Next Article in Journal
A New Perspective on Moran’s Coefficient: Revisited
Previous Article in Journal
A Blockchain-Enabled Group Covert Channel against Transaction Forgery
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Pricing of Al-Urbun and a Class of Al-Istijrar Islamic Contracts under the Black–Scholes Framework

1
School of Mathematics and Applied Statistics, University of Wollongong, Wollongong, NSW 2522, Australia
2
Department of Mathematics and Statistics, Imam Mohammad Ibn Saud Islamic University (IMSIU), Riyadh 11564, Saudi Arabia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2024, 12(2), 252; https://doi.org/10.3390/math12020252
Submission received: 11 November 2023 / Revised: 27 December 2023 / Accepted: 9 January 2024 / Published: 12 January 2024
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Financial Mathematics III)

Abstract

:
Islamic financial contracts necessarily need to abide by Shariah principles. As such, some contracts have been introduced for risk-hedging real transactions that differ from those seen in conventional financial markets. In this paper, we examine two such products, Al-Urbun and Al-Istijrar, and determine fair prices for both the Al-Urbun and a class of Al-Istijrar under the Black–Scholes framework.

1. Introduction

One of the most popular financial products available to investors is the European option contract, which has seen impressive growth in trade over the last 50 years. A European call option is a contract between two parties: the buyer (or holder) and the seller (or writer) that gives the holder the right, but not the obligation to buy an underlying asset from the writer at a later date at a price agreed upon at the opening of the contract. For that option, the buyer pays the writer an amount, known as the premium, at the opening of the contract.
The problems with the use of options in Islamic Finance, as detailed in [1], include the prohibition of gambling (Maysir), unnecessary risk taking (Gharar) and transactions based on ignorance (Jahl), trading in permitted (Halal) products only, presence of mutual consent for entering into and canceling contracts and the nature of the underlying asset (mal). In particular, the International Fiqh Academy of Organization of Islamic Cooperation [2] released a resolution with regard to the permissibility of option contracts. As currently applied in the global financial markets, option contracts are a new type of contracts that do not fall under any one of the Shariah nominate contracts. Since the object of the contract is neither a sum of money nor a utility or a financial right which may be waived then the contract is not permissible, according to Shariah. Since these contracts are initially not permissible, neither is their trading.
With regular instruments, mainly derivatives, hedging and speculation cannot be separated. However, while the Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions (AAOIFI, 2008) [3,4] (in standard 1, trading in currencies), has indicated that options are forbidden in Shariah, it has instead approved the use of Urbun. Bai’ al-urbun or Urbun, is a partial payment of the price of an asset, which enables the buyer to buy an asset for a specific price at a specific future date, but does not oblige the buyer to do so. If the buyer does choose to buy the asset, then the Urbun becomes part of the purchase price; but if the buyer chooses not to purchase the asset, the seller keeps the Urbun as compensation for their efforts. This is in contrast to a European call option, where the writer keeps the premium regardless of whether the holder exercises or not. For further details, we refer the reader to [5].
Most papers that analyze these products do so from a conceptual point of view (see, e.g., [6,7,8]) and very few papers are found in the literature that focus on the modeling and pricing of Urbun.
In [9], the authors studied the possibility of modeling Bai’ al-urbun using the Binomial Model. This model, widely used for pricing options, is adapted to Shariah rules and conditions for pricing the Urbun deposit. They consider an American-style option and compare their results for the Urbun with those for American call options.
In [10], the authors price Urbun, C ( S , t ) , using the Black–Scholes partial differential Equation (PDE) as for the European call option, but with the final condition C ( S , T ) = | S K | . This corresponds to pricing the sum of a European put option plus a European call option. Also, unfortunately, their solution does not satisfy their specified boundary condition C ( 0 , t ) = 0 .
In [11], the authors’ objective was to model Islamic options based on the Urbun principles and show how it was distinct from traditional options. With Black–Scholes as its benchmark, the authors use an artificial neural network to price the Islamic option. Their result showed that while artificial neural networks were able to price the Islamic options, there was a concerning lack of information provided by the model.
Other Islamic alternative products to conventional derivatives exist that necessarily must avoid conditions of zero-sum and also conditions of uncertainty. One of these that will be considered here is Al-Istijrar. Istijrar was recently introduced by the Muslim Commercial Bank in Pakistan and is being used for commodity financing. Furthermore, Istijrar financing has promising prospects in the Islamic banking industry in Bangladesh (see [12]). Istijrar is concerned with trade but does not include any likelihood of risk-free return by either party. The transaction includes the sale of a real commodity, purchasing and ownership. In this contract, the buyer and seller cannot speculate on the price movements. This constraint on speculation differentiates Istijrar from conventional financial products and makes it comply with the norms of Islamic ethics [13]. This product, which is detailed in Section 3, however, is very complex and involves averages and embedded options. Such a contract may allow either party to reset the ultimate buying price when various trigger points are reached in terms of the high or low values of the asset. Whether such actions are taken may depend on one party’s perception of the other party’s strategy. This then becomes a problem in game theory. In this paper, we consider a particular case of the product in which the values at the boundaries are set.
Not much can be found in the literature on the mathematical pricing of the Al-Istijrar contracts. However, in [13], Obaidullah noted that the contract with the buyer has the nature of an up-and-in call barrier option and the contract with the seller has the nature of a down-and-in put option contract. (He also noted that the options had the nature of average rate (Asian) options). As the value of these options to both parties must be equal, he arrives at the condition for equality using the standard valuation approach suggested by [14], which assumes that the underlying price follows a multiplicative binomial process.
The Black–Scholes framework has also been used to price products that lead to nonlinear cases, e.g., when incorporating the effects of market illiquidity (see, e.g., [15,16,17]).
In Section 2 and Section 3 of this paper, we focus on the Al-Urbun and Al-Istijrar contracts, respectively. We provide more detail on the contracts and examine their pricing from a mathematical perspective under the Black–Scholes framework. We conclude in Section 4.

2. Al-Urbun

As stated in the Introduction, Bai’ al-urbun is a partial payment of an asset’s price that allows the buyer to buy the asset at a particular price at a particular date in the future. If the buyer chooses to buy the asset, the Urbun is included in the purchase price; if the buyer does not buy the asset, the seller keeps the money as compensation.
The following example illustrates the Urbun contract:
A buyer pays a deposit of 500 SR with a purchase (exercise) price of 5000 SR for 100 stocks. (i.e., 50 SR per stock with a deposit of 5 SR). The time to expiration of the contract is 3 months. At the exercise date, in 3 months, if the market price of the stock is more than 50 SR per stock, the buyer will pay 4500 SR for the remainder of the purchase price. He could then sell the stocks at the market price. The profit for the buyer is the market price less the exercise price. The seller must sell the stock at the predetermined exercise price. If the market price is above 45 SR and below 50 SR, say 47 SR, the holder will still buy the stock from the seller for 50 SR because the loss from the stock ( 47 50 ) SR plus retrieval of the Urbun, 5 SR, (the payoff) is still positive and is better than a payoff of 0. Note however, that the final profit is still negative ( 47 50 + 5 5 = 3 ) SR as the Urbun 5 SR was initially paid. Again, it is still better than losing the entire Urbun. If the price in the market is lower than 45 SR, the buyer will forfeit the purchase and the seller will keep the Urbun.
Table 1 and Table 2 detail the payoffs and profits from European call options and the Urbun for different final stock prices.
Notice that with the Urbun contract when K a < S < K , the holder still exercises and makes a loss of S K but that is less than the loss he would have if he did not exercise, i.e., a as a < S K .

Pricing of Al-Urbun

We consider the option to buy stock with price S at time t = T for the exercise price of K. We assume that the underlying asset price is governed by
d S = μ S d t + σ S d Z ,
where μ and σ are, respectively, the constant expected return and volatility of the stock and d Z is an increment in a Wiener process Z.
We wish to determine a fair price for the Urbun, or deposit, a.
Result 1.
The fair price of the Urbun contract V ( S , t ) for the option to purchase a stock S at price K at time t = T for an initial deposit a, is
V ( S , t ) = C B S ( S , t ; K a , T ) ,
where
a = C B S ( S , 0 ; K a , T ) ,
and where C B S ( S , t ; X , T ) = S N ( d 1 ) X e r ( T t ) N ( d 2 ) , d 1 , 2 = ( ln ( S X ) + ( r ± σ 2 2 ) ( T t ) ) σ T t is the Black–Scholes value of a European call option with exercise price X and expiry T. r is the constant risk-free interest rate, and N ( . ) denotes the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution (see [18]).
Proof. 
The proof follows simply from that of the European call option. □
Setting up a portfolio of one short Urbun contract and V S long shares, i.e.,
Π = V ( S , t ) + V S S
and considering the change in the portfolio in a time d t (see [19]) demonstrates that the portfolio must be risk-free during the time d t . This then leads to the pricing PDE (as for the European call option)
V t + σ 2 S 2 2 V S S + r S V S r V = 0 ,
which for the Urbun contract we solve subject to
V ( S , T ) = max ( S ( K a ) , 0 ) ,
V ( 0 , t ) = 0 ,
lim S V ( S , t ) S .
Further, as we have an extra unknown, namely a, we have an extra condition
V ( S , 0 ) = a .
The unique solution to (4a)–(4d) is (2). Substituting (4e) into (2) we obtain (3).
Equation (3) gives an implicit solution for the Urbun deposit a.
With the Urbun contract, when one exercises at t = T , they essentially pay K a , the remainder of the exercise price, as a was paid as a deposit at the opening of the contract. The RHS of (3) represents the Black–Scholes value of a European call option with exercise price K a . This gives the fair price of the option which is the amount paid (the premium or in this case the deposit) at the opening of the contract, i.e., ‘a’ (the LHS).
Result 2.
The Urbun is an increasing function of S and when S = K then a = K .
Proof. 
Consider a = a ( S ) . From (2) we have
a = S N ( d 1 ) ( K a ) e r T N ( d 2 ) .
We show that a ( S ) > 0 .
Differentiating (5) with respect to S we have
a ( S ) = N ( d 1 ) + S N ( d 1 ) d 1 S + a ( S ) e r T N ( d 2 ) ( K a ) e r T N ( d 2 ) d 2 S .
Using d 1 S = d 2 S = 1 S σ T + a ( S ) ( K a ) σ T and then making a ( S ) the subject, we obtain
a ( S ) = N ( d 1 ) 1 e r T N ( d 2 ) > 0 .
Here we have used the relationship S N ( d 1 ) ( K a ) e r T N ( d 2 ) = 0 which is easily proven.
Further we have that when S = K in (2), then a = K satisfies (2) as N ( d 1 ) = 1 and K a = 0 .
Note: From Result 1, this means that when S = K , the fair value of the Urbun is the entire exercise price, and when S > K , there is no fair value of the Urbun, i.e., no solution to (2). In the current setting, the stock price is expected to grow at a positive growth rate so if initially S > K then it would be expected that the option will be exercised and there would be no benefit to the seller. Hence if S > K , and the holder can secure an Urbun, then he is in the enviable position of having an advantage because the Urbun is actually worth more than K.
Result 3.
American-style Urbun contracts can imply arbitrage opportunities. For example, if S > K at the opening of the Urbun option contract, the Urbun could be exercised straightaway—the holder pays a, then exercises and receives S K + a , thus making S K > 0 immediately.
Figure 1 and Table 3 illustrate a comparison of Urbun prices with the European call option prices with the parameters K = 100 , σ = 0.25 , r = 0.05 , T = 1 . As expected, the Urbun prices are always greater than the corresponding European call option prices and the differences increase with S.

3. Al-Istijrar

Al-istijrar, or Istijrar, also involves trade between two parties, a buyer who might be a company looking to finance the purchase of an underlying asset, and a bank or other financial institution. The sale price of the traded commodity is calculated as the average of the market price over the financing period. The contract has embedded options for both parties that are triggered if the market price reaches an upper or lower bound during the financing period. The option gives the right to a party to set the sale price at some predetermined level. At the opening of the contract, there is one master agreement where all terms and conditions are finalized.
As stated in [13], ‘Istijrar does not allow any room for controversy, or difference of opinion as the options are embedded in the contract and are not tradable in themselves. The contract does not allow for any kind of speculative gain as it is backed by real purchase, ownership and sale of a commodity’.
A typical contract might be as follows: A company that seeks finance for a short term to buy a commodity approaches a bank. The bank buys the commodity at the current price, say S 0 , and sells it to the company, to pay for it at a mutually agreed upon date, say 9 months. The sale price is unlike a usual trade and is determined at the end of the financing period, i.e., in 9 months, as the average of a series of asset prices during the 9 months. Both the company and the bank agree on a publically available, irrefutable source of price information and also on the sampling interval for observing asset prices on which the average price is calculated. The Istijrar contract has embedded options for both parties to fix the sale price at different predetermined levels. These options are activated if the asset price increases or decreases too much and crosses either a pre-specified upper or lower bound. The buyer company can choose to fix the sale price, payable on the due date, if S reaches S u , an upper bound during the 9-month financing period. The bank, on the other hand, can choose to fix the sale price, payable on the due date, if S reaches S l , a lower bound.
Note that if the buyer company expects the price will continue to rise after S u , (so the average of the price during the entire period would be driven up) then they would exercise their option at S u . However, if they expect that the increasing price trend price would stop and that asset prices will fall, then they would be better off not exercising.
If the price falls below S l and the bank expects the price decline to continue (so the average of the prices during the entire period would be driven down) then they would exercise the option to fix the payment. However, if the bank expects the price decline to stop and thinks the prices will increase, then it might be better not to exercise the option.
This hedging instrument allows for the sharing of risk in which the settlement price benefits both parties. It is not a zero-sum game, as both parties benefit from the contract.

Pricing of a Particular Case of an Al-Istijrar Contract

The Al-Istijrar contract has features in common with Asian and barrier options, so the pricing of these contracts will in some ways be similar to them.
Averaging of the underlying asset in the contracts can be either arithmetic or geometric. In this paper, we use arithmetic averaging, which is the sum of all the constituent asset prices, equally weighted, and then divided by the total number of prices used. If we consider closely spaced prices over a finite time then the sums, we calculate when averages become integrals of the functions of the asset over the averaging period, leading to a continuously sampled average. In other words, if the sampling takes place so frequently then it may be best to view them as being continuously sampled rather than a string of discrete samples.
The continuously sampled arithmetic average is defined as
1 t 0 t S ( t ) d t ,
which is
lim n 1 n i = 1 n S ( t i ) .
Pricing of the Istijrar is complex and challenging. Here we make reasonable assumptions about the boundary conditions to make the mathematical model tractable and manageable. This helps us to gain insight and understanding of the underlying principles and processes that govern the contract.
The class of A-Istijrar we consider here is designed in such a way that the ‘options’ at the boundaries would always be exercised as it is for the relevant participant’s benefit. Hence we assume that if the stock price reaches S u that the buyer client would exercise and set the value on an agreed upon pre-determined value. Further, we assume that if it decreases and reaches S l then the bank will exercise and the value there be set at a pre-determined value.
To value a contract contingent on an arithmetic average we define (see [19])
I = 0 t S ( t ) d t
as a new independent variable, called a state variable. As the history of the asset price is independent of the current price, we can treat S , I , t as independent variables—different realizations of the random walk lead to different values of I. Hence the value of the contract is not just a function of S and t but also of I.
We again assume that the real process followed by the asset is given by (1). The pricing equation for the value of the Istijrar contract, V ( S , I , t ) , is then necessarily the same as for Asian options contingent on arithmetic averaging (see [14]), namely,
V t + S V I + σ 2 S 2 2 V S S + r S V S r V = 0 .
The final condition for the Istijrar contract is V ( S , I , T ) = I / T .
We take the boundary conditions to be
V ( S u , I , t ) = e r ( T t ) T I + S u * ( T t ) + k 1 ,
V ( S l , I , t ) = e r ( T t ) T I + S l * ( T t ) + k 2 ,
lim I V ( S , I , t ) ,
where k 1 , k 2 are set constants and S u * and S l * are constant estimates of the average value of S over [ t , T ] given S = S u or S = S l . So at the upper(lower) boundary S = S u ( S = S l ) the buyer (bank) sets the value as the discounted estimated average at time T of the asset prices, plus a set constant. Here we are using the Mean Value Theorem for integrals to estimate t T S ( t ) d t (see, e.g., [20]). Note that at t = T the value is I / T + k 1 at the upper boundary, so we expect the client would choose k 1 < 0 . Similarly, at t = T the value is I / T + k 2 at the lower boundary, so we expect the bank would choose k 2 > 0 .
We let V = exp ( r ( T t ) ) W ( S , I , t ) so that the new problem is
W t + S W I + σ 2 S 2 2 W S S + r S W S = 0 ,
subject to W ( S , I , T ) = I / T , and
W ( S u , I , t ) = 1 T I + S u * ( T t ) + k 1 e r ( T t ) ,
W ( S l , I , t ) = 1 T I + S l * ( T t ) + k 2 e r ( T t ) ,
lim I W ( S , I , t ) .
Equation (15) has a classical symmetry S * = S , t * = t , W * = W + ϵ , I * = I + T ϵ (see [21]). This leads to the functional form of the similarity reduction given by W ( S , I , t ) = I T + f ( S , t ) (with this form for W, the PDE and given conditions reduce to a problem for f ( S , t ) with only two independent variables). Substituting this into the above problem we obtain
f t + σ 2 S 2 2 f S S + r S f S = S / T ,
subject to f ( S , T ) = 0 and
f ( S u , t ) = S u * ( T t ) T + k 1 e r ( T t ) ,
f ( S l , t ) = S l * ( T t ) T + k 2 e r ( T t ) .
Next, we let τ = T t and S = e x so our problem reduces to
f τ σ 2 2 f x x + f x r + σ 2 2 = e x T ,
subject to
f ( x , 0 ) = 0 ,
f ( ln S u , τ ) = S u * τ T + k 1 e r τ ,
f ( ln S l , τ ) = S l * τ T + k 2 e r τ .
Now with f = e α x + β τ u ( x , τ ) where α = σ 2 2 r σ 2 , β = α 2 σ 2 2 , our problem simplifies to
u τ σ 2 2 u x x = 1 T e x e α x β τ ,
subject to
u ( x , 0 ) = 0 ,
u ( ln S u , τ ) = S u α e β τ k 1 e r τ + S u * τ T ,
u ( ln S l , τ ) = S l α e β τ k 2 e r τ + S l * τ T .
Finally, to shift our domain to start at 0, we let z = x ln S l so our problem is
u τ = σ 2 2 u z z + 1 T S l 1 α e z ( 1 α ) e β τ ,
subject to
u ( z , 0 ) = 0 ,
u ( 0 , τ ) = S l α e β τ k 2 e r τ + S l * τ T ,
u ( L , τ ) = S u α e β τ k 1 e r τ + S u * τ T ,
where L = ln S u ln S l .
The solution to the problem [22] is
u ( z , τ ) = 0 τ 0 L 1 T S l 1 α e ξ ( 1 α ) e β t G ( z , ξ , τ t ) d ξ d t
+ σ 2 2 0 τ e β t S l α k 2 e r t + S l * t T H 1 ( z , τ t ) d t
σ 2 2 0 τ e β t S u α k 1 e r t + S u * t T H 2 ( z , τ t ) d t ,
where
G ( z , ξ , τ ) = 2 L n = 1 sin n π z L sin n π ξ L exp σ 2 2 n 2 π 2 τ L 2
= 1 2 π σ 2 τ n = exp ( z ξ + 2 n L ) 2 2 σ 2 τ exp ( z + ξ + 2 n L ) 2 2 σ 2 τ .
The first form of the series above for G converges rapidly for large τ while the second form converges rapidly for small τ .
Then,
H 1 ( z , τ ) = ξ G ( z , ξ , τ ) | ξ = 0 ,
H 2 ( z , τ ) = ξ G ( z , ξ , τ ) | ξ = L .
Undoing the change of variables we obtain
V ( S , I , t ) = e r ( T t ) I T + S α e β ( T t ) u ( ln S l n S l , T t ) .
Figure 2 details the Istijrar prices with parameters S u = 50 , S l = 5 , r = 0.05 , σ = 0.2 , T = 0.25 , S l * = 4 3 S l , S u * = 3 4 S u , k 1 = 2 , k 2 = 2 . Notice how the values generally increase with S and at a particular S value the Istijrar values are close to S. However close to the lower boundary the Istijrar values are greater than S while close to the upper boundary, they are a fair bit smaller than S. We used n = 5 in (37) as adding more terms made no difference to the solution to 4 decimal places.

4. Conclusions

The Islamic finance industry is a rapidly growing part of the world’s financial sector. However, even with the introduction of financial instruments such as the Urbun and Istijrar, there do not appear to be many published studies that focus on the mathematical modeling and pricing of these instruments. This paper addresses this issue. In the Black–Scholes framework, we have determined an implicit solution for the fair price of the Urbun and shown that under this framework, if the current stock price is greater than the exercise price, then no fair value can be found for its price. Otherwise, the price can be found using an application of the Black–Scholes value for the European call option. We have also considered a form of Istijrar whereby at specified upper (lower) bounds reached by the stock price during the life of the contract, the value is set at pre-determined values that would benefit the buyer (seller). By assuming reasonable forms for the boundary conditions, we were able to formulate an explicit solution from which we can gain insight and understanding of the underlying principles of the Istijrar contract. Given that currently, there are no other explicit solutions for the Istijrar, we believe that our solution can offer important perspicacity to the contract.

Author Contributions

Writing—review and editing, J.G. and M.A. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported and funded by the Deanship of Scientific Research at Imam Mohammad Ibn Saud Islamic University (IMSIU) (grant number IMSIU-RG23118).

Data Availability Statement

All relevant data are within the manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Oubdi, L.; Raghibi, A. Istijrar: An Overview on the Practice and Issues of Hedging in Islamic Finance. Available online: https://mpra.ub.uni-muemchen.de/82646 (accessed on 10 September 2023).
  2. International Fiqh Academy of Orgainzation of Islamic Corporation. Available online: https://iifa-aifi.org/en (accessed on 15 September 2023).
  3. Abumustafa, A.; Al-Abduljader, S. Investigating the implications of derivative securities in emerging stock markets: The Islamic perspective. J. Deriv. Hedge Funds 2011, 17, 115–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Accounting and Auditing Organizations for Islamic Financial Institutions. Shariah Standards. Available online: http://www.iefpedia.com/english (accessed on 22 September 2023).
  5. Bacha, O. Financial Derivatives: Markets And Applications; World Scientific Publishing Company: Singapore, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  6. Dhiraj, N.; Ahmat, M.; Nazarov, I.; Arif, M. Islamic structured products:innovation or replication? A New discussion on contemporary application and Shariah issues. J. Econ. Bus. 2019, 2, 418–430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Grira, J.; Labidi, C. Labidi, Banks, funds and risks in Islamic Finance: Literature and Future research avenues. Financ. Res. Lett. 2021, 41, 101815. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Ghlamallah, E.; Alexakis, C.; Dowling, M.; Piepenbrink, A. The topics of Islamic economics and finance research. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2021, 75, 145–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Omrana, S.; Aboulaich, R.; Idrissi, A. Modelling “Bai Al Arboun” using binomial model. Int. J. Bus. 2015, 20, 224–236. [Google Scholar]
  10. El Hajaji, A.; El Khamlichi, A.; Serghini, A.; Hilal, K.; Mokhlis, K. A New Model for pricing the options in Islamic Finance. Appl. Math. E-Notes 2023, 23, 71–82. [Google Scholar]
  11. Adzhar, Z.; Tafri, F. Islamic options pricing model via artificial neural network: “Benchmarking to Black-Scholes”. In Proceedings of the International Conference on Statistics in Science, Business and Engineering (ICSSBE), Langkawi, Malaysia, 10–12 September 2012; Volume 20, pp. 224–236. [Google Scholar]
  12. Rahman, M.; Chowdhury, N. The prospects of istijrar financing in Islamic banking: An exploratory study in Bangladesh. Qual. Res. Financ. Marks. 2023. ahead of print. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Obaidullah, M. Istijrar: A Product of Financial Engineering. Available online: https://isva.io/ (accessed on 2 October 2023).
  14. Cox, J.; Ross, S.; Rubinstein, M. Option pricing: A simplified approach. J. Financ. Econ. 1979, 7, 229–263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Company, R.; Jódar, L.; Pintos, J.R. Numerical analysis andcomputing for option pricing models in illiquid markets. Math. Comput. Model. 2010, 52, 1066–1073. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Romero, J.M.; González-Gaxiola, O.; Ruiz de Chavez, J.; Bernal-Jaquez, R. The Black-Scholes equation and certain quantum Hamiltonians. Int. J. Pure Appl. Math. 2011, 67, 165–173. [Google Scholar]
  17. Company, R.; Jódar, L.; Ponsoda, E.; Ballester, C. Numericalanalysis and simulation of option pricing problems modeling illiquidmarkets. Comput. Math. Appl. 2010, 59, 2964–2975. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Black, F.; Scholes, M. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J. Pol. Econ. 1973, 81, 637–659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Wilmott, P. Derivatives: The Theory and Practice of Financial Engineering; John Wiley & Sons: Chichester, UK, 1998. [Google Scholar]
  20. Anton, H. Calculus with Analytic Geometry; John Wiley & Sons: New York, NY, USA, 1988. [Google Scholar]
  21. Bluman, G.; Kumei, S. Symmetries and Differential Equations; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 1989. [Google Scholar]
  22. Polyanin, A. Handbook of Linear Partial Differential Equations for Engineers and Scientists; Chapman & Hall/CRC: Boca Raton, FL, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Comparison between Urbun and European call option with K = 100 , σ = 0.25 , r = 0.05 , T = 1 .
Figure 1. Comparison between Urbun and European call option with K = 100 , σ = 0.25 , r = 0.05 , T = 1 .
Mathematics 12 00252 g001
Figure 2. Istijrar prices with S u = 50 , S l = 5 , r = 0.05 , σ = 0.2 , T = 0.25 , S l * = 4 3 S l , S u * = 3 4 S u , k 1 = 2 , k 2 = 2 .
Figure 2. Istijrar prices with S u = 50 , S l = 5 , r = 0.05 , σ = 0.2 , T = 0.25 , S l * = 4 3 S l , S u * = 3 4 S u , k 1 = 2 , k 2 = 2 .
Mathematics 12 00252 g002
Table 1. Payoffs and Profits at Expiry from a European Call Option with premium C.
Table 1. Payoffs and Profits at Expiry from a European Call Option with premium C.
PayoffProfit
HolderWriterHolderWriter
S > KSKKSSKCKS + C
S < K00CC
Table 2. Payoffs and Profits at Expiry from an Urbun Option with deposit a.
Table 2. Payoffs and Profits at Expiry from an Urbun Option with deposit a.
PayoffProfit
HolderWriterHolderWriter
S > KSK + a (> 0)KaS (< 0)SK (> 0)KS (< 0)
Ka < S < KSK + a (> 0)KaS (< 0)SK (< 0)KS (> 0)
S < Ka00aa
Table 3. Comparison of Urbun and European call option prices with K = 100 , σ = 0.25 , r = 0.05 , T = 1 .
Table 3. Comparison of Urbun and European call option prices with K = 100 , σ = 0.25 , r = 0.05 , T = 1 .
SUrbunEuropean Call Option
500.02740.0274
600.24600.2402
701.18101.0775
804.02693.1415
9012.31416.8698
9524.69929.3950
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Goard, J.; AbaOud, M. Pricing of Al-Urbun and a Class of Al-Istijrar Islamic Contracts under the Black–Scholes Framework. Mathematics 2024, 12, 252. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12020252

AMA Style

Goard J, AbaOud M. Pricing of Al-Urbun and a Class of Al-Istijrar Islamic Contracts under the Black–Scholes Framework. Mathematics. 2024; 12(2):252. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12020252

Chicago/Turabian Style

Goard, Joanna, and Mohammed AbaOud. 2024. "Pricing of Al-Urbun and a Class of Al-Istijrar Islamic Contracts under the Black–Scholes Framework" Mathematics 12, no. 2: 252. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12020252

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop