Next Article in Journal
Numerical Study of a Phase Change Material Energy Storage Tank Working with Carbon Nanotube–Water Nanofluid under Ha’il City Climatic Conditions
Previous Article in Journal
Algebraic Methods for Achieving Super-Resolution by Digital Antenna Arrays
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Risk-Sensitive Maximum Principle for Controlled System with Delay

School of Control Science and Engineering, Shandong University, Jinan 250061, China
Mathematics 2023, 11(4), 1058; https://doi.org/10.3390/math11041058
Submission received: 10 January 2023 / Revised: 10 February 2023 / Accepted: 16 February 2023 / Published: 20 February 2023
(This article belongs to the Section Computational and Applied Mathematics)

Abstract

:
Risk-sensitive maximum principle and verification theorem for controlled system with delay is obtained by virtue of classical convex variational technique. The prime feature in the research is that risk-sensitive parameter ϑ seriously affects adjoint equation and variational inequality. Moreover, a verification theorem of optimality is derived under some concavity conditions. An example is given to illustrate our theoretical result.

1. Introduction

Risk-sensitive stochastic control problem (RSCP) is an important kind of control problem, which is closely related to differential game of exponential linear quadratic Gaussian (LQG) problem [1,2,3,4,5], and can be widely used in asset management to describe investors’ risk attitude through a risk-sensitive parameter [6]. At first, dynamic programming principle (DPP) is mainly a tool to study RSCP. Ref. [7] established a maximum principle (MP) of RSCP based on large deviation theory in 1990. Since then, many studies on RSCP have focused on MP. In 2005, a new kind of risk-sensitive (RS) MP was derived in [8] by means of relationship between DPP and MP and a logarithmic transformation. On this basis, a general MP of partially observable and partial information RSCP was obtained in [9,10,11]. Ref. [12] studied an RSCP where the state system consisted of a jump diffusion. Refs. [13,14] established an MP for a mean-field (MF) partially observed RSCP and an MP for an MF type Markov regime-switching jump diffusion systems, respectively. Ref. [15] studied an RSCP in which the cost functional is given by a controlled backward stochastic differential equation (BSDE). The generalized risk-sensitive DPP of valued function was obtained.
Time delay is a familiar phenomenon and is used to describe historically relevant behaviors and phenomena in medicine, networking, and congestion fields, see [16,17,18,19,20]. Therefore, many models in the fields of economics, finance, and engineering are described by delayed stochastic systems, for example [21,22,23]. With wide application of stochastic systems with time delay, its optimization has always been a hot topic and has received more and more attention. In general, delayed systems are tricky to deal with due to its infinite dimensional state space structure and lack of Itô’s formula. An MP for optimal control problem with delay was obtained in [24]. Ref. [25] introduced a novel type BSDE named anticipated BSDE(ABSDE). Ref. [26] derived an MP for a stochastic control delay system using the duality between SDDE and ABSDE. Refs. [27,28,29] studied optimal control problems of different forms of delay systems. Ref. [30] studied an optimal control problem for RS MF SDDE with partial information and obtained a stochastic MP. Refs. [31,32,33] investigated the different types of stochastic differential game. In many papers and references therein, including [8,13,30], cost functional is type of exponential-integral RS. This paper considers a class of utility functional named hyperbolic absolute risk aversion (HARA). This cost functional has practical implications, where it can formulate a vital risk-sensitive optimal portfolio model.
In this paper, we investigate a kind of RSCP with delay and HARA expected utility functional with the exponent ϑ > 0 . The key contributions of this work are as follows:
(1)
Different from the systems investigated in [24,30], the state system considered in this paper is stochastic and delayed. Moreover, the cost functional is an HARA expected utility functional with exponent ϑ > 0 , which can be used to describe some specific financial phenomena. Thus, the results of this paper can be applied to solve more financial problems.
(2)
The existence of delay and the complexity of the cost functional cause some difficulties to handle the problem. Thus, a duality method and an expanding variable dimension method are adopted to obtain an MP. This is different from the methods in [3,4,8,9,24].
(3)
The adjoint equation and maximum condition are greatly affected by parameter ϑ . Note that if ϑ = 1 , we can obtain results similar to [26]. Thus, our results are more general than [26].
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. A formulation of RSCP with delay is given in Section 2. An MP and verification theorem of optimal control are derived in Section 3. Further, we consider an RSCP with a general running cost functional, and obtain MP and verification theorem for an optimal control in Section 4. Applied derived results, an RS management problem of pension fund deferred surplus is solved in Section 5. The last, we conclude this research with a concluding statement.

2. Problem Formulation

Let ( Ω , F , P ) be a complete filtered probability space with a natural filtration { F r } 0 r T generated by a one-dimensional standard Brownian motion { B ( r ) } 0 r T . T > 0 is the finite fixed time node. ς > 0 is the time delay quantity. R represents a one-dimensional Euclidean space. There are brief notations below for simplification: C [ ς , 0 ] = { m ( · ) : [ ς , 0 ] R | m ( · ) is a continuous function}, L 2 ( ς , 0 ; U ) = { m ( · ) : [ ς , 0 ] U | m ( · ) is a deterministic continuous function satisfying δ 0 | m ( r ) | 2 d r < + } , L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R ) = { m ( · ) : Ω × [ 0 , T ] R | m ( · ) is an F t -adapted process satisfying E 0 T | m ( r ) | 2 d r < + } .
Consider an SDDE system
d x ν ( r ) = f ( r , x ν ( r ) , x ν ( r ς ) , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) d r + g ( r , x ν ( r ) , x ν ( r ς ) , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) d B ( r ) , r [ 0 , T ] , x ν ( r ) = ζ ( r ) , ν ( r ) = η ( r ) , r [ ς , 0 ] ,
where f , g : [ 0 , T ] × R 4 R , η ( · ) L 2 ( ς , 0 ; U ) ; ζ ( · ) C [ ς , 0 ] is F 0 -measurable and satisfies E sup ς r 0 | ζ ( r ) | 2 < + .
Define an admissible control set U a d = { ν ( r ) | ν ( r ) L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R ) , ν ( r ) U , a . s . , r [ 0 , T ] , and ν ( r ) = η ( r ) , r [ ς , 0 ] } , where U R is a non-empty, convex set.
A cost functional is
J ( ν ( · ) ) = 1 ϑ E [ Θ ( x ν ( T ) ) ] ϑ ,
where ϑ > 0 is a risk-sensitivity index.
Problem 1 (RSC).
Find a μ ( · ) U a d achieving
J ( μ ( · ) ) = max ν ( · ) U a d J ( ν ( · ) )
associated with (1). Any μ ( · ) exists, then μ ( · ) is called an optimal control. The corresponding state is denoted by x μ ( · ) .

3. MP and Verification Theorem

We need assumptions below.
Hypothesis 1 (H1).
f, g are continuously differentiable in ( x ν , x δ ν , ν , ν δ ) , and their derivatives are bounded.
Hypothesis 2 (H2).
Θ : R [ 0 , + ) is continuously differential with regard to x and | Θ | K ( 1 + | x | ) and derivative | Θ x | M , where M is a positive constant.
Hypothesis 3 (H3).
Let E [ Θ ( x ( T ) ) ] ( 2 ϑ 2 ) < + , when 0 < ϑ < 1 , and let E [ x ( T ) ] ( 2 ϑ 2 ) < + , when ϑ > 1 .

3.1. MP

Let ( μ ( · ) , x μ ( · ) ) be an optimal solution of Problem (RSC), and ν 1 ( · ) L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R ) be such that μ ( · ) + ν 1 ( · ) U a d . Since U is convex, μ ε ( · ) = μ ( · ) + ε ν 1 ( · ) , 0 ε 1 is also in U a d . Its corresponding trajectory is denoted by x ε ( · ) .
Introduce these signs for ease of notation.
b ε ( r ) = b ( r , x ε ( r ) , x ε ( r ς ) , μ ε ( r ) , μ ε ( r ς ) ) , b μ ( r ) = b ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) ) , b ϕ μ ( r ) = b ϕ ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) ) ,
where b = f , g and ϕ = x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς .
The equation of variation is
d x 1 μ ( r ) = [ f x μ x 1 μ ( r ) + f x ς μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) + f ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + f ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) ] d r + [ g x μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ) + g x ς μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) + g ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + g ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) ] d B ( r ) , r [ 0 , T ] , x 1 μ ( r ) = 0 , ν 1 ( r ) = 0 , r [ ς , 0 ] .
By similar means in [26], we can obtain following result.
Lemma 1.
Suppose that (H1) is tenable, there is
lim ε 0 sup 0 r T E | x ˜ ( r ) | 2 = 0 ,
where x ˜ ( r ) = x ε ( r ) x μ ( r ) ε x 1 μ ( r ) .
Similar to [34], we can obtain Lemma 2 by using Lemma 1 and Taylor’s expansion.
Lemma 2.
Suppose that (H1)–(H3) is tenable, there is
E { [ Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 Θ x μ ( x ( T ) ) x 1 μ ( T ) } 0 ,
where x 1 μ ( T ) satisfies (3).
A Hamiltonian function is defined as follows
H ( r , x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς , m , n ) = m f ( r , x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς ) + n g ( r , x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς ) ,
and use the notation H ϕ μ = H ϕ ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , m ( r ) , n ( r ) ) , ϕ = ν , ν δ .
Introduce an adjoint equation
d m ( r ) = [ f x μ ( r ) m ( r ) + g x μ ( r ) n ( r ) + E F r [ f x ς μ ( r + ς ) m ( r + ς ) + g x ς μ ( r + ς ) n ( r + ς ) ] d r n ( r ) d B ( r ) , r [ 0 , T ] , m ( T ) = [ Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) , m ( r ) = 0 , n ( r ) = 0 , r [ T , T + ς ] .
Obviously, (6) admits a unique solution (see [25]).
The following is obtained by making used of Itô’s formula
E m ( T ) , x 1 μ ( T ) = E 0 T { E F t [ f x ς μ ( r + ς ) m ( r + ς ) ] x 1 μ ( r ) E F r [ g x ς μ ( r + ς ) n ( r + ς ) ] x 1 μ ( r ) + m ( r ) f x ς μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) + m ( r ) f ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + m ( r ) f v ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) + n ( r ) g x ς μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) + n ( r ) g ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + n ( r ) g ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) } d r .
Combining special conditions, it yields
E 0 T { m ( r ) f x ς μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) E F r [ ( f x ς μ | r + ς ) m ( r + ς ) ] x 1 μ ( r ) } d r = E 0 T m ( r ) f x ς μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) d r E ς T + ς f x ς μ ( r ) m ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) d r = E 0 ς m ( r ) f x ς μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) d r E T T + ς f x ς μ ( r ) m ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) d r = 0 .
Similarly, we derive
E 0 T { n ( r ) g x ς μ ( r ) x 1 μ ( r ς ) E F r [ ( g x ς μ | r + ς ) n ( r + ς ) ] x 1 μ ( r ) } d r = 0 .
Using (5), it can be deduced
E 0 T { H ν μ , ν 1 ( r ) + H ν ς μ , ν 1 ( r ς ) } d r 0 ,
and thus,
H ν μ + E F r [ H ν ς μ | r + ς ] , ν μ ( r ) 0 , ν U , a . e . , a . s . .
Then, we draw the desired conclusion.
Theorem 1 (MP: I).
Suppose that (H1)–(H3) is tenable. Let ( μ ( · ) , x μ ( · ) ) be an optimal solution of Problem (RSC), then, we assert (7).

3.2. Verification Theorem

Next up, we will construct a verification theorem for optimality.
Introduce an additional hypothesis.
Hypothesis 4 (H4).
0 < ϑ < 1 , H ( r , · , · , · , · , m ( r ) , n ( r ) ) is concave in ( x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς ) and Θ ( · ) is concave in x.
Theorem 2 (Verification Theorem: I).
Suppose μ ( · ) U a d and let x μ ( · ) be the corresponding trajectory. Suppose that ( m ( · ) , n ( · ) ) is a solution to (6). If hypotheses (H1)–(H4) and maximum condition (7) hold for μ ( · ) , then μ ( · ) is an optimal control for Problem (RSC).
Proof. 
For any ν ( · ) U a d , denote by x ν ( · ) its matching state process. Calculate
J ( ν ( · ) ) J ( μ ( · ) ) = 1 ϑ E { [ Θ ( x ν ( T ) ) ] ϑ [ Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ } 1 ϑ E { ϑ [ Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) ( x ν ( T ) x μ ( T ) ) } = E { ( Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ) ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) ( x ν ( T ) x μ ( T ) ) } .
It can be obtained with the help of Itô’s formula as follows
E { ( Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ) ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) ( x ν ( T ) x μ ( T ) ) } = E 0 T { m ( r ) , f ν ( r ) f μ ( r ) + f x μ ( r ) m ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) + g x μ ( r ) n ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) E F r ( f x μ | r + ς ) m ( r + ς ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) E F r ( g x μ | r + ς ) n ( r + ς ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) + n ( r ) , g ν ( r ) g μ ( r ) } d r = E 0 T { H ( r , x ν ( r ) , x ν ( r ς ) , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) , m ( r ) , n ( r ) ) H ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , m ( r ) , n ( r ) ) f x μ ( r ) m ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) g x μ ( r ) n ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) E F r [ ( f x ς μ | r + ς ) m ( r + ς ) ] , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) E F r [ ( g x ς μ | r + ς ) n ( r + ς ) ] , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) } d r
E 0 T { H x ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , m ( r ) , n ( r ) ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) + H x ς ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , m ( r ) , n ( r ) ) , x ν ( r ς ) x μ ( r ς ) + H ν μ , ν ( r ) μ ( r ) + H ν ς μ , ν ( r ς ) μ ( r ς ) f x μ ( r ) m ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) g x μ ( r ) n ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) E F r [ ( f x ς μ | r + ς ) m ( r + ς ) ] , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) E F r [ ( g x ς μ | r + ς ) n ( r + ς ) ] , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) } d r E 0 T { H x ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , m ( r ) , n ( r ) ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) + H x ς ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , m ( r ) , n ( r ) ) , x ν ( r ς ) x μ ( r ς ) f x μ ( r ) m ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) g x μ ( r ) n ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) E F r [ ( f x ς μ | r + ς ) m ( r + ς ) ] , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) E F r [ ( g x ς μ | r + ς ) n ( r + ς ) ] , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) } d r = 0 .
Then we complete the proof. □

4. A General RSCP

A general RS cost functional is considered
J ( ν ( · ) ) = 1 ϑ E [ 0 T l ( r , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) d r + Θ ( x ν ( T ) ) ] ϑ , ϑ > 0 .
Problem 2 (G-RSC).
The objective is to seek a μ ( · ) U a d achieving
J ( μ ( · ) ) = max ν ( · ) U a d J ( ν ( · ) ) ,
associated with (1).
We introduce the following assumptions.
Hypothesis 5 (H5).
l : [ 0 , T ] × U 2 R + is continuously differentiable in ν , ν ς , and the derivatives are bounded.
Hypothesis 6 (H6).
If 0 < ϑ < 1 , we assume
E [ 0 T l ( r , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) d r + Θ ( x ν ( T ) ) ] 2 ϑ 2 < + ;
if ϑ > 1 , then
E [ 0 T l ( r , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) d r ] 2 ϑ 2 < + .

4.1. MP

Let ( μ ( · ) , x μ ( · ) ) be an optimal solution to Problem (G-RSC). In order to obtain the desired results, we define an SDDE
d y ν ( r ) = l ( r , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) d r , r [ 0 , T ] , y ν ( r ) = 0 , ν ( r ) = η ( r ) , r [ ς , 0 ] .
Let y ε ( · ) and y μ ( · ) , respectively, correspond to μ ε ( · ) and μ ( · ) through (10).
A variational equation is
d y 1 μ ( r ) = [ l ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + l ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) ] d r , r [ 0 , T ] , y 1 μ ( r ) = 0 , ν 1 ( r ) = 0 , r [ ς , 0 ] ,
where l ϕ μ ( r ) = l ϕ ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) ) , ϕ = ν , ν ς . We can derive that
lim ε 0 sup 0 r T E | y ˜ ( r ) | 2 = 0 ,
where y ˜ ( r ) = y ε ( r ) y μ ( r ) ε y 1 μ ( r ) .
Thus, Problem (G-RSC) is simplified as maximizing
J ( ν ( · ) ) = 1 ϑ E [ y ν ( T ) + Θ ( x ν ( T ) ) ] ϑ , ϑ > 0
associated with (1) and (10).
We can derive that from J ( μ ε ( · ) ) J ( μ ( · ) ) 0
1 ϑ E [ y ε ( T ) + Θ ( x ε ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 ϑ E [ y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ = 1 ϑ E [ ϑ ( y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ) ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) ( x ε ( T ) x μ ( T ) ) + ϑ ( y μ ( T ) Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ) ϑ 1 ( y ε ( T ) y μ ( T ) ) + o ( ε ) ] = ε E [ ( y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ) ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) ( x 1 μ ( T ) ] + ε E [ ( y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ) ϑ 1 y 1 μ ( T ) ] + o ( ε ) 0 .
Divide both sides of the above inequality by ε , then take the limit ε 0 , such that
E { [ y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) x 1 μ ( T ) } + E { [ y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 y 1 μ ( T ) } 0 .
Introduce the ABSDEs
d α ( r ) = β ( r ) d B ( r ) , r [ 0 , T ] , α ( T ) = [ y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 , α ( r ) = 0 , β ( r ) = 0 , r [ T , T + ς ] ,
and
d ψ ( r ) = [ f x μ ( r ) ψ ( r ) + g x μ ( r ) φ ( r ) + E F r [ ( f x ς μ | r + ς ) ψ ( r + ς ) + ( g x ς μ | r + ς ) φ ( r + ς ) ] d r φ ( r ) d B ( r ) , r [ 0 , T ] , ψ ( T ) = [ y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) , ψ ( r ) = 0 , φ ( r ) = 0 , r [ T , T + ς ] .
Obviously, we can obtain in virtue of Itô’s formula
E { [ y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 y 1 μ ( T ) } = E 0 T { α ( r ) l ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) + α ( r ) l ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) } d r ,
and
E { [ y μ ( T ) + Θ ( x μ ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) x 1 μ ( T ) } = E 0 T { ψ ( r ) f ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + ψ ( r ) f ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) + φ ( r ) g ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + φ ( r ) g ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) } d r .
Combining (12), (15), and (16), we obtain
E 0 T { α ( r ) l ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) + α ( r ) l ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + ψ ( r ) f ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + ψ ( r ) f ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) + φ ( r ) g ν μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ) + φ ( r ) g ν ς μ ( r ) ν 1 ( r ς ) } d r 0 .
A Hamiltonian function is introduced as follows
H ( r , x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς , ψ , φ , α ) = H ( r , x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς , ψ , φ ) + α , l ( r , ν , ν ς ) .
For convenience, here are the following abbreviation
H ( r ) = H ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) , H ( r , ν , μ ( r ς ) ) = H ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , ν , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) , H ( r , μ ( r ) , ν ) = H ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , ν , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) .
It follows from (17), (18), and Theorem 1 that
H ν μ + E F r [ H ν ς μ | r + ς ] , ν μ ( r ) 0 , ν U , a . e . , a . s . .
Through above analysis, the following natural result is obtained.
Theorem 3 (MP: II).
Under hypotheses (H1), (H2), (H5), and (H6), if ( μ ( · ) , x μ ( · ) ) is an optimal solution to Problem (G-RSC), then, (19) holds.

4.2. Verification Theorem

We need the assumption below.
Hypothesis 7 (H7).
l is differentiable in ( ν , ν ς ) , and l ( · , ν ( · ) , ν ( · ς ) ) L F 1 ( 0 , T ; R ) .
Hypothesis 8 (H8).
H v ( t , x ( t ) , x ( t δ ) , v , u ( t δ ) , ψ ( t ) , φ ( t ) , α ( t ) ) and H v δ ( t , x ( t ) , x ( t δ ) , u ( t ) , v , ψ ( t ) , φ ( t ) , α ( t ) ) are continuous at v = u ( t ) for any t [ 0 , T ] , and for all ( t , x , x δ , v , v δ ) [ 0 , T ] × R × R × U × U ,
( x , x δ , v , v δ ) H ( t , x , x δ , v , v δ , ψ ( t ) , φ ( t ) , α ( t ) )
is concave, x Θ ( x ) is concave, and 0 < ϑ < 1 .
Theorem 4 (Verification Theorem: II).
Let u ( · ) U a d be given such that l v u ( · ) , l v δ u ( · ) L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R ) , l v ( t , v , u ( t δ ) ) L 1 ( Ω , F , P ) and l v ( t , u ( t ) , v ) L 1 ( Ω , F , P ) hold. Let ( α ( · ) ,
β ( · ) ) and ( ψ ( · ) , φ ( · ) ) be the solutions of adjoint equations (13) and (14). If (H1), (H2), (H6), (H7), and (H8) hold, and
H ( t ) + E F t [ H ( t ) | t + δ ] = max v U { H ( t , v , u ( t δ ) ) + E F t [ H ( t , u ( t ) , v ) | t + δ ] }
hold for all t [ 0 , T ] . Then, u ( · ) is an optimal control for Problem (G-RSC).
Proof. 
For any v ( · ) U a d , we consider
J ( v ( · ) ) J ( u ( · ) ) = 1 ϑ E { [ y v ( T ) + Θ ( x v ( T ) ) ] ϑ [ y ( T ) + Θ ( x ( T ) ) ] ϑ } 1 ϑ E { ϑ [ y ( T ) + Θ ( x ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 Θ x ( x ( T ) ) ( x v ( T ) x ( T ) ) + ϑ [ y ( T ) + Θ ( x ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 ( y v ( T ) y ( T ) ) } = E { [ y ( T ) + Θ ( x ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 Θ x ( x ( T ) ) ( x v ( T ) x ( T ) ) + [ y ( T ) + Θ ( x ( T ) ) ] ϑ 1 ( y v ( T ) y ( T ) ) } = E { ψ ( T ) ( x v ( T ) x ( T ) ) + α ( T ) ( y v ( T ) y ( T ) ) } .
Using Itô’s formula, it yields
E { ψ ( T ) ( x ν ( T ) x μ ( T ) ) } = E 0 T f x μ ( r ) ψ ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) d r E 0 T g x μ ( r ) φ ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) d r E 0 T E F r [ ( f x ς μ | r + ς ) ψ ( r + ς ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) d r E 0 T E F r [ ( g x ς μ | r + ς ) φ ( r + ς ) ] , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) d r + E 0 T ψ ( r ) , f ( r , x ν ( r ) , x ν ( r ς ) , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) f ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) ) d r + E 0 T φ ( r ) , g ( r , x ν ( r ) , x ν ( r ς ) , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) g ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) ) d r
and
E { α ( T ) ( y ν ( T ) y μ ( T ) ) } = E 0 T α ( r ) , l ( r , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) l ( r , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) ) d r .
Combining (20)–(22), we obtain
J ( ν ( · ) ) J ( μ ( · ) ) E 0 T [ H ( r , x ν ( r ) , x ν ( r ς ) , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) H ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) ] d r E 0 T f x μ ( r ) ψ ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) d r E 0 T g x μ ( r ) φ ( r ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) d r E 0 T E F r [ ( f x ς μ | r + ς ) ψ ( r + ς ) , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) d r E 0 T E F r [ ( g x ς μ | r + ς ) φ ( r + ς ) ] , x ν ( r ) x μ ( r ) d r .
Noticing that ( x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς ) H ( r , x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) is concave, so there is
J ( ν ( · ) ) J ( μ ( · ) ) E 0 T H ν ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) , ν ( r ) μ ( r ) d r + E 0 T H ν ς ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) , ν ( r ς ) μ ( r ς ) d r
= E 0 T H ν ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) , ν ( r ) μ ( r ) d r + E 0 T E F r [ H ν ς ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) | r + ς ] , ν ( r ) μ ( r ) d r = E 0 T H ν ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) + E F r [ H ν ς ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) | r + ς ] , ν ( r ) μ ( r ) d r .
Recalling that, for each r [ 0 , T ] , ν H ( r , ν , μ ( r ς ) ) + E F r [ H ( r , μ ( r ) , ν ) | r + ς ] is maximal at ν = μ ( r ) , and H ν ( r , ν , μ ( r ς ) ) and E F r [ H ( r , ν , μ ( r ς ) ) | r + ς ] are continuous in v for all ω Ω uniformly, then we obtain
{ H ν ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) + E F r [ H ν ς ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) | r + ς ] } × ( ν ( r ) μ ( r ) ) = { ν [ H ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) + E F r [ H ( r , x μ ( r ) , x μ ( r ς ) , μ ( r ) , μ ( r ς ) , ψ ( r ) , φ ( r ) , α ( r ) ) | r + ς ] } × ( ν ( r ) μ ( r ) ) 0 .
Then it hints that
J ( μ ( · ) ) = max ν ( · ) U a d J ( ν ( · ) ) .
So the conclusion is confirmed. □
Obviously, the hypotheses in Theorems 3 and 4 are strict. When ϑ = 1 , Problem (G-RSC) degenerates to a usual risk-neutral optimal control problem, where we denote this problem by Problem (G-RNC). In this case, the hypotheses on Θ and l can be simplified by
Hypothesis 9 (H9).
l : [ 0 , T ] × U 2 R and Θ : R R are, respectively, continuously differentiable in ( ν , ν ς , x ν ) , and the derivatives are bounded.
Define a Hamiltonian function
H ¯ ( r , x ν ( r ) , x ν ( r ς ) , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) , ξ ( r ) , η ( r ) ) = H ( r , x ν ( r ) , x ν ( r ς ) , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) , ξ ( r ) , η ( r ) ) + l ( r , ν ( r ) , ν ( r ς ) ) ,
where ( ξ ( · ) , η ( · ) ) satisfies
d ξ ( r ) = [ f x μ ( r ) ξ ( r ) + g x μ ( r ) η ( r ) + E F r [ ( f x ς μ | r + ς ) ξ ( r + ς ) + ( g x ς μ | r + ς ) η ( r + ς ) ] d r η ( r ) d B ( r ) , r [ 0 , T ] , ξ ( T ) = Θ x ( x μ ( T ) ) , ξ ( r ) = 0 , η ( r ) = 0 , r [ T , T + ς ] .
Assume (H1), (H8) hold and ϑ = 1 . We can obtain Theorem 5 by virtue of techniques in Theorem 1.
Theorem 5 (Risk-Neutral MP).
Presume that μ ( · ) is an optimal control to Problem (G-RNC), and x μ ( · ) be the corresponding trajectory. Then, the maximum principle
H ¯ ν μ + E F r [ H ¯ ν ς μ | r + ς ] , ν μ ( r ) 0 , ν U , a . e . , a . s .
is supported.
Similarly, maximum condition (24) added to some concavity hypothesis is also a sufficient condition.
Introduce an additional hypothesis.
Hypothesis 10 (H10).
H ¯ ( r , · , · , · , · , ξ ( r ) , η ( r ) ) is concave in ( x ν , x ς ν , ν , ν ς ) and Θ ( · ) is concave in x ν .
Theorem 6 (Risk-Neutral Verification Theorem).
Suppose μ ( · ) U a d and let x μ ( · ) be the corresponding trajectory, ( ξ ( · ) , η ( · ) ) satisfy (23). If μ ( · ) satisfies (H1), (H9), (H10), and maximum condition (24), hence μ ( · ) is an optimal solution to Problem (G-RNC).

5. Applications

Let us give an application example in this section.
Example 1.
There are two types of investment products to choose for a pension fund manager, named bond and stock. Additionally, their prices meet, respectively, d M 0 ( s ) = r ( s ) M 0 ( s ) d s and d M 1 ( s ) = M 1 ( s ) [ μ ( s ) d s + σ ( s ) d B ( s ) ] , where r ( · ) is return rate, μ ( · ) is appreciation rate of return and σ ( · ) is volatility coefficient. Further, presume that r ( · ) and σ ( · ) are deterministic bounded functions, and μ ( · ) is an F r -adapted bounded process. In addition, σ ( s ) 1 properly exists and is bounded.
We use θ ( s ) to represent the manager’s investment amount in stocks, x ( s ) to represent his wealth, whose initial value is m > 0 . Further k ( x ( s ) x ( s ς ) ) represents fund members’ surplus premium, which depends on fund growth’s performance over the past period for some k > 0 . Hence, x ( · ) satisfies SDDE
d x ( s ) = [ ( r ( s ) k ) x ( s ) + k x ( s ς ) + ( μ ( s ) r ( s ) ) θ ( s ) ] d r + θ ( s ) σ ( s ) d B ( s ) , s [ 0 , T ] , x ( 0 ) = m , s [ ς , 0 ] .
Represent U a d = { θ ( · ) L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R ) | θ ( s ) c 0 , s [ 0 , T ] } by admissible control set.
Define the associated utility functional
J ( θ ( · ) ) = E [ 0 T L e β s log θ ( s ) d s + K x ( T ) ] ,
where L , K > 0 , and β are discount factors.
Problem 3 (B).
The manager wants to achieve
J ( θ * ( · ) ) = max θ ( · ) U a d J ( θ ( · ) ) .
Now, applying Theorem 5 and Theorem 6, we obtain the Hamiltonian function
H ¯ ( s , x , x ς , ξ , η ) = ξ [ ( r ( s ) k ) x + k x ς + ( μ ( s ) r ( s ) ) θ ( s ) ] + η θ ( s ) σ ( s ) + L e β s log θ ( s ) ,
and adjoint equation
d ξ ( s ) = { [ ( r ( s ) k ) ξ ( s ) + E F s [ k ξ ( s + ς ) ] } d s η ( s ) d B ( s ) , s [ 0 , T ] , ξ ( T ) = K , ξ ( s ) = 0 , s ( T , T + ς ] , η ( s ) = 0 , s [ T , T + ς ] .
We can solve (3) by continuously Itô integrating on steps of length δ, i.e.,
ξ ( s ) = K e 0 T ( r ( s ) k ) d s , η ( s ) = 0 , s [ T ς , T ] ; ξ ( s ) = K e T ς T ( r ( s ) k ) d s e T 2 δ s ( r ( t ) k ) d t + T 2 ς s K k e t + ς T ( r ( u ) k ) d u e t s ( r ( u ) k ) d u d t , η ( s ) = 0 , s [ T 2 ς , T ς ] ;
Then, an optimal investment amount θ * ( s ) of Problem (B) is
θ * ( s ) = ω ( s ) , if ω ( s ) c 0 , c 0 , if ω ( s ) < c 0 ,
where
ω ( s ) = L e β s ξ ( s ) 1 .
We can give the following result by Theorem 6.
Proposition 1.
The optimal investment amount θ * ( s ) of Problem (B) is given by (28), where ω ( s ) is defined by (9) and ξ ( s ) is of the form (26).

6. Conclusions

In this article, an MP of a kind of RSCP with delay and HARA utility is derived by using a dual method and a expanding variable dimension method. Moreover, a sufficient condition is also obtained under some concavity conditions. A pension fund management problem is used as an application illustration. The results develop those of [26,34].
We will consider possible extensions to the problem with partial information, mean-field, etc., in our future works. On the other hand, issues such as financial equations in quantum finance transformed into Hamiltonian form by variables (e.g., [35]) and its application for analyzing the phenomena of spontaneous symmetry breaking in Quantum Finance (e.g., [36]) are also interesting and worthy of study. Research on these problems is currently under way.

Funding

This research was funded by the National Key R&D Program of China under Grant No. 2022YFA1006103, the NSF of China under Grant No. 61925306, 61821004, and 11831010, and the NSF of Shandong Province under Grant No. ZR2020ZD24 and ZR2019ZD42.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank Professor Guangchen Wang for his careful reading and instructive suggestions for improving the quality of this paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Bensoussan, A.; Van Schuppen, J. Optimal control of partially observable stochastic systems with an exponential-of-integral performance index. SIAM J. Control Optim. 1985, 23, 599–613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Hata, H.; Sekine, J. Explicit solution to a certain non-ELQG risk-sensitive stochastic control problem. Appl. Math. Optim 2010, 62, 341–380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Lim, A.; Zhou, X. Risk-sensitive control with HARA utility. IEEE Trans. Automat. Control 2001, 46, 563–578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Fleming, W. Risk-sensitive stochastic control and differential games. Commun. Inf. Syst. 2006, 6, 161–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Tembine, H.; Zhu, Q.; Basar, T. Risk-sensitive mean-field games. IEEE Trans. Automat. Control 2014, 59, 835–850. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Davis, M.; Lleo, S. Jump-diffusion risk-sensitive asset management I: Diffusion factor model. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 2011, 2, 22–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Whittle, P. A risk-sensitive maximum principle. Systems Control Lett. 1990, 15, 183–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Lim, A.; Zhou, X. A new risk-sensitive maximum principle. IEEE Trans. Automat. Control 2005, 50, 958–966. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Shi, J.; Wu, Z. Maximum principle for risk-sensitive stochastic optimal control problem and applications to finance. Stoch. Anal. Appl. 2012, 30, 997–1018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Wang, G.; Wu, Z. General maximum principles for partially observed risksensitive optimal control problems and applications to finance. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 2009, 141, 677–700. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Huang, J.; Li, X.; Wang, G. Maximum principles for a class of partial information risk-sensitive optimal controls. IEEE Trans. Automat. Control 2010, 55, 1438–1443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Shi, J.; Wu, Z. A risk-sensitive stochastic maximum principle for optimal control of jump diffusions and its applications. Acta Math. Sci. Ser. B 2011, 31, 419–433. [Google Scholar]
  13. Ma, H.; Liu, B. Maximum principle for partially observed risk-sensitive optimal control problems of mean-field type. Eur. J. Control 2016, 32, 16–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Moon, J. Risk-sensitive maximum principle for stochastic optimal control of mean-field type Markov regime-switching jump-diffusion systems. Int. J. Robust Nonlinear Control 2021, 31, 2141–2167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Moon, J. Generalized risk-sensitive optimal control and Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation. IEEE Trans. Automat. Control 2021, 66, 2319–2325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Zhu, B.; Han, B.; Lin, X. Existence results for a class of semilinear fractional partial differential equations with delay in Banach spaces. J. Funct. Spaces 2019, 2019, 6295019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Mohammed, S. Stochastic Functional Differential Equations; Pitman Advanced Publishing Program: El-Bireh, Palestine, 1984; Volume 99. [Google Scholar]
  18. Mohammed, S. Stochastic differential equations with memory: Theory, examples and applications. In Stochastic Analysis and Related Topics VI; Progress in Probability; Birkhuser: Boston, MA, USA, 1996; pp. 1–77. [Google Scholar]
  19. Ramsey, R. A mathematical theory of savings. Econ. J. 1928, 38, 543–559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Gandolfo, G. Economic Dynamics; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  21. Arriojas, M.; Hu, Y.; Mohammed, S.; Pap, G. A delayed black and scholes formula. Stoch. Anal. Appl. 2007, 25, 471–492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Ivanov, A.; Swishchuk, A. Optimal control of stochastic dierential delay equations with application in economics. Russ. Math. Surv. 2008, 2, 157–183. [Google Scholar]
  23. Richard, J. Time-delay systems: An overview of some recent advances and open problems. Automatica 2003, 39, 1667–1694. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Wang, P. Maximum principle for optimal control problem with delay. In Proceedings of the 2018 Chinese Automation Congress (CAC), Xi’an, China, 30 November–2 December 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Peng, S.; Yang, Z. Anticipated backward stochastic differential equation. Ann. Probab. 2009, 37, 877–902. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Chen, L.; Wu, Z. Maximum principle for the stochastic optimal control problem with delay and application. Automatica 2010, 46, 1074–1080. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Wu, S. Partially-observed maximum principle for backward stochastic differential delay equations. IEEE-CAA J. Autom. Sin. 2017, 99, 1–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Li, N.; Wang, Y.; Wu, Z. An indefinite stochastic linear quadratic optimal control problem with delay and related forward-backward stochastic differential equations. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 2018, 179, 722–744. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Hao, T.; Meng, Q. A second-order maximum principle for singular optimal controls with recursive utilities of stochastic delay systems. Eur. J. Control 2019, 50, 96–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Ma, H.; Liu, B. Optimal control problem for risk-sensitive mean-field stochastic delay differential equation with partial information. Asian J. Control 2017, 19, 2097–2115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Moon, J.; Duncan, T.E.; Basar, T. Risk-sensitive zero-sum differential games. IEEE Trans. Automat. Control 2019, 64, 1503–1518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Moon, J. Necessary and sufficient conditions of risk-sensitive optimal control and differential games for stochastic differential delayed equations. Int. J. Robust Nonlinear Control 2019, 29, 4812–4827. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Zhang, L. A BSDE approach to stochastic differential games involving impulse controls and HJBI equation. J. Syst. Sci. Complex. 2022, 35, 766–801. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Wang, G.; Wu, Z. Stochastic maximum principle for a kind of risk-sensitive optimal control problem and application to portfolio choice. Acta Automat. Sin. 2007, 33, 1043–1047. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Baaquie, B. Quantum Finance: Path Integrals and Hamiltonians for Options and Interest Rates; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  36. Arraut, I.; Au, A.; Tse, A. Spontaneous symmetry breaking in quantum finance. Europhys. Lett. 2020, 131, 68003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, P. Risk-Sensitive Maximum Principle for Controlled System with Delay. Mathematics 2023, 11, 1058. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11041058

AMA Style

Wang P. Risk-Sensitive Maximum Principle for Controlled System with Delay. Mathematics. 2023; 11(4):1058. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11041058

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Peng. 2023. "Risk-Sensitive Maximum Principle for Controlled System with Delay" Mathematics 11, no. 4: 1058. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11041058

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop