment recommendation for CCC is burdened with an increased ambiguity risk and carries an indistinctness risk. For that reason, this recommendation is rejected. Eventually, only the following stocks are attributed with “Sell” or “Reduce” advice: ALR, CDR, CPS, DNP, KGH, LTS, LPP, MBK, OPL, PEO, PGE, PGN, PKN, PKO, PLY, PZU, SPL and TPE. Advice “Buy” or “Accumulate” were associated just with the stock of JSW. Thus, the disclosure of imprecision of PV estimations allows rejecting riskier recommendations.

6.4. Sortino Ratio

The Sortino ratio [87] is a tool for risk management under a financial equilibrium. In this model we compare the expected RR r ¯ s from considered security and the expected return rate r ¯ M from the distinguished market portfolio. We consider the advice choice function where the profit index and the limit value are determined by the Sortino ratio. Then, the profit index evaluates the amount of a specific unit premium for the loss risk. Moreover, the limit value evaluates an amount of the market unit premium for the loss risk. The benchmark of our assessment is a market portfolio represented by such an ordered pair ( r ¯ M , ς M 2 ) , where the downside semi variance ς M 2 evaluates the market loss risk. The reference point is a risk-free bond instrument represented by the ordered pair ( r 0 , 0 ) , where r 0 is a risk-free return rate.
The considered security S ˇ is represented by the ordered pair ( r ¯ s , ς S 2 ) , where downside semi variance ς S 2 evaluates the loss risk. Then, Sortino and Price (1997) define the profit index g ( · | ς s ) : and the limit value PT G ˇ as follows:
g ( r ¯ s | ς s ) = r s r 0 ς s
G ˇ = r M r 0 ς M
We compute SPT H s ( G ˇ ) with the use of (38) in the following manner
H s ( G ˇ ) = ς M ς s · ( r M r 0 ) + ς M · ( r 0 + 1 )
Example 7.
The market portfolio is represented by the ordered pair ( r M , ς M 2 ) = ( 0.0200 ,   0.000015 ) . Using (61), we calculate SPT for all securities belonging to the portfolio π described in Examples 1 and 2. Evaluations obtained in this way are presented in Table 9.
For each considered security, by means of (45)–(49) we calculate membership functions of investment recommendations presented in Table 10.
Investment recommendations for ALR, CCC, OPL and PKN are burdened with the increased ambiguity risk. Moreover, the recommendations for CCC, OPL and PKN carry the indistinctness risk. For that reason, those recommendations are rejected. Eventually, only the following stocks are attributed with “Buy” or “Accumulate” advice: CDR, CPS, DNP, JSW, KGH, LTS, LPP, MBK, PEO, PGE, PGN, PKO, PLY, PZU, SPL and TPE. Thus, the disclosure of the imprecision of PV estimations allows rejecting riskier recommendations.

6.5. Modiglianis’ Coefficient

In the crisp case, the Modiglianis’ Coefficient Criterion is equivalent to Sharpe Ratio Criterion. In this model, the compared values are the expected RR on a security and the expected RR on the market portfolio. Modiglianis’ profit coefficient estimates the bonus over market profits. Modiglianis’ limit value equals zero.
If the security S ˇ is represented by the pair ( r ¯ s , σ S 2 ) , then Modigliani [88] defines the profit index g ( · | σ s ) : and the PT G ˇ as follows:
g ( r ¯ s | σ s ) = r 0 r M + r s r 0 σ s   · σ M
G ˇ = 0
We compute SPT H s with the use of (38) in the following manner
H s = σ M σ s · ( r M r 0 ) + σ M · ( r 0 + 1 )
We see that in a fuzzy case, the Modiglianis’ Coefficient Criterion is also equivalent to the Sharpe Ratio Criterion. In this case, the recommendations obtained with the use of Modiglianis’ Coefficient can be found in Table 4.

6.6. Roy’s Criterion

Roy [89] has consider a fixed security S ˇ , represented by the pair ( r ¯ s ,   σ s ) , where r ¯ s is an expected return on S ˇ and σ S 2 is the variance of a return rate of the considered financial instrument. After Markowitz [9] we assume that the considered security S ˇ has a simple return rate with Gaussian distribution N ( r ¯ s ,   σ s ) . This distribution is described by its increasing and continuous cumulative distribution function F ( · | r ¯ s ,   σ s ) : [ 0 ; 1 ] given by the identity
F ( x | r ¯ s ,   σ s ) = Φ ( x r ¯ s σ s )
where the function Φ : [ 0 ; 1 ] is the cumulative distribution function of the Gaussian distribution N ( 0 ,   1 ) . The Safety Condition [89] is given as follows:
F ( L | r ¯ s ,   σ s ) = ε
where
  • L —a minimum acceptable RR,
  • ε —the probability of RR realisation below the minimum acceptable rate.
The RR realisation below the minimum acceptable rate is identified with a loss. The Roy’s criterion minimises the probability of a loss for a set minimum acceptable rate of return [46]. Additionally, the investor assumes the maximum level ε of the loss probability. Then the Roy’s criterion is described by the inequality
F ( L | r ¯ s ,   σ s ) = Φ ( L r ¯ s σ s ) ε < 1 2
It implies that
r ¯ s L σ s · Φ 1 ( ε )
In line with (38), SPT is given as follows
H s = 1 1 + L σ s · Φ 1 ( ε )
Example 8.
We study recommendations implied by Roy’s criterion all components of portfolio π described in Example 1. The investor assumes the minimal acceptable RR L = 0.0075 . Additionally, the investor assumes the maximum level of a loss probability ε = 0.05 . Then, we have Φ 1 ( 0.05 ) = 1.64 . Table 2 lists the values of O-EDF. Using (69), we compute SPT for all components of the portfolio π described in Examples 1 and 2. Evaluations obtained in this way are presented in Table 11.
If we estimate PV with the use of TrOFN presented in Table 1 then using the Roy’s criterion goes down to the comparison of an imprecise OEF with the precise SPT [70]. By means of (45)–(49) we then estimate the values of a recommendation choice function presented in Table 12.
Investment recommendations for ALR and CCC are burdened with an increased ambiguity risk. Moreover, the recommendations for CCC carry the indistinctness risk. For that reason, those recommendations are rejected. Eventually, only the following stocks are attributed with “Buy” or “Accumulate” advice: CDR, CPS, DNP, JSW, KGH, LTS, LPP, MBK, OPL, PEO, PGE, PGN, PKN, PKO, PLY, PZU, SPL and TPE. Thus, the disclosure of imprecision of PV estimations allows rejecting riskier recommendations.

6.7. Discussions

This chapter presented the recommendations obtained by means of ratios representing various criteria of assessment of the current financial efficiency of a considered asset. Here we have
  • Sharpe ratio and Sortino ratio used to maximise the premium per overall risk unit,
  • Jensen’s alpha and Treynor ratio used to maximise the premium for market risk.
  • Roy’s criterion used to minimise the probability of bearing the unacceptable loss.
This opulence of the used criteria explains to some extent the variety of recommendations attributed by the mentioned criteria to the same financial instrument. However, this is not the only reason of the differentiation between those recommendations. We should pay attention to a big differentiation of the recommendations established by Jensen’s alpha and Treynor ratio used to maximise the premium for risk. This phenomenon is difficult to explain substantively. Hence, we deduce that while managing the chosen financial instruments, we should take into account a fixed set of recommendations that attributed to them. The next chapter will be dedicated to the issue of managing the fixed set of investment recommendations.

7. Management of Investment Recommendation Set

In Section 5 and Section 6, the proposed procedure for recommendations was always considered in the case of one established criterion. Due to that we could mark all recommendations with a single symbol. In this chapter we will consider the relations between recommendations with various criteria attributed to them. For a bigger transparency of those considerations we will introduce a modified system of recommendation labels.
Any FS Λ ˜ γ ( A ) is called a recommendation. The subscript γ means any set of symbols identifying the kind of distinguished recommendation. Any recommendation Λ ˜ γ is represented by its membership function λ γ : A [ 0 , 1 ] . Also, each recommendation can be noted as
Λ ˜ γ = λ γ ( A ) A + λ γ ( A ) A + λ γ ( A 0 ) A 0 + λ γ ( A + ) A + + λ γ ( A + + ) A + +
In special cases we have
Λ ˜ γ = 0 A + 0 A + 0 A 0 + 0 A + + 0 A + + =
Λ ˜ γ = 1 A + 1 A + 1 A 0 + 1 A + + 1 A + + = A
Moreover, in notation (70) of recommendation Λ ˜ γ we can omit every advice A A satisfying the condition μ γ ( A ) = 0 . Each security S ˇ is assigned a recommendation Λ ˜ S , 1 , Λ ˜ S , 2   , Λ ˜ S , 5 ( A ) , where
  • Λ ˜ S , 1 —recommendations obtained with the use of the Sharpe ratio,
  • Λ ˜ S , 2 —recommendations obtained with the use of Jensen’s alpha,
  • Λ ˜ S , 3 —recommendations obtained with the use of the Treynor ratio,
  • Λ ˜ S , 4 —recommendations obtained with the use of the Sortino ratio,
  • Λ ˜ S , 5 —recommendations obtained with the use of Roy’s criterion.
Example 9.
Table 12 presents the recommendation
Λ ˜ C C C , 5 = 0 A + 0.0663 A + 0.0663 A 0 + 1 A + + 0.9337 A + + = 0.0663 A + 0.0663 A 0 + 1 A + + 0.9337 A + +
Let us note that various criteria assign different recommendations to the same security. Each recommendation can bear a different imprecision risk. We propose to limit the acceptable recommendations to those that are characterised by the minimal risk of imprecision. However, imprecision is evaluated by the means of two indices, which should be minimised. In this case, to minimise the risk, a multicriterial approach was implemented.
Each recommendation Λ ˜ S , i is given a pair ( d ( Λ ˜ S , i ) , e ( Λ ˜ S , i ) ) where d ( Λ ˜ S , i ) and e ( Λ ˜ S , i ) respectively mean energy and entropy measures. On the recommendation set we define two preorders Λ ˜ S , i   i s   m o r e   a c c e p t a b l e   t h a n   Λ ˜ S , j :
Λ ˜ S , i   Q 1 Λ ˜ S , j d ( Λ ˜ S , i ) d ( Λ ˜ S , j )
Λ ˜ S , i   Q 2 Λ ˜ S , j e ( Λ ˜ S , i ) e ( Λ ˜ S , j )
Those preorders are formal models of ambiguity and indistinctness of information minimisation criterion. A multicriterial comparison defined by the preorders Q 1 and Q 2 is a model of satisfying the postulate of minimisation of both factors.
Using the multicriterial comparison (73) and (74) for each security S ˇ we determine the Pareto optimum O s which includes all acceptable recommendations. To solve this optimisation task, we use an algorithm described in Appendix A.
Example 10.
For each security S ^ described in Example 1, using respectively Sharpe ratio, Jensen’s alpha, Treynor ratio, Sortino ratio, and Roy’s criterion, we determined recommendations Λ ˜ S , 1 , Λ ˜ S , 2 , Λ ˜ S , 3 , Λ ˜ S , 4 , Λ ˜ S , 5 . Those recommendations are presented in Table 4, Table 6, Table 8, Table 10 and Table 12. Using the multidimensional comparison (73) and (74), for each security S ^ we determine the Pareto optimum O s containing the information of a minimum risk. Those optima are shown in Table 13.
The results obtained in Example 10 show that in the case of many securities there is a big variety in the sets of optimum recommendations.
To unify the final recommendations for each security S ^ we determine:
  • A weakly justified recommendation (WJR) Λ ˜ S , W J R defined as the union of such Pareto optimal recommendations, which are linked to the security S ^ ;
  • A strongly justified recommendation (SJR) Λ ˜ S , S J R defined as the intersection of such Pareto optimal recommendations, which are linked to the security S ^ .
The WJR Λ ˜ S , W J R and the SJR Λ ˜ S , S J R are determined respectively by their membership functions given as follows
λ S , W J R ( A ) = max { λ S , i ( A ) :   Λ ˜ S , i O S }
λ S , S J R ( A ) = min { λ S , i ( A ) :   Λ ˜ S , i O S }
Example 11.
Separatelyfor each security S ^ described in Example 1, imprecise recommendations Λ ˜ S , 1 , Λ ˜ S , 2 , Λ ˜ S , 3 , Λ ˜ S , 4 , Λ ˜ S , 5 are compared in more detail in Table 14, Table 15, Table 16, Table 17, Table 18, Table 19, Table 20, Table 21, Table 22, Table 23, Table 24, Table 25, Table 26, Table 27, Table 28, Table 29, Table 30, Table 31, Table 32 and Table 33. In the two bottom rows of Table 14, Table 15, Table 16, Table 17, Table 18, Table 19, Table 20, Table 21, Table 22, Table 23, Table 24, Table 25, Table 26, Table 27, Table 28, Table 29, Table 30, Table 31, Table 32 and Table 33 WJRs and SJRs are given along with their imprecision estimates. All Table 14, Table 15, Table 16, Table 17, Table 18, Table 19, Table 20, Table 21, Table 22, Table 23, Table 24, Table 25, Table 26, Table 27, Table 28, Table 29, Table 30, Table 31, Table 32 and Table 33 are linked to the comments by using the names of discussed stock companies.
For the ALR shares only the following recommendation is Pareto optimal
Λ ˜ A L R , 3 = 1 A + 1 A = Λ ˜ A L R , W J R = Λ ˜ A L R , S J R
which was obtained by means of the Treynor ratio. In such situation, for this recommendation, WJR and SJR are identical. The advice Sell and Reduce is recommended by the advisor with the degree that equals 1. It means that the advisor is prepared to take full responsibility for making the investment decisions resulting from the suggested advice. The other recommendations are rejected by the advisor. In such case it is the investor who takes full responsibility for making any other decision resulting from the rejected recommendations of Buy, Accumulate and Hold.
For the CCC shares, WJR and SJR are as follows
Λ ˜ C C C , W J R = 0.337 A + 0.337 A 0 + 1 A + + 0.9337 A + +   ,
Λ ˜ C C C , S J R = 0.0663 A + 0.0663 A 0 + 1 A + + 0.663 A + + .
From the distribution of a recommendation degree represented by WJR it shows that the advisor definitely rejects the Sell recommendation. WJR also tells us that the Accumulate and Buy recommendations can be taken into consideration. Additional information on the distribution of the responsibility for the decisions taken is reflected in SJR. It supplements the picture with the following information:
  • The investor bears almost all the responsibility for making an investment decision resulting from the Reduce and Hold recommendations,
  • The advisor bears full responsibility for making an investment decision resulting from the Accumulate recommendations,
  • The investor and the advisor share the responsibility among themselves for making the investment decision based on the Buy recommendation, however, the advisor bear approximately two-thirds of that responsibility.
After analysing the information and interpretations, the investor takes the decision. We can suspect that the investor characterised by risk-aversion will choose the Accumulate recommendation while the investor who is a risk-taker will choose the Buy advice.
For the CDR shares the following WJR and SJR were determined
Λ ˜ C D R , W J R = 1 A + 1 A + 1 A + + 1 A + +   ,
Λ ˜ C D R , S J R =
From the distribution of a recommendation degree represented by WJR it shows that the advisor definitely rejects the Hold recommendation. It means that the advisor recommends an investment activity without defining its kind. SJR shows that it is the investor who bears full responsibility for any decisions made. It is obvious that such a recommendation is not useful so in such a situation we state that there is no useful recommendation.
For the CPS shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation we state that there is no useful recommendation.
For the DNP shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation we state that there is no useful recommendation.
For the JSW shares, the following WJR and SJR were determined
Λ ˜ J S W , W J R = 1 A + + 1 A + +
Λ ˜ J S W , S J R = 1 A + + 1 A + +
From the distribution of a recommendation degree represented by WJR it shows that the advisor definitely rejects the Sell, Reduce and Hold recommendations. The advisor strongly recommends Accumulate or Buy. SJR shows that it is the advisor who is willing to take full responsibility for taking the investment decisions resulting from the advised recommendations.
For the KGH shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation we state that there is no useful recommendation.
For the LTS shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the LPP shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the MBK shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the OPL shares, Pareto optimal recommendation (77) is only the one determined by the Treynor ratio. From the distribution of a recommendation degree represented by WJR it shows that the advisor definitely rejects the Hold, Accumulate and Buy recommendations. The advisor strongly recommends Sell or Reduce. SJR shows that the advisor is willing to take full responsibility for taking the investment decisions resulting from the advised recommendations.
For the PEO shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the PGE shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the PGN shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the PKN shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the PKO shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the PLY shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the PZU shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the SPL shares, WJR and SJR are determined by (80) and (81). In this situation there is no useful recommendation.
For the TPE shares, WJR and SJR were determined as follows
Λ ˜ T P E , W J R = A
and (81). WJR informs us that the advisor does not exclude any recommendation. SJR shows that full responsibility for taking any investment decision goes to the investor. Therefore, there is no useful recommendation.
Summing up, for the public companies considered in the examples, in most cases there was no useful recommendation. Such a situation occurred in the case of CDR, CPS, DNP, KGH, LTS, LPP, MBK, PEO, PGE, PGN, PKN, PKO, PLY, PZU, SPL and TPE. Only for three following companies: ALR, CCC and OPL the recommendations could be considered useful. This situation does not differ from the real phenomena in financial markets. The number of useless recommendations can be decreased by limiting the number of assessment criteria. Also, another set of criteria can be implemented. The solution to those problems should be searched based on finance.
An observation can be useful that each pair of WJR and SJR might be presented as an intuitionistic fuzzy set [90] representing a justified recommendation (JR). Then any JR is defined by its membership function equal to the SJR membership function and by its non-membership function equal to the membership function of WJR complement.

8. Conclusions

In the subject literature it is shown that OFNs are a more convenient tool for financial analysis than FNs. Therefore, the most important achievement of this work is the implementation of OFNs into the algorithmic system supporting investment decisions. In my best knowledge, the obtained algorithmic system is the only one that applies any set of profitability criteria evaluated with the use of OFNs. Until now, only an analogous system was known to be linked to the Sharpe’s criterion. For any security, this simple system assigns exactly one imprecise recommendation. The algorithmic system described in Section 5 and Section 6 assigns each security many different imprecise recommendations. For this reason, in Section 7, the proposed system is equipped with an imprecise recommendation management module.
Obtained results may provide theoretical foundations for constructing a robo-advice system supporting investment decisions. Then, we can use determined recommendations as behavioural premises for investment decisions. The attempt to use chosen recommendations multiple times leads to establishing an investing strategy. In Example 11, the interpretation of determined recommendations was presented. The shown case study is the reflection of only a little share of the set of all possible recommendations. Therefore, taking up research on a wider spectrum of recommendations established by the described algorithms seems justified. It should be an empirical research leading to establishing the heuristic investment strategy.
In financial practice, we can meet with the situation when part of PV securities is imprecisely evaluated without a subjective forecast of future quotation changes. Such PV should be evaluated by unoriented FNs. Against imprecisely evaluated PV, other securities may be equipped with a subjective forecast of rise in quotation. Such PV should be evaluated by positively oriented OFNs. In both of these cases the membership functions are identical. This results in the impossibility of a simultaneous comparison of oriented PV and unoriented PV. This is a significant disadvantage of the proposed algorithmic system supporting invest-making. The intention to deal with this inconvenience points to another direction of research into the OFNs theory.
The obtained results may as well be a starting point for future research on the impact of the PV imprecision and orientation on the investment recommendation determined with the use of algorithms presented in this paper. The implementation of intuitionistic fuzzy sets should be preceded by a theoretical and empirical research of the expediency of such approach for a representation of the justified recommendations mentioned in Section 7.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Acknowledgments

The author is very grateful to the anonymous reviewers for her\his insightful and constructive comments and suggestions.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Given security S ˇ is assigned recommendations Λ ˜ S , γ ( A ) , where the subscript γ = 1 , 2 , n identifies the method used to derive this recommendation. The acceptability of any recommendation increases along with the decrease of its ambiguity and with the decrease of indistinctness. Therefore, the subset of the most acceptable recommendation systems is distinguished as the Pareto’s optimum, determined as a two-criteria comparison of minimisation recommendation ambiguity and minimisation recommendation indistinctness.
The ambiguity of recommendation Λ ˜ S , γ is valued by energy measure d ( Λ ˜ S , γ ) calculated with the use of (5). The indistinctness of recommendation Λ ˜ S , γ is valued by energy measure d ( Λ ˜ S , γ ) determined by (6). Therefore, we represent each recommendation by the pair
( d ( Λ ˜ S , γ ) , e ( Λ ˜ S , γ ) ) = ( d S , γ , e S , γ )
On the recommendation set we define two preorders Λ ˜ S , i   i s   m o r e   t h a n   Λ ˜ S , j :
Λ ˜ S , i   Q 1 Λ ˜ S , j d S ,   i d S ,   j
Λ ˜ S , i   Q 2 Λ ˜ S , j e S ,   i e S ,   j
The set of all acceptable recommendations we appoint as Pareto’s optimum O S determined by multi-criterial comparison Q 1   Q 2 . To solve this optimisation task, we adapt an analogous algorithm presented in [91]. In order to determine the Pareto optimum O S , we execute the following algorithm:
STEP 1:
O S   : = { Λ ˜ S , 1 }
STEP 2:
i : = 2
STEP 3:
( Λ ˜ S , j O S : (   d S , j d S , i e S , j e S , i ) (   d S , j d S , i e S , j e S , i ) (   d S , j d S , i e S , j e S , i ) )
O S   : = O S     { Λ ˜ S , i }
STEP 4:
Λ ˜ S , j O S : ( ( d S , j < d S , i e S , j > e S , i )   O S   : = O S   { Λ ˜ S , j } )
STEP 5:
i : = i + 1
STEP 6:
i > n g o   t o   S T O P
STEP 7:
g o   t o   S T E P   3
STOP.
In this way, we obtain the sequence O S of partial optima of Pareto.

References

  1. Kosiński, W.; Prokopowicz, P.; Ślęzak, D. Fuzzy numbers with algebraic operations: Algorithmic approach. In Proceedings of the Intelligent Information Systems 2002, Sopot, Poland, 3–6 June 2002; Klopotek, M., Wierzchoń, S.T., Michalewicz, M., Eds.; Physica: Heidelberg, Germany, 2002; pp. 311–320. [Google Scholar]
  2. Kosiński, W. On fuzzy number calculus. Int. J. Appl. Math. Comput. Sci. 2006, 16, 51–57. [Google Scholar]
  3. Piasecki, K. Revision of the Kosiński’s Theory of Ordered Fuzzy Numbers. Axioms 2018, 7, 16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Prokopowicz, P. The Directed Inference for the Kosinski’s Fuzzy Number Model. In Proceedings of the Second International Afro-European Conference for Industrial Advancement, Villejuif, France, 9–11 September 2015; Advances in Inteligent Systems and Computing. Abraham, A., Wegrzyn-Wolska, K., Hassanien, A.E., Snasel, V., Alimi, A.M., Eds.; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2015; Volume 427, pp. 493–505. [Google Scholar]
  5. Prokopowicz, P.; Pedrycz, W. The Directed Compatibility between Ordered Fuzzy Numbers—A Base Tool for a Direction Sensitive Fuzzy Information Processing. Artif. Intell. Soft Comput. 2015, 119, 249–259. [Google Scholar]
  6. Piasecki, K. Relation “greater than or equal to” between ordered fuzzy numbers. Appl. Syst. Innov. 2019, 2, 26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Piasecki, K.; Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, A. Representation of Japanese Candlesticks by Oriented Fuzzy Numbers. Econometrics 2020, 8, 1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. D’Acunto, F.; Prabhala, N.; Rossi, A.G. The promises and pitfalls of Robo-Advising. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2019, 32, 1983–2020. [Google Scholar]
  9. Markowitz, H. Portfolio Selection. J. Financ. 1952, 7, 77–91. [Google Scholar]
  10. De Miguel, V.; Garlappi, L.; Uppal, R. Optimal versus naive diversification: How inefficient is the 1/N portfolio strategy. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2009, 22, 1915–1953. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Chen, Z.; Li, Z.; Wang, L. Concentrated portfolio selection models based on historical data. Applied Stoch. Models Bus. Ind. 2015, 31, 649–668. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Gao, J.; Xiong, Y.; Li, D. Dynamic mean-risk portfolio selection with multiple risk measures in continuous time. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 249, 647–656. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Rockafellar, R.T.; Uryasev, S. Conditional value-at-risk for general loss distributions. J. Bank. Financ. 2002, 26, 1443–1471. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Hajjami, M.; Amin, G.R. Modelling stock selection using ordered weighted averaging operator. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2018, 33, 2283–2292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Li, D.; Ng, W.L. Optimal dynamic portfolio selection: Multiperiod mean-variance formulation. Math. Financ. 2000, 10, 387–406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Liu, J.; Chen, Z. Time consistent multi-period robust risk measures and portfolio selection models with regime-switching. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2018, 268, 373–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Roman, R.-C.; Precup, R.-E.; Petriu, E.M. Hybrid Data-Driven Fuzzy Active Disturbance Rejection Control for Tower Crane Systems. Eur. J. Control 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Zhu, Z.; Pan, Y.; Zhou, Q.; Lu, C. Event-Triggered Adaptive Fuzzy Control for Stochastic Nonlinear Systems with Unmeasured States and Unknown Backlash-Like Hysteresis. IEEE Trans. Fuzzy Syst. 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Wang, S.; Zhu, S. On fuzzy portfolio selection problems. Fuzzy Optim. Decis. Mak. 2002, 1, 361–377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Kahraman, C.; Ruan, D.; Tolga, E. Capital budgeting techniques using discounted fuzzy versus probabilistic cash flows. Inf. Sci. 2002, 142, 57–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Peng, J.; Mok, H.M.K.; Tse, W.M. Credibility programming approach to fuzzy portfolio selection problems. In Proceedings of the International Conference on Machine Learning and Cybernetics, Guangzhou, China, 18–21 August 2005; Volume 4, pp. 2523–2528. [Google Scholar]
  22. Huang, X. Two new models for portfolio selection with stochastic returns taking fuzzy information. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2007, 180, 396–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Huang, X. Portfolio selection with fuzzy return. J. Intell. Fuzzy Syst. 2007, 18, 383–390. [Google Scholar]
  24. Yan, L. Optimal portfolio selection models with uncertain returns. Mod. Appl. Sci. 2009, 3, 76–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  25. Zhang, Y.; Li, X.; Wong, H.S.; Tan, L. Fuzzy multi-objective portfolio selection model with transaction costs. In Proceedings of the IEEE International Conference on Fuzzy Systems, Jeju Island, Korea, 20–24 August 2009; pp. 273–278. [Google Scholar]
  26. Fang, Y.; Lai, K.K.; Wang, S. Fuzzy Portfolio Optimization. Theory and Methods; Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, 609; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  27. Li, C.; Jin, J. Fuzzy Portfolio Optimization Model with Fuzzy Numbers. In Nonlinear Mathematics for Uncertainty and Its Applications, Advances in Intelligent and Soft Computing; Li, S., Wang, X., Okazaki, Y., Kawabe, J., Murofushi, T., Guan, L., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2011; Volume 100, pp. 557–565. [Google Scholar]
  28. Guo, H.; Sun, B.Q.; Karimi, H.R.; Ge, Y.; Jin, W. Fuzzy Investment Portfolio Selection Models Based on Interval Analysis Approach. Math. Probl. Eng. 2012, 2012, 628295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Wu, X.; Liu, Y. Optimizing fuzzy portfolio selection problems by parametric quadratic programming. Fuzzy Optim. Decis. Making 2012, 11, 411–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Lin, P.; Watada, J.; Wu, B. Portfolio selection model with interval values based on fuzzy probability distribution functions. Int. J. Innov. Comput. Inf. Control 2012, 8, 5935–5944. [Google Scholar]
  31. Liu, Y.-J.; Zhang, W.-G. Fuzzy portfolio optimization model under real constraints. Insur. Math. Econ. 2013, 53, 704–711. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Zhang, X.; Zhang, W.-G.; Xiao, W. Multi-period portfolio optimization under possibility measures. Econ. Model. 2013, 35, 401–408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Li, J.; Xu, J. Multi-objective portfolio selection model with fuzzy random returns and a compromise approach-based genetic algorithm. Inf. Sci. 2013, 220, 507–521. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Gupta, P.; Mehlawat, M.K.; Inuiguchi, M.; Chandra, S. Fuzzy Portfolio Optimization. Advances in Hybrid Multi-Criteria Methodologies; Studies in Fuzziness and Soft Computing 316; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  35. Mehlawat, M.K. Credibilistic mean-entropy models for multi-period portfolio selection with multi-choice aspiration levels. Inf. Sci. 2016, 345, 9–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Guo, S.; Yu, L.; Li, X.; Kar, S. Fuzzy multi-period portfolio selection with different investment horizons. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 254, 1026–1035. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Saborido, R.; Ruiz, A.B.; Bermúdez, J.D.; Vercher, E.; Luque, M. Evolutionary multi-objective optimization algorithms for fuzzy portfolio selection. Appl. Soft Comput. 2016, 39, 48–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Liu, Y.J.; Zhang, W.G.; Gupta, P. International asset allocation optimization with fuzzy return. Knowl. Based Syst. 2018, 139, 189–199. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Zhou, W.; Xu, Z.S. Portfolio selection and risk investment under the hesitant fuzzy environment. Knowl. Based Syst. 2018, 144, 21–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Zhou, W.; Xu, Z.S. Score-hesitation trade-off and portfolio selection under intuitionistic fuzzy environment. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2019, 268, 373–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Piasecki, K. Basis of financial arithmetic from the viewpoint of the utility theory. Oper. Res. Decis. 2012, 22, 37–53. [Google Scholar]
  42. Hao, F.F.; Liu, Y.K. Portfolio Selection Problem in Fuzzy Random Decision Systems. In Proceedings of the 3rd International Conference on Innovative Computing Information and Control, Dalian, China, 18–20 June 2008; p. 271. [Google Scholar]
  43. Hasuike, T.; Katagiri, H.; Ishii, H. Portfolio selection problems with random fuzzy variable returns. In Proceedings of the 2007 IEEE International Fuzzy Systems Conference, London, UK, 23–26 July 2007; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  44. Tsao, C.T. Assessing the probabilistic fuzzy Net Present Value for a capital, Investment choice using fuzzy arithmetic. J. Chin. Inst. Ind. Eng. 2005, 22, 106–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Piasecki, K. Effectiveness of securities with fuzzy probabilistic return. Oper. Res. Decis. 2011, 21, 65–78. [Google Scholar]
  46. Piasecki, K. On Imprecise Investment Recommendations. Stud. Logic Gramm. Rhetor. 2014, 37, 179–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  47. Piasecki, K.; Siwek, J. Two-Asset Portfolio with Triangular Fuzzy Present Values—An Alternative Approach. In Contemporary Trends in Accounting, Finance and Financial Institutions; Springer Proceedings in Business and Economics; Choudhry, T., Mizerka, J., Eds.; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2018; pp. 11–26. [Google Scholar]
  48. Piasecki, K.; Siwek, J. Multi-asset portfolio with trapezoidal fuzzy present values. Stat. Rev. 2018, 64, 183–199. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Piasecki, K.; Siwek, J. Investment Strategies Determined by Present Value Given as Trapezoidal Fuzzy Numbers. In Effective Investments on Capital Markets. Springer Proceedings in Business and Economics; Tarczyński, W., Nermend, K., Eds.; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2019; pp. 189–213. [Google Scholar]
  50. Siwek, J. Multiple asset portfolio with present value given as a discrete fuzzy number. In Proceedings of the 35th International Conference Mathematical Methods in Economics MME 2017, Hradec Králové, Czech Republic, 13–15 September 2017; Prazak, P., Ed.; Gaudeamus, University of Hradec Kralove: Hradec Králové, Czech Republic, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  51. Ward, T.L. Discounted fuzzy cash flow analysis. In Proceedings of the 1985 Fall Industrial Engineering Conference, Stuttgart, Germany, 11–13 June 1985; pp. 476–481. [Google Scholar]
  52. Buckley, J.J. The fuzzy mathematics of finance. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1987, 21, 257–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Greenhut, J.G.; Norman, G.; Temponi, C.T. Towards a fuzzy theory of oligopolistic competition. In Proceedings of the IEEE ISUMA-NAFIPS, College Park, MD, USA, 17–20 September 1995; pp. 286–291. [Google Scholar]
  54. Sheen, J.N. Fuzzy financial profitability analyses of demand side management alternatives from participant perspective. Inf. Sci. 2005, 169, 329–364. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Gutierrez, I. Fuzzy numbers and Net Present Value. Scand. J. Mgmt. 1989, 5, 149–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Kuchta, D. Fuzzy capital budgeting. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2000, 111, 367–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Lesage, C. Discounted cash-flows analysis. An interactive fuzzy arithmetic approach. Eur. J. Econ. Soc. Syst. 2001, 15, 49–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  58. Hiroto, K. Concepts of probabilistic sets. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1981, 5, 31–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Roszkowska, E.; Kacprzak, D. The fuzzy SAW and fuzzy TOPSIS procedures based on ordered fuzzy numbers. Inf. Sci. 2016, 369, 564–584. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Rudnik, K.; Kacprzak, D. Fuzzy TOPSIS method with ordered fuzzy numbers for flow control in a manufacturing system. Appl. Soft Comput. 2017, 52, 1020–1041. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Piasecki, K.; Roszkowska, E. On application of ordered fuzzy numbers in ranking linguistically evaluated negotiation offers. Adv. Fuzzy Syst. 2018, 2018, 1569860. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Kacprzak, D. A doubly extended TOPSIS method for group decision making based on ordered fuzzy numbers. Expert Syst. Appl. 2018, 116, 243–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Piasecki, K.; Roszkowska, E.; Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, A. Simple Additive Weighting Method Equipped with Fuzzy Ranking of Evaluated Alternatives. Symmetry 2019, 11, 482. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  64. Piasecki, K.; Roszkowska, E.; Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, A. Impact of the Orientation of the Ordered Fuzzy Assessment on the Simple Additive Weighted Method. Symmetry 2019, 11, 1104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  65. Kosiński, W.K.; Kosiński, W.; Kościeński, K. Ordered fuzzy numbers approach to an investment project evaluation. Manag. Prod. Eng. Rev. 2013, 4, 50–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, A. Behavioural present value determined by ordered fuzzy number. SSRN Electron. J. 2017, 1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Piasecki, K. Expected return rate determined as oriented fuzzy number. In Proceedings of the 35th International Conference Mathematical Methods in Economics Conference, Hradec Králové, Czech Republic, 13–15 September 2017; pp. 561–565. [Google Scholar]
  68. Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, A.; Piasecki, K. Two-assets portfolio with trapezoidal oriented fuzzy present values. In Proceedings of the 36th International Conference Mathematical Methods in Economics Conference, Jindřichův Hradec, Czech Republic, 12–14 September 2018; pp. 306–311. [Google Scholar]
  69. Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, A.; Piasecki, K. Present value of portfolio of assets with present values determined by trapezoidal ordered fuzzy numbers. Oper. Res. Decis. 2018, 28, 41–56. [Google Scholar]
  70. Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, A. Sharpe’s Ratio for Oriented Fuzzy Discount Factor. Mathematics 2019, 7, 272. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  71. Kacprzak, D.; Kosiński, W. Optimizing Firm Inventory Costs as a Fuzzy Problem. Stud. Logic Gramm. Rhetor. 2014, 37, 89–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  72. Prokopowicz, P.; Czerniak, J.; Mikołajewski, D.; Apiecionek, Ł.; Slezak, D. Theory and Applications of Ordered Fuzzy Number. Tribute to Professor Witold Kosiński; Studies in Fuzziness and Soft Computing, 356; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  73. Zadeh, L. Fuzzy sets. Inf. Control 1965, 8, 338–353. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  74. Klir, G.J. Developments in uncertainty-based information. Adv. Comput. 1993, 36, 255–332. [Google Scholar]
  75. De Luca, A.; Termini, S. Entropy and energy measures of fuzzy sets. In Advances in Fuzzy Set Theory and Applications; Gupta, M.M., Ragade, R.K., Yager, R.R., Eds.; North-Holland Publishing Company: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1979; pp. 321–338. [Google Scholar]
  76. De Luca, A.; Termini, S. A definition of a non-probabilistic entropy in the settings of fuzzy set theory. Inf. Control 1972, 20, 301–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  77. Kosko, B. Fuzzy entropy and conditioning. Inf. Sci. 1986, 40, 165–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Dubois, D.; Prade, H. Operations on fuzzy numbers. Int. J. Syst. Sci. 1978, 9, 613–629. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Delgado, M.; Vila, M.A.; Voxman, W. On a canonical representation of fuzzy numbers. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1998, 93, 125–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Dubois, D.; Prade, H. Fuzzy real algebra: Some results. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1979, 2, 327–348. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Shyi-Ming, C. Fuzzy system reliability analysis using fuzzy number arithmetic operations. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1994, 64, 31–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Piasecki, K.; Stasiak, M.D. The Forex Trading System for Speculation with Constant Magnitude of Unit Return. Mathematics 2019, 7, 623. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  83. Nison, S. Japanese Candlestick Charting Techniques; New York Institute of Finance: New York, NY, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar]
  84. Sharpe, W.F. Mutual fund performance. J. Bus. 1966, 39, 119–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Jensen, M.C. Risk, the pricing of capital assets, and the evaluation of investment portfolios. J. Bus. 1969, 42, 167–247. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Treynor, J.L. How to rate management of investment funds. Harv. Bus. Rev. 1963, 43, 63–75. [Google Scholar]
  87. Sortino, F.A.; Price, L.N. Performance measurement of downside risk framework. J. Investig. Fall 1994, 3, 59–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Modigliani, F.; Modigliani, L. Risk adjusted performance. J. Portf. Manag. 1997, 31, 45–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Roy, A.D. Safety-first and the holding of assets. Econometrics 1952, 20, 431–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Atanassov, K.T. Intuitionistic fuzzy sets. Fuzzy Sets. Syst. 1986, 20, 87–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Piasecki, K.; Stasiak, M.D. Optimization Parameters of Trading System with Constant Modulus of Unit Return. Mathematics 2020, 8, 1384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Recorded values of the portfolio π components.
Table 1. Recorded values of the portfolio π components.
Stock Company Present   Value   P V s Quoted   Price   P ˇ s
ALR T r ( 27.42 ;   27.30 ;   27.00 ;   26.84 ) 27.00
CCC T r ( 83.35 ;   88.00 ;   88.00 ;   89.65 ) 88.00
CDR T r ( 271.50 ;   271.50 ;   276.30 ; 276.30 ) 277.00
CPS T r ( 26.42 ;   26.60 ;   27.04 ;   27.34 ) 27.20
DNP T r ( 155.00 ;   155.00 ; 155.10 ;   157.30 ) 155.30
JSW T r ( 18.60 ;   19.36 ;   20.14 ;   20.14 ) 20.32
KGH T r ( 91.78 ;   93.60 ;   93.70 ;   94.90 ) 94.24
LTS T r ( 83.88 ;   83.40 ;   81.16 ;   80.26 ) 81.44
LPP T r ( 8205.00 ;   8380.00 ;   8395.00 ;   8460.00 ) 8385.00
MBK T r ( 367.00 ;   366.00 ; 359.80 ;   357.00 ) 359.00
OPL T r ( 7.01 ;   7.05 ;   7.20 ;   7.35 ) 7.17
PEO T r ( 97.22 ;   97.70 ;   98.20 ;   98.66 ) 98.20
PGE T r ( 7.08 ;   7.15 ;   7.30 ;   7.40 ) 7.30
PGN T r ( 3.91 ;   3.88 ;   3.86 ;   3.82 ) 3.87
PKN T r ( 83.22 ;   83.00 ;   81.62 ;   81.18 ) 81.90
PKO T r ( 34.59 ;   34.68 ;   34.90 ;   35.26 ) 34.93
PLY T r ( 35.82 ;   35.94 ;   36.76 ;   37.20 ) 36.70
PZU T r ( 40.72 ;   40.73 ;   40.89 ;   41.11 ) 40.88
SPL T r ( 276.20 ;   278.00 ;   281.80 ; 283.80 ) 287.00
TPE T r ( 1.51 ;   1.53 ;   1.56 ;   1.56 ) 1.56
Table 2. Characteristic of portfolio π components.
Table 2. Characteristic of portfolio π components.
Stock Company Expected   Return   Rate   r ¯ s CAPM   Factor   β s Variance   σ s 2 Downside   Semi   Variance   ς s 2 EDF   v ¯ s OEDF   V s
ALR 0.0263 1.706 0.000031 0.000018 0.9744 T r ( 0.9896 ;   0.9852 ;   0.9744 ;   0.9686 )
CCC 0.0367 2.160 0.000048 0.000026 0.9646 T r ( 0.9136 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9827 )
CDR 0.2490 9.925 0.000311 0.000189 0.8006 T r ( 0.7847 ;   0.7847 ;   0.7986 ;   0.7986 )
CPS 0.0594 3.852 0.000093 0.000050 0.9439 T r ( 0.9168 ;   0.9231 ;   0.9384 ;   0.9488 )
DNP 0.0672 3.465 0.000011 0.000006 0.9370 T r ( 0.9352 ;   0.9352 ;   0.9358 ;   0.9491 )
JSW 0.0199 0.598 0.000016 0.000010 0.9805 T r ( 0.8975 ;   0.9342 ;   0.9718 ;   0.9718 )
KGH 0.0567 2.699 0.000063 0.000039 0.9463 T r ( 0.9216 ;   0.9399 ;   0.9409 ;   0.9529 )
LTS 0.1054 3.643 0.000161 0.000092 0.9047 T r ( 0.9318 ;   0.9265 ;   0.9016 ;   0.8916 )
LPP 0.0872 1.958 0.000126 0.000071 0.9198 T r ( 0.9001 ;   0.9193 ;   0.9209 ;   0.9280 )
MBK 0.0674 6.243 0.000097 0.000059 0.9369 T r ( 0.9578 ;   0.9552 ;   0.9390 ;   0.9317 )
OPL 0.0278 1.9406 0.000028 0.000017 0.9730 T r ( 0.9513 ;   0.9567 ;   0.9771 ;   0.9974 )
PEO 0.0459 1.348 0.000068 0.000036 0.9561 T r ( 0.9466 ;   0.9512 ;   0.9561 ;   0.9606 )
PGE 0.0674 4.392 0.000099 0.000071 0.9369 T r ( 0.9087 ;   0.9177 ;   0.9369 ;   0.9497 )
PGN 0.0751 3.976 0.000109 0.000065 0.9302 T r ( 0.9398 ;   0.9326 ;   0.9278 ;   0.9182 )
PKN 0.0408 2.674 0.000049 0.000029 0.9608 T r ( 0.9763 ;   0.9737 ;   0.9575 ;   0.9524 )
PKO 0.1974 5.463 0.000216 0.000099 0.8351 T r ( 0.8270 ;   0.8291 ;   0.8344 ;   0.8430 )
PLY 0.2607 6.2156 0.000589 0.000312 0.7932 T r ( 0.7742 ;   0.7768 ;   0.7945 ;   0.8040 )
PZU 0.1952 5.541 0.000301 0.000181 0.8367 T r ( 0.8334 ;   0.8336 ;   0.8369 ;   0.8414 )
SPL 0.3001 8.867 0.000563 0.000391 0.7692 T r ( 0.7403 ;   0.7451 ;   0.7553 ;   0.7606 )
TPE 0.0432 2.991 0.000056 0.000035 0.9586 T r ( 0.9279 ;   0.9402 ;   0.9586 ;   0.9586 )
Table 3. Specific profitability threshold (SPT) H s for the Sharpe criterion.
Table 3. Specific profitability threshold (SPT) H s for the Sharpe criterion.
Stock Company OEDF   V s SPT   H s
ALR T r ( 0.9896 ;   0.9852 ;   0.9744 ;   0.9686 ) 0.9790
CCC T r ( 0.9136 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9827 ) 0.9758
CDR T r ( 0.7847 ;   0.7847 ;   0.7986 ;   0.7986 ) 0.9509
CPS T r ( 0.9168 ;   0.9231 ;   0.9384 ;   0.9488 ) 0.9694
DNP T r ( 0.9352 ;   0.9352 ;   0.9358 ;   0.9491 ) 0.9845
JSW T r ( 0.8975 ;   0.9342 ;   0.9718 ;   0.9718 ) 0.9828
KGH T r ( 0.9216 ;   0.9399 ;   0.9409 ;   0.9529 ) 0.9734
LTS T r ( 0.9318 ;   0.9265 ;   0.9016 ;   0.8916 ) 0.9623
LPP T r ( 0.9001 ;   0.9193 ;   0.9209 ;   0.9280 ) 0.9657
MBK T r ( 0.9578 ;   0.9552 ;   0.9390 ;   0.9317 ) 0.9689
OPL T r ( 0.9513 ;   0.9567 ;   0.9771 ;   0.9974 ) 0.9797
PEO T r ( 0.9466 ;   0.9512 ;   0.9561 ;   0.9606 ) 0.9727
PGE T r ( 0.9087 ;   0.9177 ;   0.9369 ;   0.9497 ) 0.9686
PGN T r ( 0.9398 ;   0.9326 ;   0.9278 ;   0.9182 ) 0.9675
PKN T r ( 0.9763 ;   0.9737 ;   0.9575 ;   0.9524 ) 0.9756
PKO T r ( 0.8270 ;   0.8291 ;   0.8344 ;   0.8430 ) 0.9576
PLY T r ( 0.7742 ;   0.7768 ;   0.7945 ;   0.8040 ) 0.9362
PZU T r ( 0.8334 ;   0.8336 ;   0.8369 ;   0.8414 ) 0.9516
SPL T r ( 0.7403 ;   0.7451 ;   0.7553 ;   0.7606 ) 0.9461
TPE T r ( 0.9279 ;   0.9402 ;   0.9586 ;   0.9586 ) 0.9745
Table 4. Imprecise recommendations determined with the use of the Sharpe ratio.
Table 4. Imprecise recommendations determined with the use of the Sharpe ratio.
Recommendation Choice Function
Stock Company A A A 0 A + A + + Energy MeasureEntropy Measure
ALR 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
CCC 0 0.3812 0.3812 1 0.6188 2.3812 0.2966
CDR 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
CPS 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
DNP 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
JSW 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
KGH 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
LTS 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
LPP 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
MBK 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
OPL 0 0.8719 0.8719 1 0.1281 2.8719 0.0833
PEO 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PGE 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PGN 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PKN 0 0.2692 0.2692 1 0.7308 2.2692 0.1926
PKO 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PLY 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PZU 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
SPL 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
TPE 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Table 5. SPT H s for the Jensen’s alpha.
Table 5. SPT H s for the Jensen’s alpha.
Stock Company OEDF   V s SPT   H s
ALR T r ( 0.9896 ;   0.9852 ;   0.9744 ;   0.9686 ) 0.9720
CCC T r ( 0.9136 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9827 ) 0.9667
CDR T r ( 0.7847 ;   0.7847 ;   0.7986 ;   0.7986 ) 0.8837
CPS T r ( 0.9168 ;   0.9231 ;   0.9384 ;   0.9488 ) 0.9473
DNP T r ( 0.9352 ;   0.9352 ;   0.9358 ;   0.9491 ) 0.9517
JSW T r ( 0.8975 ;   0.9342 ;   0.9718 ;   0.9718 ) 1.0000
KGH T r ( 0.9216 ;   0.9399 ;   0.9409 ;   0.9529 ) 0.9604
LTS T r ( 0.9318 ;   0.9265 ;   0.9016 ;   0.8916 ) 0.9496
LPP T r ( 0.9001 ;   0.9193 ;   0.9209 ;   0.9280 ) 0.9690
MBK T r ( 0.9578 ;   0.9552 ;   0.9390 ;   0.9317 ) 0.9212
OPL T r ( 0.9513 ;   0.9567 ;   0.9771 ;   0.9974 ) 0.9692
PEO T r ( 0.9466 ;   0.9512 ;   0.9561 ;   0.9606 ) 0.9762
PGE T r ( 0.9087 ;   0.9177 ;   0.9369 ;   0.9497 ) 0.9413
PGN T r ( 0.9398 ;   0.9326 ;   0.9278 ;   0.9182 ) 0.9459
PKN T r ( 0.9763 ;   0.9737 ;   0.9575 ;   0.9524 ) 0.9607
PKO T r ( 0.8270 ;   0.8291 ;   0.8344 ;   0.8430 ) 0.9296
PLY T r ( 0.7742 ;   0.7768 ;   0.7945 ;   0.8040 ) 0.9215
PZU T r ( 0.8334 ;   0.8336 ;   0.8369 ;   0.8414 ) 0.9287
SPL T r ( 0.7403 ;   0.7451 ;   0.7553 ;   0.7606 ) 0.8942
TPE T r ( 0.9279 ;   0.9402 ;   0.9586 ;   0.9586 ) 0.9570
Table 6. Imprecise recommendations determined with the use of Jensen’s alpha.
Table 6. Imprecise recommendations determined with the use of Jensen’s alpha.
Recommendation Choice Function
Stock Company A A A 0 A + A + + Energy MeasureEntropy Measure
ALR 0.4138 1 0.5862 0.5862 0 2.5862 0.3303
CCC 0 0.8840 0.8840 1 0.1160 2.8840 0.0748
CDR 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
CPS 0 0.1442 0.1442 1 0.8558 2.1442 0.0947
DNP 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
JSW 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
KGH 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
LTS 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
LPP 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
MBK 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
OPL 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
PEO 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PGE 0 0.6563 0.6563 1 0.3437 2.6563 0.2598
PGN 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PKN 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
PKO 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PLY 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PZU 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
SPL 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
TPE 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
Table 7. SPT H s for the Treynor ratio.
Table 7. SPT H s for the Treynor ratio.
Stock Company OEDF   V s SPT   H s
ALR T r ( 0.9896 ;   0.9852 ;   0.9744 ;   0.9686 ) 0.9545
CCC T r ( 0.9136 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9827 ) 0.9401
CDR T r ( 0.7847 ;   0.7847 ;   0.7986 ;   0.7986 ) 0.7283
CPS T r ( 0.9168 ;   0.9231 ;   0.9384 ;   0.9488 ) 0.9029
DNP T r ( 0.9352 ;   0.9352 ;   0.9358 ;   0.9491 ) 0.9005
JSW T r ( 0.8975 ;   0.9342 ;   0.9718 ;   0.9718 ) 0.9877
KGH T r ( 0.9216 ;   0.9399 ;   0.9409 ;   0.9529 ) 0.9171
LTS T r ( 0.9318 ;   0.9265 ;   0.9016 ;   0.8916 ) 0.8689
LPP T r ( 0.9001 ;   0.9193 ;   0.9209 ;   0.9280 ) 0.8995
MBK T r ( 0.9578 ;   0.9552 ;   0.9390 ;   0.9317 ) 0.8730
OPL T r ( 0.9513 ;   0.9567 ;   0.9771 ;   0.9974 ) 0.9505
PEO T r ( 0.9466 ;   0.9512 ;   0.9561 ;   0.9606 ) 0.9410
PGE T r ( 0.9087 ;   0.9177 ;   0.9369 ;   0.9497 ) 0.8910
PGN T r ( 0.9398 ;   0.9326 ;   0.9278 ;   0.9182 ) 0.8891
PKN T r ( 0.9763 ;   0.9737 ;   0.9575 ;   0.9524 ) 0.9309
PKO T r ( 0.8270 ;   0.8291 ;   0.8344 ;   0.8430 ) 0.7901
PLY T r ( 0.7742 ;   0.7768 ;   0.7945 ;   0.8040 ) 0.7472
PZU T r ( 0.8334 ;   0.8336 ;   0.8369 ;   0.8414 ) 0.7909
SPL T r ( 0.7403 ;   0.7451 ;   0.7553 ;   0.7606 ) 0.7088
TPE T r ( 0.9279 ;   0.9402 ;   0.9586 ;   0.9586 ) 0.9254
Table 8. Imprecise recommendations determined with use Treynor ratio.
Table 8. Imprecise recommendations determined with use Treynor ratio.
Recommendation Choice Function
Stock Company A A A 0 A + A + + Energy MeasureEntropy Measure
ALR 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
CCC 0.4804 1 0.5196 0.5196 0 2.5196 0.4050
CDR 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
CPS 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
DNP 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
JSW 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
KGH 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
LTS 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
LPP 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
MBK 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
OPL 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
PEO 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
PGE 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
PGN 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
PKN 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
PKO 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
PLY 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
PZU 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
SPL 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
TPE 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Table 9. SPT H s for the Sortino ratio.
Table 9. SPT H s for the Sortino ratio.
Stock Company OEDF   V s SPT   H s
ALR T r ( 0.9896 ;   0.9852 ;   0.9744 ;   0.9686 ) 0.9793
CCC T r ( 0.9136 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9827 ) 0.9766
CDR T r ( 0.7847 ;   0.7847 ;   0.7986 ;   0.7986 ) 0.9507
CPS T r ( 0.9168 ;   0.9231 ;   0.9384 ;   0.9488 ) 0.9706
DNP T r ( 0.9352 ;   0.9352 ;   0.9358 ;   0.9491 ) 0.9848
JSW T r ( 0.8975 ;   0.9342 ;   0.9718 ;   0.9718 ) 0.9826
KGH T r ( 0.9216 ;   0.9399 ;   0.9409 ;   0.9529 ) 0.9731
LTS T r ( 0.9318 ;   0.9265 ;   0.9016 ;   0.8916 ) 0.9630
LPP T r ( 0.9001 ;   0.9193 ;   0.9209 ;   0.9280 ) 0.9665
MBK T r ( 0.9578 ;   0.9552 ;   0.9390 ;   0.9317 ) 0.9687
OPL T r ( 0.9513 ;   0.9567 ;   0.9771 ;   0.9974 ) 0.9796
PEO T r ( 0.9466 ;   0.9512 ;   0.9561 ;   0.9606 ) 0.9738
PGE T r ( 0.9087 ;   0.9177 ;   0.9369 ;   0.9497 ) 0.9665
PGN T r ( 0.9398 ;   0.9326 ;   0.9278 ;   0.9182 ) 0.9676
PKN T r ( 0.9763 ;   0.9737 ;   0.9575 ;   0.9524 ) 0.9757
PKO T r ( 0.8270 ;   0.8291 ;   0.8344 ;   0.8430 ) 0.9619
PLY T r ( 0.7742 ;   0.7768 ;   0.7945 ;   0.8040 ) 0.9394
PZU T r ( 0.8334 ;   0.8336 ;   0.8369 ;   0.8414 ) 0.9516
SPL T r ( 0.7403 ;   0.7451 ;   0.7553 ;   0.7606 ) 0.9334
TPE T r ( 0.9279 ;   0.9402 ;   0.9586 ;   0.9586 ) 0.9741
Table 10. Imprecise recommendations determined with the use of the Sortino ratio.
Table 10. Imprecise recommendations determined with the use of the Sortino ratio.
Recommendation Choice Function
Stock Company A A A 0 A + A + + Energy MeasureEntropy Measure
ALR 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
CCC 0 0.3370 0.3370 1 0.663 2.3370 0.0228
CDR 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
CPS 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
DNP 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
JSW 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
KGH 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
LTS 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
LPP 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
MBK 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
OPL 0 0.8769 0.8769 1 0.1231 2.8769 0.0798
PEO 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PGE 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PGN 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PKN 0 0.2308 0.2308 1 0.7692 2.2308 0.1607
PKO 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PLY 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PZU 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
SPL 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
TPE 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Table 11. SPT H s for the Roy’s criterion.
Table 11. SPT H s for the Roy’s criterion.
Stock Company OEDF   V s SPT   H s
ALR T r ( 0.9896 ;   0.9852 ;   0.9744 ;   0.9686 ) 0.9836
CCC T r ( 0.9136 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9646 ;   0.9827 ) 0.9815
CDR T r ( 0.7847 ;   0.7847 ;   0.7986 ;   0.7986 ) 0.9649
CPS T r ( 0.9168 ;   0.9231 ;   0.9384 ;   0.9488 ) 0.9772
DNP T r ( 0.9352 ;   0.9352 ;   0.9358 ;   0.9491 ) 0.9873
JSW T r ( 0.8975 ;   0.9342 ;   0.9718 ;   0.9718 ) 0.9861
KGH T r ( 0.9216 ;   0.9399 ;   0.9409 ;   0.9529 ) 0.9799
LTS T r ( 0.9318 ;   0.9265 ;   0.9016 ;   0.8916 ) 0.9725
LPP T r ( 0.9001 ;   0.9193 ;   0.9209 ;   0.9280 ) 0.9748
MBK T r ( 0.9578 ;   0.9552 ;   0.9390 ;   0.9317 ) 0.9769
OPL T r ( 0.9513 ;   0.9567 ;   0.9771 ;   0.9974 ) 0.9841
PEO T r ( 0.9466 ;   0.9512 ;   0.9561 ;   0.9606 ) 0.9794
PGE T r ( 0.9087 ;   0.9177 ;   0.9369 ;   0.9497 ) 0.9767
PGN T r ( 0.9398 ;   0.9326 ;   0.9278 ;   0.9182 ) 0.9760
PKN T r ( 0.9763 ;   0.9737 ;   0.9575 ;   0.9524 ) 0.9814
PKO T r ( 0.8270 ;   0.8291 ;   0.8344 ;   0.8430 ) 0.9694
PLY T r ( 0.7742 ;   0.7768 ;   0.7945 ;   0.8040 ) 0.9548
PZU T r ( 0.8334 ;   0.8336 ;   0.8369 ;   0.8414 ) 0.9653
SPL T r ( 0.7403 ;   0.7451 ;   0.7553 ;   0.7606 ) 0.9557
TPE T r ( 0.9279 ;   0.9402 ;   0.9586 ;   0.9586 ) 0.9806
Table 12. Imprecise recommendations.
Table 12. Imprecise recommendations.
Recommendation Choice Function
Stock Company A A A 0 A + A + + Energy MeasureEntropy Measure
ALR 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
CCC 0 0.0663 0.0663 1 0.9337 2.0663 0.0414
CDR 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
CPS 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
DNP 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
JSW 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
KGH 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
LTS 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
LPP 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
MBK 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
OPL 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
PEO 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PGE 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PGN 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PKN 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PKO 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PLY 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
PZU 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
SPL 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
TPE 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Table 13. Pareto optimum of portfolio π components.
Table 13. Pareto optimum of portfolio π components.
Stock CompanyPareto Optimum
ALR { Λ ˜ A L R , 3 }
CCC { Λ ˜ C C C , 4 , Λ ˜ C C C , 5 }
CDR { Λ ˜ C D R , 1 ,   Λ ˜ C D R , 2 ,   Λ ˜ C D R , 3 ,   Λ ˜ C D R , 4 , Λ ˜ C D R , 5 }
CPS { Λ ˜ C P S , 1 ,   Λ ˜ C P S , 3 ,   Λ ˜ C P S , 4 , Λ ˜ C P S , 5 }
DNP { Λ ˜ D N P , 1 ,   Λ ˜ D N P , 2 ,   Λ ˜ D N P , 3 ,   Λ ˜ D N P , 4 , Λ ˜ D N P , 5 }
JSW { Λ ˜ J S W , 1 ,   Λ ˜ J S W , 2 ,   Λ ˜ J S W , 3 ,   Λ ˜ J S W , 4 , Λ ˜ J S W , 5 }
KGH { Λ ˜ K G H , 1 ,   Λ ˜ K G H , 2 ,   Λ ˜ K G H , 3 ,   Λ ˜ K G H , 4 , Λ ˜ K G H , 5 }
LTS { Λ ˜ L T S , 1 ,   Λ ˜ L T S , 2 ,   Λ ˜ L T S , 3 ,   Λ ˜ L T S , 4 , Λ ˜ L T S , 5 }
LPP { Λ ˜ L P P , 1 ,   Λ ˜ L P P , 2 ,   Λ ˜ L P P , 3 ,   Λ ˜ L P P , 4 , Λ ˜ L P P , 5 }
MBK { Λ ˜ M B K , 1 ,   Λ ˜ M B K , 2 ,   Λ ˜ M B K , 3 ,   Λ ˜ M B K , 4 , Λ ˜ M B K , 5 }
OPL { Λ ˜ O P L , 3 }
PEO { Λ ˜ P E O , 1 ,   Λ ˜ P E O , 2 ,   Λ ˜ P E O , 3 ,   Λ ˜ P E O , 4 , Λ ˜ P E O , 5 }
PGE { Λ ˜ P G E , 1 ,   Λ ˜ P G E , 3 ,   Λ ˜ P G E , 4 , Λ ˜ P G E , 5 }
PGN { Λ ˜ P G N , 1 ,   Λ ˜ P G N , 2 ,   Λ ˜ P G N , 3 ,   Λ ˜ P G N , 4 , Λ ˜ P G N , 5 }
PKN { Λ ˜ P K N , 3 ,   Λ ˜ P K N , 5 }
PKO { Λ ˜ P K O , 1 ,   Λ ˜ P K O , 2 ,   Λ ˜ P K O , 3 ,   Λ ˜ P K O , 4 , Λ ˜ P K O , 5 }
PLY { Λ ˜ P L Y , 1 ,   Λ ˜ P L Y , 2 ,   Λ ˜ P L Y , 3 ,   Λ ˜ P L Y , 4 , Λ ˜ P L Y , 5 }
PZU { Λ ˜ P Z U , 1 ,   Λ ˜ P Z U , 2 ,   Λ ˜ P Z U , 3 ,   Λ ˜ P Z U , 4 , Λ ˜ P Z U , 5 }
SPL { Λ ˜ S P L , 1 ,   Λ ˜ S P L , 2 ,   Λ ˜ S P L , 3 ,   Λ ˜ S P L , 4 , Λ ˜ S P L , 5 }
TPE { Λ ˜ T P E , 1 ,   Λ ˜ T P E , 2 ,   Λ ˜ T P E , 3 ,   Λ ˜ T P E , 4 , Λ ˜ T P E , 5 }
Table 14. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for ALR.
Table 14. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for ALR.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ A L R , i ) e ( Λ ˜ A L R , i )
Λ ˜ A L R , 1 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
Λ ˜ A L R , 2 0.4138 1 0.5862 0.5862 0 2.5862 0.3303
Λ ˜ A L R , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ A L R , 4 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
Λ ˜ A L R , 5 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
Λ ˜ A L R , W J R 1 1 0 0 0
Λ ˜ A L R , S J R 1 1 0 0 0
Table 15. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for CCC.
Table 15. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for CCC.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ C C C , i ) e ( Λ ˜ C C C , i )
Λ ˜ C C C , 1 0 0.3812 0.3812 1 0.6188 2.3812 0.2966
Λ ˜ C C C , 2 0 0.8840 0.8840 1 0.1160 2.8840 0.0748
Λ ˜ C C C , 3 0.4804 1 0.5196 0.5196 0 2.5196 0.4050
Λ ˜ C C C , 4 0 0.3370 0.3370 1 0.6630 2.3370 0.0228
Λ ˜ C C C , 5 0 0.0663 0.0663 1 0.9337 2.0663 0.0414
Λ ˜ C C C , W J R 00.33700.337010.9337
Λ ˜ C C C , S J R 00.06630.066310.6630
Table 16. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for CDR.
Table 16. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for CDR.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ C D R , i ) e ( Λ ˜ C D R , i )
Λ ˜ C D R , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ C D R , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ C D R , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ C D R , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ C D R , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ C D R , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ C D R , S J R 00000
Table 17. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for CPS.
Table 17. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for CPS.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ C P S , i ) e ( Λ ˜ C P S , i )
Λ ˜ C P S , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ C P S , 2 0 0.1442 0.1442 1 0.8558 2.1442 0.0947
Λ ˜ C P S , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ C P S , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ C P S , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ C P S , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ C P S , S J R 00000
Table 18. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for DNP.
Table 18. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for DNP.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ D N P , i ) e ( Λ ˜ D N P , i )
Λ ˜ D N P , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ D N P , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ D N P , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ D N P , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ D N P , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ D N P , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ D N P , S J R 00000
Table 19. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for JSW.
Table 19. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for JSW.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ J S W , i ) e ( Λ ˜ J S W , i )
Λ ˜ J S W , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ J S W , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ J S W , 3 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ J S W , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ J S W , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ J S W , W J R 00011
Λ ˜ J S W , S J R 00011
Table 20. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for KGH.
Table 20. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for KGH.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ K G H , i ) e ( Λ ˜ K G H , i )
Λ ˜ K G H , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ K G H , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ K G H , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ K G H , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ K G H , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ K G H , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ K G H , S J R 00000
Table 21. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for LTS.
Table 21. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for LTS.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ L T S , i ) e ( Λ ˜ L T S , i )
Λ ˜ L T S , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ L T S , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ L T S , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ L T S , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ L T S , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ L T S , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ L T S , S J R 00000
Table 22. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for LPP.
Table 22. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for LPP.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ L P P , i ) e ( Λ ˜ L P P , i )
Λ ˜ L P P , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ L P P , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ L P P , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ L P P , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ L P P , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ L P P , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ L P P , S J R 00000
Table 23. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for MBK.
Table 23. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for MBK.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ M B K , i ) e ( Λ ˜ M B K , i )
Λ ˜ M B K , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ M B K , 2 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ M B K , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ M B K , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ M B K , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ M B K , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ M B K , S J R 00000
Table 24. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for OPL.
Table 24. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for OPL.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ O P L , i ) e ( Λ ˜ O P L , i )
Λ ˜ O P L , 1 0 0.8719 0.8719 1 0.1281 2.8719 0.0833
Λ ˜ O P L , 2 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
Λ ˜ O P L , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ O P L , 4 0 0.8769 0.8769 1 0.1231 2.8769 0.0798
Λ ˜ O P L , 5 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
Λ ˜ O P L , W J R 11000
Λ ˜ O P L , S J R 11000
Table 25. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PEO.
Table 25. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PEO.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ P E O , i ) e ( Λ ˜ P E O , i )
Λ ˜ P E O , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P E O , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P E O , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ P E O , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P E O , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P E O , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ P E O , S J R 00000
Table 26. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PGE.
Table 26. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PGE.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ P G E , i ) e ( Λ ˜ P G E , i )
Λ ˜ P G E , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P G E , 2 0 0.6563 0.6563 1 0.3437 2.6563 0.2598
Λ ˜ P G E , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ P G E , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P G E , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P G E , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ P G E , S J R 00000
Table 27. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PGN.
Table 27. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PGN.
Kryterium A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ P G N , i ) e ( Λ ˜ P G N , i )
Λ ˜ P G N , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P G N , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P G N , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ P G N , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P G N , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P G N , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ P G N , S J R 00000
Table 28. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PKN.
Table 28. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PKN.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ P K N , i ) e ( Λ ˜ P K N , i )
Λ ˜ P K N , 1 0 0.2692 0.2692 1 0.7308 2.2692 0.1926
Λ ˜ P K N , 2 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
Λ ˜ P K N , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ P K N , 4 0 0.2308 0.2308 1 0.7692 2.2308 0.1607
Λ ˜ P K N , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P K N , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ P K N , S J R 00000
Table 29. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PKO.
Table 29. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PKO.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ P K O , i ) e ( Λ ˜ P K O , i )
Λ ˜ P K O , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P K O , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P K O , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ P K O , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P K O , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P K O , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ P K O , S J R 00000
Table 30. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PLY.
Table 30. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PLY.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ P L Y , i ) e ( Λ ˜ P L Y , i )
Λ ˜ P L Y , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P L Y , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P L Y , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ P L Y , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P L Y , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P L Y , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ P L Y , S J R 00000
Table 31. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PZU.
Table 31. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for PZU.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ P Z U , i ) e ( Λ ˜ P Z U , i )
Λ ˜ P Z U , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P Z U , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P Z U , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ P Z U , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P Z U , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ P Z U , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ P Z U , S J R 00000
Table 32. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for SPL.
Table 32. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for SPL.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ S P L , i ) e ( Λ ˜ S P L , i )
Λ ˜ S P L , 1 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ S P L , 2 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ S P L , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ S P L , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ S P L , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ S P L , W J R 11011
Λ ˜ S P L , S J R 00000
Table 33. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for TPE.
Table 33. Imprecise and Pareto optimal recommendations for TPE.
Criterion A A A 0 A + A + + d ( Λ ˜ T P E , i ) e ( Λ ˜ T P E , i )
Λ ˜ T P E , 1 0   0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ T P E , 2 0 1 1 1 0 3 0
Λ ˜ T P E , 3 1 1 0 0 0 2 0
Λ ˜ T P E , 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ T P E , 5 0 0 0 1 1 2 0
Λ ˜ T P E , W J R 11111
Λ ˜ T P E , S J R 00000

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, A. On Application Oriented Fuzzy Numbers for Imprecise Investment Recommendations. Symmetry 2020, 12, 1672. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym12101672

AMA Style

Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak A. On Application Oriented Fuzzy Numbers for Imprecise Investment Recommendations. Symmetry. 2020; 12(10):1672. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym12101672

Chicago/Turabian Style

Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, Anna. 2020. "On Application Oriented Fuzzy Numbers for Imprecise Investment Recommendations" Symmetry 12, no. 10: 1672. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym12101672

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop