Next Article in Journal / Special Issue
Decomposing the Bonferroni Inequality Index by Subgroups: Shapley Value and Balance of Inequality
Previous Article in Journal
Data-Driven Jump Detection Thresholds for Application in Jump Regressions
Previous Article in Special Issue
Income Inequality, Cohesiveness and Commonality in the Euro Area: A Semi-Parametric Boundary-Free Analysis
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

On the Decomposition of the Esteban and Ray Index by Income Sources

by
Elena Bárcena-Martín
1 and
Jacques Silber
2,3,4,*
1
Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales, Universidad de Málaga, Calle Ejido 6, Málaga 29071, Spain
2
Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University, 52900 Ramat-Gan, Israel
3
LISER, Esch-sur-Alzette L-4366, Luxembourg
4
Centro Camilo Dagum, Tuscan Interuniversity Centre, Advanced Statistics for Equitable and Sustainable Development, Università di Pisa, Dipartimento di Economia e Management, Pisa 56124, Italy
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Econometrics 2018, 6(2), 17; https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics6020017
Submission received: 18 January 2018 / Revised: 22 February 2018 / Accepted: 11 March 2018 / Published: 26 March 2018
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Econometrics and Income Inequality)

Abstract

:
This paper proposes a simple algorithm based on a matrix formulation to compute the Esteban and Ray (ER) polarization index. It then shows how the algorithm introduced leads to quite a simple decomposition of polarization by income sources. Such a breakdown was not available hitherto. The decomposition we propose will thus allow one to determine the sign, as well as the magnitude, of the impact of the various income sources on the ER polarization index. A simple empirical illustration based on EU data is provided.
JEL Classification:
D31; D63; J31

1. Introduction

During the past 25 years, many studies attempted to measure the extent of the middle class and stressed the link between the concept of bipolarization and the importance of the middle class. Another strand of the economic literature emphasized the concept of polarization (or multi-polarization). The basic contribution here is that of Esteban and Ray (1994) who linked the concept of polarization to the notions of identification, alienation, and potential social conflict. Identification refers to the idea that an individual feels some degree of identification with those who are ‘close’ to him/her. Identification is thus an increasing function of the number of individuals who are in the same income class as that individual. The alienation function on the contrary characterizes the antagonism caused by income differences so that an individual will feel alienated from those who are ‘far away’ from him/her. While Esteban and Ray (1994), as well as Esteban et al. (2007), assumed that the number of groups was determined ex ante, Duclos et al. (2004) extended the analysis of polarization to the continuous case, letting the data determine the number of relevant groups and poles.
The focus of most empirical studies of bi-polarization and polarization was on the distribution of total income. There have however been a few attempts to decompose bipolarization and polarization indices by income sources (e.g., Araar 2008; Deutsch and Silber 2010) but the procedures are not very simple. More recently, Bárcena-Martín et al. (2017) proposed a simple matrix formulation to decompose the Foster and Wolfson bi-polarization index by income sources.
The main contribution of the present paper is to introduce a simple algorithm to compute the Esteban and Ray (1994) polarization index. We derive this algorithm from the simple matrix formulation suggested by Silber (1989) to compute the Gini index. We then show that, with such an approach, it is easy to derive the contribution of various income sources (or explanatory variables in the case of an earnings function) to the degree of polarization of the distribution of total income.
Section 2 describes the algorithm allowing the simple computation of the ER index polarization index while Section 3 shows how such a formulation simplifies the decomposition of this index by income sources. Section 4 presents a simple empirical illustration and Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Matrix Representation of the Esteban and Ray (1994) ER Polarization Index

The Esteban and Ray (1994) polarization index ER is expressed as
E R = i = 1 n j = 1 n v i β v j | μ i μ j |
where v k is the relative population frequency of population subgroup k , μ k the mean income1 of group k and β a parameter which varies between 2 and 2.6 (see, Esteban and Ray 1994).
We can also write expression (1) as
E R = i = 1 n μ i v i ( j = 1 i 1 v j β j = i + 1 n v j β ) + i = 1 n μ i v i β ( j = 1 i 1 v j j = i + 1 n v j )
where the mean incomes μ i are ranked by increasing values.
More generally, assuming n population subgroups, expression (2) becomes
ER = t’Gs + v’Gr = ERA + ERB
In (3), E R A and E R B are the two components of the ER index, t is a (1 by n) row vector, written as t = [ v 1 β   v 2 β   v n β ] , s is a (n by 1) column vector which, as row vector, would be written as s = [ μ 1 v 1   μ 2 v 2   μ n v n ] ,   v is a (1 by n) row vector written as v = [ v 1   v 2 v n ] and r is a (n by 1) column vector which, as a row vector would be expressed as r = [ ( μ 1 v 1 β )   ( μ 2 v 2 β ) ( μ n v n β ) ] . G is a square n by n matrix, called G-matrix, whose typical element g i j is equal to 0 if i = j , to −1 if j > i and to +1 if i > j (see, Silber 1989, for more details on this G-matrix2). It is important to stress that the elements μ i v i in vector s’ and the elements ( μ i v i β ) in vector r’ have both to be ranked by decreasing values of the mean incomes μ i .
Let τ’ be a (1 by n) row vector, written as τ = [ ( v 1 β i = 1 n v i β ) ( v i β i = 1 n v i β ) ( v n β i = 1 n v i β ) ] . Let also θ be a (n by 1) column vector of the income shares ( μ i v i ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) ) . In other words, if we call ( v i β i = 1 n v i β ) the ‘identification modified population share’ of population subgroup i, the expression τ’ is a kind of Gini index comparing a priori shares which are the ‘identification modified population shares’ with a posteriori shares which are the actual income shares of the various population subgroups, the comparison being made via the linear operator G, the G-matrix.
Similarly, let η’ be a (n by 1) row vector whose typical element η i is written as η i = ( μ i v i β i = 1 n μ i v i β ) . η i will be labeled the ‘identification modified income share’ of population subgroup i. The expression v G η is then a kind of Gini index, comparing a priori shares, the actual population shares, with a posteriori shares, the ‘identification modified income shares’ of the various population subgroups. This comparison is made again via the linear operator G, the G-matrix.
Expression (3) is then rewritten as
E R = ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) [ τ G θ ] + ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) [ v G η ]
In other words, the polarization index is equal to the corrected sum of two Gini-related indices. The first one compares the ‘identification modified population shares’ with the actual income shares of the different population subgroups. The second one compares the actual population shares with the ‘identification modified income shares’ of the different population subgroups. The first correction factor is equal to the product ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) while the second correction factor is equal to the product ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) ( i = 1 n v i ) = ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) .

3. Decomposing the ER Index by Income Sources

Assume there are J income sources. The average income μ i , in population subgroup i, may then be expressed as
μ i = j = 1 J μ i j
so that expression (3) may also be written as
E R = t G [ j = 1 J s . j ] + v G [ j = 1 J r . j ]
where s . j is a (n by 1) column vector whose typical element s i j is equal to v i μ i j while r . j is a (n by 1) column vector whose typical element r i j is equal to v i β μ i j . Note that the elements s i j in vector s . j and the elements r i j in vector r . j have to be ranked by decreasing mean incomes μ i .
We may then rewrite (6) as
E R = j = 1 J D j
where D j , the contribution of income source j to the ER index, is expressed as
D j = [ t G s . j + v G r . j ]
We could also express (8) as
D j = [ t G s . j ˜   t G s . j t G s . j ˜ + v G r . j ˜ v G r . j v G r . j ˜ ]
where s . j ˜ is a (n by 1) column vector whose typical elements s i j ˜ , which are equal to v i μ i j , are ranked in descending order of μ i j , while r . j ˜ is a (n by 1) column vector whose typical elements r i j ˜ , which are equal to v i β μ i j , are ranked also in descending order of μ i j .
Note however that
( t G s . j ˜ + v G r . j ˜ ) = E R j A + E R j B = E R j
where E R j is the Esteban and Ray polarization index for income source j, E R j A   and   E R j B being its two components.
Let us also define two correlation measures, C O R j A and C O R j B , with
C O R j A = t G s . j t G s . j ˜
C O R j B = v G r . j v G r . j ˜
These correlation measures may evidently be positive or negative.
Combining expressions (7)–(12) we derive that
E R = j = 1 J { [ E R j A C O R j A ] + [ E R j B C O R j B ] }
We therefore conclude that, ceteris paribus,
-
The higher E R j A , the higher the degree of polarization of the distribution of total income.
-
The higher E R j B , the higher the degree of polarization of the distribution of total income.
-
If C O R j A is positive, the higher this correlation measure, the higher the degree of polarization of the distribution of total income. However, if it is negative, it will have a negative impact on the overall Esteban and Ray index ER.
-
Similarly, if C O R j B is positive, the higher this correlation measure, the higher the degree of polarization of the distribution of total income. However, if it is negative, it will have a negative impact on the overall Esteban and Ray index ER3.

4. A Short Empirical Illustration

In this section, we present a simple empirical illustration, based on EU data from the European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC) data set for the 2016 wave (EUROSTAT 2016). EU-SILC is an international database that consists of comparable, country-specific data. We analyze polarization in the 17 countries with data available for 2016: AT (Austria), BE (Belgium), BG (Bulgaria), EE (Estonia), EL (Greece), ES (Spain), FR (France), HR (Croatia), HU (Hungary), LT (Lithuania), LV (Latvia), PL (Poland), PT (Portugal), RO (Romania), RS (Serbia), SE (Sweden), and SI (Slovenia). The units of analysis are the individuals and the unit of measurement is the household. The measure of income is the total disposable household income. Since a given level of household income corresponds to a different standard of living, depending on the size and composition of the household, we adjust incomes for differences in household size and composition using the “modified OECD” equivalence scale4. The latter assigns a value of 1 to the first adult in the household, 0.5 to each remaining adult, and 0.3 to each person younger than 14.
Disposable income includes net income from work, other private income not related to work, pensions and other social transfers. Net money income includes all income sources received by the household and by each of its current members in the year preceding the survey. Social insurance contributions, pay-as-you-earn taxes, and non-money income are not included in this definition of income.
The decomposition of the ER polarization index by income sources is based on three income sources:
  • Benefits (benefits) that include: old-age and survivor’ benefits, unemployment benefits, sickness benefits, disability benefits, education-related allowances, family/children related allowances, social exclusion not classified elsewhere, housing allowances
  • Income from rental of a property or land, interest, dividends, profit from capital investments in unincorporated business (property and interest)
  • Income available before including sources 1 and 2 (income before)
Table A1 in the Appendix gives, for each of these countries, the average value of these income sources, the average total income and the population size.
Table 1 refers to data in Euros. We give there the value of the ER index when the parameter β is equal to 2.5 and when it is equal to 1 (Gini related measure5). We also computed, as suggested by Esteban and Ray (1994), the ER index with these two values of the parameter β, for the case where the logarithm of income rather than income was the variable under study. Table 1 gives also, when income and not the logarithm of income is used, the relative contributions of the different income sources, to the ER index. It appears that the most important (relative) contribution to the value of the ER index is that of income before transfer (62.4%) while this source has a share in total income of 70.7%. On the contrary, benefits and ‘property income and interest’ have a higher relative contribution to the ER index (respectively 25.4% and 12.2%) than their share in total income (23.2% and 6.1%). We may also observe that the contributions of these sources to the Gini-related index (parameter β equal to 1) is quite similar to their contributions to the ER index (65.6, 24.9, and 9.5%). They actually lie between their contributions to the average total income and to the ER index.
When introducing the logarithm of income into the formulation of the ER index with β = 2.5, we observe that this index is quite small (0.045) when compared to its value (0.577) when β = 1.
Table 2 is similar to Table 1 but here all the computations are derived from PPP income data. While the relative contributions of the three income sources to the average EU PPP income (on the basis of the countries for which data were available) are quite similar to those presented in Table 1, the computation of the ER index and of the contributions of the income sources to this index show a somehow different picture. When the parameter β is equal to 2.5, it appears that the ER index is lower than in Table 1, whether this index is derived from income data or from the logarithm of incomes. What is more interesting is that there is an important decrease in the relative contribution of income before transfer (from 62.4% to 54.4%) when β = 2.5 and from 65.6% to 59.6% when β = 1. On the contrary, there is an increase in the relative contribution of benefits: from 25.4% to 28.6% when β = 2.5 and from 24.9% to 27.7% when β = 1. A similar increase is observed for property income and interest since the relative contribution rises from 12.2% to 17.0% when β = 2.5 and from 9.5% to 12.8% when β = 1. In short, when using PPP rather than current data, polarization and inequality turn out to be smaller, but the relative contribution of benefits and property income and interest to polarization and inequality rises.

5. Concluding Comments

This paper has shown how it is possible to express the Esteban and Ray (1994) ER index in matrix form. Such a formulation greatly simplifies the decomposition of this index by income sources. We gave a simple empirical illustration showing that this breakdown gives useful information as to the impact of the different income sources on the polarization of incomes. This illustration was based first on income data in Euros and then on PPP income data. We could also apply the proposed breakdown to an analysis of the polarization of the distribution of wages or earnings. If we estimate a traditional earnings function, we could then easily derive the contribution to the polarization of wages of the explanatory variables of such a function. Indeed, we intend to explore these issues in future empirical work.

Acknowledgments

Elena Bárcena-Martín gratefully acknowledges the financial support provided by the University of Malaga.

Author Contributions

Both authors contributed equally to the paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. The Similarity between the Decomposition by Income Sources of the Gini Index and of the ER Index

Remember that expression (4) is written as
E R = ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) [ τ G θ ] + ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) [ v G η ]
where τ’ is a (1 by n) row vector, written as τ = [ ( v 1 β i = 1 n v i β ) ( v i β i = 1 n v i β ) ( v n β i = 1 n v i β ) ] , θ a (n by 1) column vector of the income shares ( μ i v i ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) ) ,   η a (n by 1) row vector whose typical element η i is written as η i = ( μ i v i β i = 1 n μ i v i β ) and v’ a row vector of the population shares.
We can rewrite (A1) as
E R = ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) [ τ G ( j = 1 J θ j ) ] + ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) [ v G ( j = 1 J η j ) ]
where
θ j = ( μ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) ) = ( μ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ) ( ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) )
η j = ( μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i v i β ) = ( μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i v i β )
Given that the G-matrix is a linear operator we then derive that
E R = ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) [ j = 1 J τ G θ j ] + ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) [ j = 1 J v G η j ]
  E R = ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) [ j = 1 J τ G { ( μ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ) ( ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) ) } ] + ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) [ j = 1 J v G { ( μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i v i β ) } ]
E R = ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) { [ j = 1 J ( ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) ) τ G ( μ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ) ] } + ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) { [ j = 1 J ( i = 1 n μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i v i β ) v G ( μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β ) ] }
If instead of ranking the incomes μ i j by decreasing values of the incomes μ i , we rank them by decreasing values of the incomes μ i j , and call μ ˜ i j this re-ordered vector, we end up with
E R = ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) { [ j = 1 J ( ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) ) [ τ G ( μ ˜ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ) ] ] ( ( μ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ) / ( μ ˜ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ) ) } + ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) { [ j = 1 J ( i = 1 n μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i v i β ) [ v G ( μ ˜ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β ) ] ] ( ( μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β ) / ( μ ˜ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β ) ) } E R = ( i = 1 n v i β ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) j = 1 J α j β j γ j   + ( i = 1 n μ i v i β ) j = 1 J λ j ν j ρ j
with
α j = ( ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ( i = 1 n μ i v i ) )
β j = τ G ( μ ˜ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) )
γ j = ( ( μ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ) / ( μ ˜ i j v i ( i = 1 n μ i j v i ) ) )
λ j = ( i = 1 n μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i v i β )
ν j = v G ( μ ˜ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β )
ρ j = ( ( μ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β ) / ( μ ˜ i j v i β i = 1 n μ i j v i β ) )
where α j and λ j are similar to income shares, β j and ν j are components of the ER index for income source j and γ j and ρ j are ‘correlation measures’.
In other words, we have here quite a similar decomposition to that proposed by Lerman and Yitzhaki (1985) for the Gini index.
Table A1. Database.
Table A1. Database.
CountryMean Total IncomeIncome Before %Benefits %Property and Interest %Total Population
AT26,662.4870.0%27.3%2.7%7,963,391
BE24,520.274.0%24.6%1.3%9,319,177
BG4164.4976.4%21.9%1.7%6,235,715
EE11,043.9782.3%16.6%1.1%1,113,681
EL9161.7675.7%19.8%4.5%8,092,137
ES16,370.3471.9%24.4%3.6%42,446,793
FR25,730.8465.1%24.4%10.5%55,793,599
HR6663.0180.3%18.3%1.4%3,225,726
HU5474.7475.6%23.2%1.2%8,332,493
LT7742.3481.6%16.6%1.8%2,417,930
LV8135.0680.3%18.6%1.2%1,708,676
PL6912.3780.9%18.2%0.9%32,623,207
PT10,892.6179.1%17.7%3.2%8,183,986
RO2850.8282.4%17.5%0.1%15,991,057
RS3214.2174.2%25.0%0.8%5,432,579
SE29,761.277.6%17.6%4.8%7,647,944
SI13,678.0773.8%23.5%2.7%1,794,388
Country codes: AT (Austria), BE (Belgium), BG (Bulgaria), EE (Estonia), EL (Greece), ES (Spain), FR (France), HR (Croatia), HU (Hungary), LT (Lithuania), LV (Latvia), PL (Poland), PT (Portugal), RO (Romania), RS (Serbia), SE (Sweden), SI (Slovenia).

References

  1. Araar, Abdelkrim. 2008. On the Decomposition of Polarization Indices: Illustrations with Chinese and Nigerian Household Surveys. Working Paper 08-06. Centre Inter-universitaire sur le Risque, les Politiques Economiques et l’Emploi, Université Laval, Québec, Canda. [Google Scholar]
  2. Bárcena-Martín, Elena, Joseph Deutsch, and Jacques Silber. 2017. On the Decomposition of the Foster and Wolfson Bi-Polarization Index by Income Sources. Review of Income and Wealth. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Coulter, Fiona A. E., Frank A. Cowell, and Stephen P. Jenkins. 1992. Equivalence scales relativities and the extent of inequality and poverty. Economic Journal 102: 1067–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Deutsch, Joseph, and Jacques Silber. 2010. Analyzing the Impact of Income Sources on Changes in Bi-Polarization. In The Measurement of Individual Well-Being and Group Inequalities: Essays in Memory of Z. M. Berrebi. Edited by Joseph Deutsch and Jacques Silber. London: Routledge Economics, Taylor and Francis Group, pp. 127–52. [Google Scholar]
  5. Duclos, Jean-Yves, Joan Esteban, and Debraj Ray. 2004. Polarization: Concepts, Measurement, Estimation. Econometrica 72: 1737–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Esteban, Joan-Maria, and Debraj Ray. 1994. On the Measurement of Polarization. Econometrica 62: 819–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Esteban, Joan, Carlos Gradín, and Debraj Ray. 2007. An Extension of a Measure of Polarization, with an application to the income distribution of five OECD countries. Journal of Economic Inequality 5: 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Lerman, Robert I., and Shlomo Yitzhaki. 1985. Income Inequality Effects by Income Sources: A New Approach and Applications to the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics 67: 151–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Pyatt, Graham. 1976. On the Interpretation and Disaggregation of Gini coefficients. Economic Journal 86: 243–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Silber, Jacques. 1989. Factors Components, Population Subgroups and the Computation of the Gini Index of Inequality. The Review of Economics and Statistics LXXI: 107–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1
Esteban and Ray (1994) refer to the natural logarithm of income rather than to income. We will make a somehow similar assumption by stating that the mean income of a given group refers in fact to its mean income relative to the mean income in the whole population. To simplify the notations, we do not introduce the population mean income in the formulations.
2
As stressed already in Silber (1989), the first matrix formulation of the Gini index was proposed by Pyatt (1976).
3
Expression (13) reminds us of the decomposition of the Gini index by income sources (see, Lerman and Yitzhaki 1985) where the contribution of an income source to the overall Gini index is a function of the share of this source in total income, of the Gini index of this source and of the Gini-correlation between this source and total income. In (13) the contribution of an income source to the overall ER index is a function of the two components of the ER index for this source, and of two correlation measures. However the share of the source does not appear. In Appendix A, we provide a more detailed decomposition where the parallel with the traditional decomposition of the Gini index by income sources becomes evident.
4
For a survey of equivalence scales and related income distribution issues, and some comparisons of scale relativities, see Coulter et al. (1992).
5
When, in expression (1), we divide the income data by the average income and assume that β = 1, ER will equal to twice the traditional Gini index. What is called the absolute Gini index, is actually the product of the Gini index by the mean, so that when β = 1 and we use absolute incomes and not relative incomes in (1) ER will be equal to twice the absolute Gini index.
Table 1. Contributions of the income sources to the ER index (based on income data in Euros).
Table 1. Contributions of the income sources to the ER index (based on income data in Euros).
Measure ComputedValue for Total IncomeRelative Contribution of Income BeforeRelative Contribution of BenefitsRelative Contribution of Property Income and Interest
Average income with absolute contribution of income sources15,63411,0603626948
Average income with relative contribution of income sources100%70.70%23.20%6.10%
ER with parameter β equal to 2.5 computed on basis of relative incomes (relative contributions of income sources)0.03862.4%25.4%12.2%
ER with parameter β equal to 1 computed on basis of relative incomes (relative contributions of income sources)0.64565.6%24.9%9.5%
ER with parameter β equal to 2.5 and logarithms of incomes 0.045
ER with parameter β equal to 1 (like Gini) and logarithms of incomes0.577
Table 2. Contributions of the income sources to the ER index (based on PPP income data).
Table 2. Contributions of the income sources to the ER index (based on PPP income data).
Measure ComputedValue for Total IncomeRelative Contribution of Income BeforeRelative Contribution of BenefitsRelative Contribution of Property Income and Interest
Average income with absolute contribution of income sources17,04812,2333892924
Average income with relative contribution of income sources100%71.7%22.8%5.4%
ER with parameter β equal to 2.5 computed on basis of relative incomes (relative contributions of income sources)0.02454.4%28.6%17.0%
ER with parameter β equal to 1 computed on basis of relative incomes (relative contributions of income sources)0.41359.6%27.7%12.8%
ER with parameter β equal to 2.5 and logarithms of incomes0.026
ER with parameter β equal to 1 (like Gini) and logarithms of incomes0.478

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Bárcena-Martín, E.; Silber, J. On the Decomposition of the Esteban and Ray Index by Income Sources. Econometrics 2018, 6, 17. https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics6020017

AMA Style

Bárcena-Martín E, Silber J. On the Decomposition of the Esteban and Ray Index by Income Sources. Econometrics. 2018; 6(2):17. https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics6020017

Chicago/Turabian Style

Bárcena-Martín, Elena, and Jacques Silber. 2018. "On the Decomposition of the Esteban and Ray Index by Income Sources" Econometrics 6, no. 2: 17. https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics6020017

APA Style

Bárcena-Martín, E., & Silber, J. (2018). On the Decomposition of the Esteban and Ray Index by Income Sources. Econometrics, 6(2), 17. https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics6020017

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop