Next Article in Journal
Detection of SARS-CoV-2 in Wastewater Northeast of Mexico City: Strategy for Monitoring and Prevalence of COVID-19
Previous Article in Journal
Knowledge, Attitude, Practices and Viewpoints of Undergraduate University Students towards Self-Medication: An Institution-Based Study in Riyadh
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Impact of Income Inequality on Urban Air Quality: A Game Theoretical and Empirical Study in China

1
Department of Applied Economics, School of Economics and Business Administration, Chongqing University, Chongqing 400044, China
2
International Business and Logistics Faculty, California State University Maritime Academy, Vallejo, CA 945900, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18(16), 8546; https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18168546
Submission received: 30 April 2021 / Revised: 3 July 2021 / Accepted: 9 August 2021 / Published: 13 August 2021
(This article belongs to the Section Air)

Abstract

:
Income inequality and environmental pollution are of great concern in China. It is important to better understand whether the narrowing of income inequality and environmental improvement contradict each other. The study aims to investigate the linkage between income inequality and environmental pollution. To illustrate the interplay between different income groups on environmental issues, we apply a mixed-strategy game. Based on the game-theoretic analytical result, the probability of residents supporting clean energy and environmental protection decreases as income inequality widens and increases as inequality narrows. This empirical study is based on the proportion of coal consumption and urban air pollution data from 113 key environmental protection cities and regions in China. The air quality data are from the National Environmental Air Quality Monitoring Network published in the China Statistical Yearbook from 2014–2018. Convincing results show that regions with higher income inequality suffer severe smog and related pollution and that economies with narrow income disparity experience significant improvements in smog and pollution control, with the expansion of the proportion of clean energy use. The results also provide no evidence of the impact of per capita income on pollution. We studied the relationship between individuals of different wealth levels within an economy, within a repeated-game setting. The finding suggests that the distribution of growth impacts pollution. Imposing higher taxes on air polluters while transferring the revenue to the lower-income group is suggested.

1. Introduction

In addition to the debate over the balance between economic growth and environmental protection, scholars have begun to discuss the role of economic inequality, which measures how unevenly income is distributed throughout a society. Few countries other than China illustrate the need for more research on the relationship between inequality and the environment. China has experienced rapid economic growth over the last two decades [1] that has caused crisis levels of inequality and pollution. For example, China’s Gini coefficient (a measure of the gap between the rich and poor) was recently estimated as 0.47 (http://www.stats.gov.cn/ztjc/zdtjgz/yblh/zysj/201710/t20171010_1540710.html, 10 October 2017), one of the highest levels of inequality in Asia, where the average level of the Gini coefficient was estimated as 0.36 (https://data.adb.org/dataset/gini-coefficient-asia-and-pacific, 8 November 2016). [2]. This number is approaching a “danger line” of 0.5 [3] associated with widespread social instability and stagnation of development [3,4,5]. In addition, air pollution is at levels that harm human health in most of China’s cities. Of the 338 cities monitored by China’s Ministry of Environmental Protection in 2015, 73 cities fulfilled national standards for air quality [6], which refers to the air pollution level in these cities. In this study, we mainly focus on the linkage between income inequality and urban air quality in China. In other words, we want to clarify how the increasing income disparity potentially influences air pollution. Under the realization of that common prosperity and environmental governance are important issues in the long-term plan of the Chinese government, it is crucial for policy-makers to clarify the relationship between income inequality and environmental pollution, which is still academically controversial.
The results of the theoretical analyses, specifically within the game-theoretic model, suggest that inequality is associated with greater environmental pollution, which is empirically confirmed through the use of data from 113 Chinese cities for most forms of air pollution used within this study. These data depict the current status of China as having a large degree of inequality among individuals and cities. Multiple types of air pollution are employed as measures of environmental damage. Air pollution, most likely influenced by income inequality [7], has become a major factor threatening the health of residents. According to the World Health Organization [8], 1,150,296 Chinese citizens have died because of air pollution, and ceasing this trend is one of the most urgent environmental issues for policymakers and citizens.
The empirical results show that income inequality aggravates air pollution, measured by annual average fine particulate matter (PM2.5) concentration, and further prove that in addition to PM2.5, income inequality is positively correlated with other air pollution indicators. The results also show no evidence of the impact of per capita income on pollution. For endogeneity concerns, we use the urbanization rate as the instrument variable (IV). Based on the two-stage least squared (TSLS) regression analysis, we confirm the robustness of the empirical result. This finding suggests that the distribution of the growth, as opposed to economic growth, impacts pollution. From the perspective of policy-making, imposing higher taxes on air polluters while transferring the revenue to the lower-income group is suggested.

2. Literature Review and Development of Hypotheses

2.1. Trade-Off between Economic Growth and the Environment

Studies have argued that at the initial stage of economic development, large amounts of natural resources are consumed, leading to the discharge of waste and build-up of pollutants, this ultimately compromises social well-being [9]. However, in the long run, economic growth leads to improved environmental protection. Such viewpoints have been well summarized and empirically supported by prior research e.g., [10,11]. One of the most influential theories is the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) [12] derived from the well-known Kuznets Curve [13,14]. According to the curve, environmental damage is positively correlated with economic development in pre-industrial economies, but in post-industrial economies, environmental damage declines with economic development. However, subsequent studies have challenged the aforementioned findings or deeply examined the impact of income and on the environment [15,16,17]. Subsequently, economic experiments and other new methods have been used to validate this issue e.g., [18]. Thus, because some environmental factors vary with a change in residents’ income, considering potential associations between income inequality and environmental protection is valuable and reasonable.

2.2. Empirical Evidence on the Linkage between Inequality and Emissions

Much of the empirical literature on inequality and emissions has obtained contradictory or inconclusive results. Research on income inequality and the environment has focused on carbon emissions. The positive association between inequality and carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions has been examined at the country level [19,20] and state level (provincial level) [4,21,22]. However, contradictory results indicate low [23,24] or negative [25] correlation between inequality and CO2 emissions.
Scholars have begun investigating air pollution and proposed smog prevention and control recommendations [26,27]. Research on non-CO2 emissions and inequality has shown similarly mixed results and has examined forms of air pollution such as sulfur dioxide (SO2) or air particulates [28,29,30,31,32]. A majority of the literature argues that income inequality positively impacts emissions [33,34]. At the national level, some scholars believe the turning point of EKC will be realized at a lower economic level with a narrower income gap [34]. However, the effect of such a relation in different countries may vary according to the level of development [33]. Controversial points on this issue mainly distinguish on whether the types of pollutants and sample differences are the key determinants in influencing the relationship between inequality and pollution [35,36].
Additionally, two studies have examined the relationship between inequality and overall indices of environmental pollution that include air pollution as part of their weighted index [37,38]. Interestingly, some research argues that air pollution can also influence income inequality. For example, pollution may have different impacts on individual activities depending on the time dimension and eventually exacerbate the income inequality [39]. Besides, income inequality may also affect the impact of environmental pollution on different groups and make some more vulnerable [40]. These findings pose a potential endogenous problem when modelling income inequality and air pollution.
Because the relationship between inequality and environmental pollution remains unaccounted for, additional discussions are necessary. This study extends CO2-oriented research [4,21,24] by examining the relationship between economic inequality and multiple measures of daily air quality beyond CO2. We also extend the research on provincial-level data [37,38] by using city-level data and examining the impact of inequality on multiple and specific measures of air quality.

2.3. Game Theoretical Approach and Other Formal Models

Informed by the research on the relationship between economic activities and climate or environment change [41,42,43], and based on non-cooperative games [44], we created a normative non-cooperative game and its Nash equilibrium. The non-cooperative game between “rich” and “poor” economies demonstrates a typical prisoner’s dilemma. If the strategic space is defined as a limited continuously derivable set, a social dilemma of sub-optimal Nash equilibrium is observed [45].
For dynamic games with perfect information, backward induction can be used to obtain the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, which entails that different players tend to reach consensus over time under dynamic conditions [42,46,47]. The endlessly repeated prisoner’s dilemma can provide a more realistic depiction, and the literature has concluded that there are many subgame perfect Nash equilibriums under trigger conditions [48,49]. Studies have found that different governance measures, including subsidies, taxes, and other incentives, could be used to change the game equilibrium and ultimately enhance the efficiency of the sub-optimal equilibrium [50]. Further research investigated the game of environmental protection between China and Japan by examining acid rain and suggested that Japan should subsidize China in the area of acid rain control [51]. This illustrates the difficulty of achieving cooperation without a central government to resolve conflicts through the use of subsidies or regulations.
The academic community has also endeavored to examine cooperative games of emission reduction. Optimal emission reduction was considered possible under extensive cooperation conditions [52]. Cooperation had positive externalities, and even small-scale cooperation could lead to emission reduction [53]. Some scholars have used implementation theory to study the game of pollution control [54] and found that limited cooperation in dynamic games could result in more efficient pollution control than simply being a endeavored free rider.
In addition to the game-theoretic approach, other formal models are applied. Other factors, for example, type of democracy [55] and social power [28,56], have often been included in the analytical frame of income inequality and environment. In some cases, the importance of concavity in the relationship between income and environmental damage is emphasized [30]. However, the existence of concavity or convexity remains controversial [31,57].
Most of these models have made strong assumptions regarding how much power the wealthy have, strong preferences for pollution by the wealthy, what type of government is best, or household consumption patterns. The model presented in this study is designed to have minimal assumptions (other than standard assumptions about preferences for income and environmental protection). We draw similar conclusions on the impact of inequality on pollution but use fewer assumptions. We also use a game-theoretic approach to explore a greater number of outcomes that depend on the distribution of wealth.
As mentioned previously, the role of inequality between nations has been modelled in a game-theoretic approach [51,58,59] and has highlighted the difficulties of obtaining cooperation between developed and developing countries on mutually beneficial environmental policies. Although these studies illustrate the challenges of developing countries (e.g., China) cooperating with developed countries on issues such as climate change, they do not provide guidance on obtaining cooperation between individuals of different wealth levels within a country. This study extends the analysis of these studies by using a repeated-game approach to model the impact of inequality on environmental protection within a single country rather than among countries.
In summary, if EKC holds in China, then environmental pollution may further deteriorate with the expansion of the income gap before the turning point of the curve. Conversely, after reaching the turning point, the narrowing income disparity would result in environmental improvement. Therefore, based on the urban air pollution condition, we establish the following two hypotheses, which will be theoretically analyzed using a mixed-strategy game and empirically tested in the due course.
Hypothesis 1 (H1).
There is an inverted U-shaped relationship between economic growth and air pollution in urban China according to the EKC hypothesis.
Hypothesis 2 (H2).
Expansion of income inequality aggravates air pollution in urban China.

3. Materials and Methods

3.1. Game-Theoretic Model

This section selects an ongoing environmental protection project aiming to address environmental pollution and improve environmental quality, studies two groups, namely, the high-income group and low-income group, and analyses how well the groups accept the project through the use of mixed-strategy games. As two independent decision-makers, the two groups independently decide whether they accept the project and if they choose to make optimal self-benefiting decisions according to the utility maximization principle. As the macro-regulatory body, the government encourages and promotes residents to accept the project and facilitates project realization by providing subsidies and levying the tax. This proposed model analyses the two groups’ optimal decision-making under the two different approaches.
We suppose that residents in an economy comprise non-cooperative game players, with their income following a normal distribution according to which residents are defined as i ( μ , σ 2 ) , where μ denotes the mean of residents’ income and σ denotes its standard deviation, and every resident has an identifiable income characteristic I i R + . Income is an exogenous variable in this benchmark model. Without loss of generality, income is defined as I i ( 0 , 1 ] . The government does not participate in the game at this stage.
When making the decision, residents independently choose to accept or reject in a non-cooperative manner. Their income follows a normal distribution with the median defined as I ¯ . The high-income group is defined as those with higher-than-median income, and the low-income group is defined as those with lower-than-median income. Real numbers are defined as P i [ 0 , 1 ] , and the accompanying probability of strategy is P i , i = 1 , 2 , 3 n , assuming the accompanying probability of residents choosing to “accept” is P i and that of residents choosing to “reject” is 1 P i . P is positively associated with income. When making the decision, the players should consider both their preference and common social factors; that is, residents’ preferences and common social factors which jointly shape their decisions.
The environment is usually considered as a sort of public goods. This study refers to some relevant research [60,61,62] on the consumer utility function setting in the supply of public goods. It is also combined with the classic assumption of income utility and makes the following assumptions about the utility function of the individual. We suppose that the utility is a discrete finite set. The utility is reduced to U ( I , E ) without loss of generality, where E denotes the environmental quality coefficient. We assume that the high-income individuals have high marginal utility because they can vote for the environmental project at a certain cost other than the loss of income. Low-income individuals may experience the loss of utility by paying a price for the environmental project that may be higher than the gain from an improved environment. The utility function satisfies the following conditions:
I i > I j U i ( I i , E * ) > U j ( I j , E * ) E i > E j U i ( I * , E i ) > U j ( I * , E j )
where E* and I* denote any E-level and I-level, respectively. We assume that the efforts to improve the environment are because of individuals’ financial contributions deducted from their incomes. Each individual pays the same amount of donation to support a project that significantly increases the utility of the environment. The players can either approve or reject the project by paying or not paying. The players’ utilities are composed of income and environmental utility.
Proposition 1
. In a mixed-strategy environmental protection game G = S 1 , S n ; u 1 u n for any strategy S i = S i 1 S i k , i 1 , 2 n , if there is no authoritative intervention by the government and residents choose the game independently, there is only one pure strategy Nash equilibrium, θ = 0 ,     γ = 0 . θ is the accompanying probability of the high-income group choosing to “accept” and γ is the accompanying probability of the low-income group choosing to “accept”.
In a typical Nash equilibrium, spontaneous environmental protection behaviors are unlikely. That phenomenon is called a prisoner’s dilemma. Therefore, it is necessary to introduce government intervention to solve the “uncovered market problem” [63]. When making the decision, individuals should consider their preferences and common social factors. We assume that there is a strictly monotonically increasing utility function of income. Hence, in an outcome of a non-cooperative game, rational individuals reject the project, inevitably leading to environmental damage and reductions in social benefits.
We suppose that there is a society-administering government that regulates the emission of pollutants through the use of tax. Now, we introduce subsidy t i into the game model as compensation for environmental impact. The subsidy is related to income: t i N + , i 1 , 2 , 3 n .
Proposition 2
. In a mixed-strategy environmental protection game G = S 1 , S n ; u 1 u n , when the government provides subsidies for environmental protection, s i N + , i 1 , 2 , 3 n exists, satisfying the mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium S * = S 1 * , S n * ; u 1 * u n * , and the accompanying probability for the high-income group and the low-income group to “accept” is θ * and γ * , respectively.
The subsidy of the environmental project does not increase the income level of high-income or low-income individuals. Rather, the income levels of both subsets decrease. However, some may have a higher utility in aggregate when environment utility is included in the function. Without the loss of generality, we suppose that the income of the high-income group and the low-income group are I H ¯ and I L ¯ , respectively. To further understand the Nash equilibrium in the subsidy situation, we suppose that the tax on the high-income group and the low-income group are t H ¯ and t L ¯ , respectively.
Proposition 3.
The defined mixed-strategy environmental protection game G = S 1 , S n ; u 1 u n has and only has one mixed strategy Nash equilibrium S * = S 1 * , S n * ; u 1 * u n * and has accompanying probability P i [ 0 , 1 ] .
We define this as: Δ I = I H ¯ I L ¯ .
Proposition 4.
In the mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium S * = S 1 * , S n * ; u 1 * u n * of the mixed-strategy environmental protection game G = S 1 , S n ; u 1 u n , θ and Δ I are monotonically negatively correlated, and γ and Δ I are monotonically negatively correlated.
Proposition 4 indicates that in a mixed strategy game, the probability of an environmental protection policy being supported decreases as income inequality widens and increases as income inequality narrows. Notably, we assume that the income I i ( 0 , 1 ] is normally distributed; thus, the low-incomers have negative utilities change when there is public expenditure on investment, and high-incomers improve their utilities when there is public investment in the environment. If the income inequality is Δ I 0 , the proportion of residents supporting an environmental protection policy reaches a maximal value. In a loose definition, the environment is more likely to maintain a high level when the income is less unevenly distributed than when it is more evenly distributed. This conclusion forms the most important normative research finding of this paper, from which we can deduce that residents’ willingness to adopt environmental protection measures is weak in locations where income inequality is widespread; therefore, achieving meaningful environmental improvement is difficult. In locations with moderate income inequality, residents’ willingness to adopt environmental protection measures is strong, thus, environmental protection can be achieved at a lower cost.

3.2. Model Specification

We attempt to empirically verify the findings from micro-level foundation theory research. The core variables of this empirical research are air quality and income inequality in Chinese cities. We study the income inequality of major cities and environmental coefficients in 2014–2018, thus attempting to identify the empirical relationship between them. We focus on cities because the greatest amount of air pollution is generated and spread within urban areas. However, because the geographic range of Chinese administrative cities’ may include rural areas, we also discuss the detailed urban–rural income ratios.
To examine the impact of income inequality on air quality, we constructed a regression model:
A I R i , t = β 0 + β 1 U R I k , t + β 2 X i , t + μ i + ε i , t
where, subscripts i, k, and t denote cities, provinces, and years, respectively. μ i controls for the individual fixed effect. ε i t is a random error term. AIRi,t is the air quality of city i in year t, measured by seven indicators: the annual average SO2 concentration (μg/m3), annual average nitrogen dioxide (NO2) concentration (μg/m3), annual average inhalable particulate matter (PM10) concentration (μg/m3), the 95th percentile of daily average CO concentration (μg/m3), the 90th percentile of the daily maximum 8-h average O3 concentration (μg/m3), the average annual concentration of fine particulate matter (PM2.5) (μg/m3), and the number of days with air quality reaching or exceeding grade II (good air quality days [GAQD]) (according to the national standard “Air Quality Standard (GB 3095-2012)” issued by the Ministry of Ecological Environment of the People’s Republic of China in 2012, if the concentration of a certain type of air pollutant in a city exceeds the concentration limit of air quality grade II, it is determined that the air quality of that day does not reach grade II). The average annual concentration of PM2.5 from global satellite observations is used in our empirical research as a robustness check.
URIk,t is the urban-rural inequality of province k in year t, which are provincial indicators representing the income inequality of city i in province k. As the urban-rural income inequality constitutes over 70% of the overall regional income inequality in China [64,65,66], it is justified to use the urban-rural income ratio as a substitute variable for income inequality.
The vector Xi,t represents a range of control variables related to a city’s air quality, including per capita gross regional product (PCGRP) at a constant price for the year 2014, the density of the population (DP), industry structure measured by the share of the secondary industry in the gross regional product (Secondary Industries Proportion, SIP), unit area coal consumption (provincial indicator, Coal Consumption, CC), greening rate (GR) of the urban built-up area, and level of financial development (FD) measured by per capita loans from financial institutions. Among them, PCGRP and DP represent social development, and other variables control the source of pollution.

3.3. Sample and Data

Air quality data of 113 key environmental protection cities from the National Environmental Air Quality Monitoring Network published in the China Statistical Yearbook are used to measure the dependent variables of urban air pollution. Because of widespread concern about smog in China, the Chinese government issued the new Environmental Air Quality Standard (GB3095-2012) and the Technical Specifications for Environmental Air Quality Assessment (Provisional) (HJ663-2013), which include seven indicators in the statistical coverage: SO2, NO2, PM10, CO, O3, PM2.5, and GAQD. These are the most authoritative annual continuous observation data on China’s air quality, covering major air pollutants. The summary statistics of air quality indicators of 113 key environmental protection cities in China are shown in Table 1. Environmental monitoring reports that Haikou is the city with the best air quality in China, while Baoding and Zibo are the cities with the most serious air pollution in recent years. Table 1 also report the unit root test results to address the concern of integrated of order 0 (I(0)). For the panel data with only 5 years, IPS test with t-bar statistic [67] and HT test with z-statistic [68] have been used. These test show that the empirical research of this paper will not be troubled by the unit root.
Compared with satellite observations widely used in smog research in China [69], the data from ground monitoring by the Ministry of Ecology and Environment of the People’s Republic of China in key environmental protection cities have an advantage in that the observations the of air pollutants can be obtained from ground monitoring, and information on changes in the structure of air pollutants can therefore be obtained. As a robustness test, this study also employs the average annual concentration of PM2.5 from global satellite observations. These data were obtained from the Air Quality Life Index, produced by the Energy Policy Institute at the University of Chicago (EPIC) (https://dev-aqli-epic.pantheonsite.io/the-index/?visitorCountryCode=CN&l=en, 15 November 2018).
The urban-rural inequality (URI) of the province is measured as the ratio of disposable income per capita of urban residents to per capita disposable income of rural residents. We use the regional urban-rural income ratio as a proxy for income inequality. Urban and rural income data are based on household surveys conducted by the National Statistical Bureau of China. Using the urban–rural income ratio as an inequality indicator is justified because the urban-rural income gap constitutes over 70% of the overall regional income in China [64,65,66]. Bourguignon and Morrisson [70] suggested that a major factor in country differences in income distribution is the labor productivity of non-agricultural sectors versus that of agriculture.
Data on the gross regional product, population, industry structure, green space, and loans were collected from China City Statistical Yearbooks (2015–2019). The provincial coal consumption data from 2014 to 2017 were collected from the China Energy Statistical Yearbooks (2015–2018). Coal consumption data for 2018 are not reported in statistical yearbooks; thus, it is calculated as the ratio of national coal consumption in 2018 and 2017, because the change in coal consumption is negligible over the two years (National coal consumption in 2017 is 3914.03 million tons, and in 2018, 3974.52 million tons). The correlation matrix and variance inflation factor (VIF) among these control variables is shown in Table 2. Since the correlation coefficient between variables is not particularly large, and all VIF are less than 10, this indicates that our regressions will not be affected by multicollinearity. The condition index for collinearity diagnostics among the variables reported the in Table 3 reinforces those results.

4. Results and Discussion

4.1. Income Inequality and Air Pollution

The individual fixed effect ui in the empirical model shown in Equation (1) represents factors affecting urban air quality that cannot be observed, such as atmospheric circulation and environmental capacity, which are constant in the time dimension. The Hausman test is used to confirm that the fixed effects model is better than the random effect model. The adjusted R2 of the model shows a good fit, and the specific estimation results are shown in Table 4.
Despite differences in the sources and determinants of air pollution, the concentrations of most typical air pollutants are monitored, except for O3 (the O3 pollution in Chinese cities is mainly related to high temperature and photochemical smog generated by motor vehicle exhaust, which is quite different from other typical air pollutants) (Table 4), including SO2, PM10, CO, and PM2.5, are significantly positively associated with the urban-rural income inequality variable (URIi,t). The empirical results validate the hypothesis that the widening of income inequality increases the severity of air pollution and that income distribution deteriorates urban air quality, further worsening the negative effect of widening income inequality on social benefits.
Our results also show the impact of per capita GDP (lnPCGRPi,t) and urban population density (lnDPi,t) on air pollution in Chinese cities. Most of the air quality indicators have a significant and positive association with per capita GDP, including SO2, NO2, PM10, CO, and PM2.5, from ground monitoring and satellite observations. GAQD, the reverse indicator of air pollution, has a significant and negative association with per capita GDP. Thus, economic growth will increase the severity of China’s environmental pollution. The coefficient estimations of urban population density were significant in the regressions of PM10 and ground monitoring of PM2.5. Thus, there is a positive correlation between smog and urban population density even when controlling for other factors such as income inequality and per capita GDP.
The variables selected from air pollution sources show strong explanatory power with respect to urban air quality in the empirical model. Cities with a large share of secondary industry and those which use coal extensively experience serious air pollution, and financial development can reduce air pollution. However, public facilities investment, which uses the urban greening rate as a proxy variable, shows no effect on air pollution.
Hence, two empirical results are as follows:
Result 1: Income inequality aggravates air pollution measured by annual average PM2.5 concentration, from ground monitoring and satellite observations.
Result 2: Income inequality is positively correlated with annual average SO2 concentration, annual average NO2 concentration, annual average PM10 concentration, and the 95th percentile of daily average CO concentration. The empirical evidence further supports that besides PM2.5, income inequality is positively correlated with other air pollution indicators.
Therefore, hypothesis H2 is supported based on regression results of most of the air pollutants investigated. These results are similar to some previous studies, e.g., Zhang and Zhao [21] and Hao et al. [4]. These studies have demonstrated that inequality is associated with higher CO2 emission, and we extend it to some other typical pollutants. Contrarily, our results are inconsistent with those of Liu, et al. [38] and Yang et al. [37], who argue that wider inequality is associated with a lower pollution level.

4.2. Endogeneity Concerns

It appears that air pollution can aggravate income inequality [39]. Therefore, we have to examine whether the inclusion of income inequality in the model may suffer from the endogeneity problem. In other words, the causality between air pollution and income inequality could be bidirectional.
The TSLS allows us to address the endogeneity problem. The precision of TSLS estimation lies in the appropriateness of instrumental variables.
We use urbanization rate as the IV of URIk,t, where the rate of urbanization is the urban population/rural population ratio. The explained variables of our model involve air pollution in urban areas, which has no correlation with the urbanization rate in theory. The urban-rural inequality is an important factor driving the migration between urban and rural areas. There is a close relationship between urbanization rate and urban-rural income inequality, so the rate of urbanization can be used as an exogenous IV of urban-rural income inequality. Table 5 reports the results of the TSLS regression, and the under identification test, weak identification test and overidentification test show that the IV selected in our empirical study is valid. Our empirical results are robust when using instrumental variables and TSLS estimation.

4.3. Testing Environmental Kuznets Curves with Urban-Rural Inequality

According to the EKC hypothesis, there is an inverted U-shaped relationship between economic growth and environmental pollution, that is, environmental quality has a dynamic trend of deterioration first and then improvement with economic growth [10,11]. The EKC hypothesis comes from the observation of economic data. Grossman and Krueger [11] found no evidence that environmental quality deteriorates steadily with economic growth. Rather, for most indicators, economic growth brings an initial phase of deterioration followed by a subsequent phase of improvement. The EKC is exhibited in Figure 1.
The relationship between economic growth and the environment is likely to be non-linear. When testing the EKC hypothesis, the commonly used reduced-form is a quadratic function. See Equation (2).
p o l l u t i o n i , t = f ( P C G D P ) = β 0 + β 2 ln P C G R P i , t + β 3 ( ln P C G R P i , t ) 2 + ε i , t
where, pollution is the environmental pollution variables. Once β2 > 0, β3 < 0 is observed in Equation (3), the EKC hypothesis is established, that is, environmental quality deteriorates first and then improves with economic growth. The turning point of EKC can be calculated by the value of β2 and β3, where the environment quality changes from deterioration to improvement.
To explore whether the EKC hypothesis is true for urban air pollution in China, we estimate the following econometric model that considers urban-rural inequality.
A I R i , t = β 0 + β 1 U R I k , t + β 2 ln P C G R P i , t + β 3 ( ln P C G R P i , t ) 2 + μ i + ε i , t
Estimation results of PCGRP and urban air pollution are shown in Table 6. Table 6 reports the regression result of SO2 and PM2.5, the two major air pollutants in China.
The regression results in Table 6 show that consistent with the main conclusions of this paper, the larger the urban–rural inequality, the more serious the air pollution from SO2, PM2.5 from ground monitoring and space observation, with the assumption of the same PCGRP (per capita gross regional product) and other control variables.
In addition, we observe that the EKC hypothesis is established in Table 6 because the statistical air pollutant indicators show that the air quality of Chinese cities deteriorates first and then improves with the economic growth. The regressions without control variables indicate that if the PCGRP exceeds RMB (Chinese currency) 45,214, the annual average concentration of PM2.5 from ground monitoring will decrease. The PCGRP of most Chinese cities has exceeded this standard, and they are in the stage of environmental quality improvement. The regressions with control variables show the turning point of PM2.5 from ground monitoring is RMB 159,072, that is, some cities in the developed areas have crossed the turning point.
Air pollution and the increase of an income gap are by-products of China’s economic growth and major concerns of the public. The emission characteristics of China’s provinces and cities are closely related to their different economic development and income levels, so the formulation and implementation of relevant policies should be proceeded with caution [71]. Fortunately, based on the results of this study, the policy ideas around solving these issues is not contradictory. There is a significant positive causal relationship between income inequality and air pollution, which means that reducing income inequality should effectively solve air pollution. It may also imply that there is no need to curb economic growth excessively for the sake of environmental governance. Sustainable economic development eventually narrows the income gap, and hence leads to the improvement of the environment. The regression results of other air pollutants based on the EKC hypothesis are shown in Table 7. Only PM10 shows similar results as SO2 and PM2.5, in which the air quality of Chinese cities improves first and then deteriorates with the economic growth. Therefore, hypothesis H1 is supported only for some of the pollutants.

5. Conclusions and Policy Implications

Overall, this paper has presented a triangulation of evidence on the impact of inequality on the environment. More specifically, income inequality aggravates air pollution measured by annual average PM2.5 concentration, both from ground monitoring and satellite observations. Income inequality is also positively correlated with other typical air pollutants (SO2, NO2, PM10, CO). The results also show no evidence of the impact of per capita income on pollution. Our game-theoretic model and empirical results concur that reducing inequality improves environmental protection. Our empirical results are consistent with those of Zhang and Zhao [21] and Hao et al. [4], who have demonstrated that inequality is associated with higher CO2 pollution, but inconsistent with those of Liu et al. [38] and Yang et al. [37], who have demonstrated that inequality is associated with the lower levels of the broad-based environmental protection indices that they used.
We suspect that a reason our results are consistent with Zhang and Zhao [21] and Hao et al. [4] is that CO2 emissions are associated with the burning of fossil fuels, which is associated with SO2 and other air pollutants examined in this study. Unlike other pollutants, CO2 does not worsen air quality; thus, it is less likely to be of concern to China’s citizens who confront the reality of poor air quality every day. Future research should differentiate the impact of inequality between CO2 and other air pollutants. Regarding the inconsistency of our results with Liu et al. [38] and Yang et al. [37], further research should be conducted to compare the impact of using different units of analysis such as cities, provinces, and national-level data. In general, the main contribution of this study is that we presented evidence on the positive impact of income disparity on air pollution, which suggests that policies to improve the unequal income distribution may also have a beneficial environmental effect.
A limitation of our study is that it does not examine whether the results can be explained by our theoretical model or if other models provide a better explanation. One means to test Boyce’s [56] theory is to examine if the recent anti-corruption campaign in China led to a decrease in air pollution because the anti-corruption campaign was intended to weaken the power of corrupt government officials who became wealthy from accepting bribes from the rich and powerful. To test our model better, more research should be conducted on local government responsiveness when income in a city or region become more equal. Based on the results of this study and limitations mentioned above, follow-up investigation may focus on specific production and management activities from a more micro perspective and differentiate the different air pollutants. We will also focus on the relation between narrowing the income gap and achieving the goal of “emission peak and carbon neutrality”. Besides, how the trajectory of an environmental indicator in the EKC and the other trajectory of income inequality in the Kuznets Curve converge is also the topic we hope to work on in the future.
Several policy implications can be gleaned from our results. First, we find a strong impact of inequality on air pollution but no impact of per capita income on pollution. This finding suggests that it is not economic growth that affects pollution but the distribution of the growth. One effective measure to improve air quality may be to impose higher taxes on air polluters while allocating a portion of the revenue to lower-income individuals. The control variable that had the biggest impact on air pollution is the proportion of the secondary industry. This result suggests that the government should encourage economic development in industries other than the secondary industry. Another policy recommendation would be to invest in green technologies as a secondary industry which could improve energy efficiency and reduce emissions.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, F.W.; methodology, X.L.; software, F.W.; validation, F.W.; formal analysis, X.L.; investigation, F.W.; resources, F.W.; data curation, F.W.; writing—original draft preparation, J.S.; writing—review and editing, J.Y.; supervision, X.L.; project administration, X.L.; funding acquisition, X.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the Chinese National Funding of Social Sciences [grant number 17BGL144]; the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities [grant number 2020CDJSK02XK10].

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data presented in this study are available on request from the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Liu, X.; Da, W.; Martin, G.; Liu, K. Regional income mobility in large cities throughout China. Appl. Econ. Lett. 2019, 26, 1322–1327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Jain-Chandra, S.; Khor, N.; Mano, R.; Schauer, J.; Wingender, P.; Zhuang, J. Inequality in China—Trends, Drivers and Policy Remedies; International monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Zhu, B. Study of Chinese Gini Coefficients Issues. Ph.D. Thesis, Southwest University of Finance and Economics, Chengdu, China, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  4. Hao, Y.; Chen, H.; Zhang, Q. Will income inequality affect environmental quality? Analysis based on China’s provincial panel data. Ecol. Indic. 2016, 67, 533–542. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Galor, O.; Moav, O. From Physical to Human Capital Accumulation: Inequality and the Process of Development. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2004, 71, 1001–1026. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Zhao, Y. Air Quality Improved in More Cities: MEP. Global Times. 2017. Available online: http://www.globaltimes.cn/content/1036183.shtml (accessed on 5 March 2017).
  7. Jorgenson, A.; Thombs, R.; Clark, B.; Givens, J.; Hill, T.; Huang, X.; Kelly, O.; Fitzgerald, J. Inequality amplifies the negative association between life expectancy and air pollution: A cross-national longitudinal study. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 758, 143705. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. World Health Organization. Global Health Data Repository. 2018. Available online: http://apps.who.int/gho/data/view.main.BODAMBIENTAIRDTHS8 (accessed on 15 November 2018).
  9. Meadows, D.H.; Goldsmith, E.; Meadow, P. The Limits to Growth; New American Library: New York, NY, USA, 1972. [Google Scholar]
  10. Grossman, G.M.; Krueger, A.B. Environmental Impacts of a North American Free Trade Agreement; Working Paper No. 3914; National Bureau of Economikc Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar]
  11. Grossman, G.M.; Krueger, A.B. Economic Growth and the Environment. Q. J. Econ. 1995, 110, 353–377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Panayotou, T. Empirical Tests and Policy Analysis of Environmental Degradation at Different Stages of Economic Development; Working Paper No. 238; ILO: Geneva, Switzerland, 1993. [Google Scholar]
  13. Kuznets, S. Economic Growth and Income Inequality. Am. Econ. Rev. 1955, 45, 1–28. [Google Scholar]
  14. Kuznets, S. Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations: VIII. Distribution of Income by Size. Econ. Dev. Cult. Chang. 1963, 11, 1–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Arrow, K.; Bolin, B.; Costanza, R.; Dasgupta, P.; Folke, C.; Holling, C.S.; Jansson, B.-O.; Levin, S.; Mäler, K.-G.; Perrings, C.; et al. Economic growth, carrying capacity, and the environment. Science 1995, 268, 520–521. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  16. Galeotti, M.; Lanza, A. Richer and cleaner? A study on carbon dioxide emissions in developing countries. Energy Policy 1999, 27, 565–573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Kaufmann, R.K.; Davidsdottir, B.; Garnham, S.; Pauly, P. The determinants of atmospheric SO2 concentrations: Reconsidering the environmental Kuznets curve. Ecol. Econ. 1998, 25, 209–220. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Karapetyan, D.; D’Adda, G. Determinants of conservation among the rural poor: A charitable contribution experiment. Ecol. Econ. 2014, 99, 74–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Baek, J.; Gweisah, G. Does income inequality harm the environment? Empirical evidence from the United States. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 1434–1437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Baloch, M.A.; Khan, S.U.-D.; Ulucak, Z.Ş.; Ahmad, A. Analyzing the relationship between poverty, income inequality, and CO2 emission in Sub-Saharan African countries. Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 740, 139867. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Zhang, C.; Zhao, W. Panel estimation for income inequality and CO2 emissions: A regional analysis in China. Appl. Energy 2014, 136, 382–392. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Jorgenson, A.; Schor, J.; Huang, X. Income Inequality and Carbon Emissions in the United States: A State-level Analysis, 1997–2012. Ecol. Econ. 2017, 134, 40–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Borghesi, S. Income inequality and the environmental Kuznets curve. In Environment, Inequality and Collective Action; Basili, M., Franzini, M., Vercelli, A., Eds.; Routledge: New York, NY, USA; London, UK, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  24. Wolde-Rufael, Y.; Idowu, S. Income distribution and CO2 emission: A comparative analysis for China and India. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 74, 1336–1345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Ravallion, M.; Heil, M.; Jalan, J. Carbon emissions and income inequality. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 2000, 52, 651–669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Du, X.; Li, H. European and American Experiences and Its Implications on Air Pollution Control Strategy in China during the 13th Five-Year Period. Chin. J. Environ. Manag. 2016, 5, 57–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Hao, L.; Wang, Y.; Su, L.; Qin, H. The Evolution Mechanism of China’ s Air Pollution Control Policy Based on Advocacy Coalition Perspective. J. China Univ. Geosci. 2016, 16, 34–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Torras, M.; Boyce, J.K. Income, inequality, and pollution: A reassessment of the environmental Kuznets Curve. Ecol. Econ. 1998, 25, 147–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Scruggs, L.A. Political and economic inequality and the environment. Ecol. Econ. 1998, 26, 259–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Heerink, N.; Mulatu, A.; Bulte, E. Income inequality and the environment: Aggregation bias in environmental Kuznets curves. Ecol. Econ. 2001, 38, 359–367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Brännlund, R.; Ghalwash, T. The income–pollution relationship and the role of income distribution: An analysis of Swedish household data. Resour. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 369–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Kasuga, H.; Takaya, M. Does inequality affect environmental quality? Evidence from major Japanese cities. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 142, 3689–3701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Qi, Y.; Lu, H. Income Inequality, Environmental Quality and Public Health. Bus. Manag. J. 2013, 35, 157–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Bimonte, S. Information access, income distribution, and the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Ecol. Econ. 2002, 41, 145–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Magnani, E. The Environmental Kuznets Curve, environmental protection policy and income distribution. Ecol. Econ. 2000, 32, 431–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Drabo, A. Impact of Income Inequality on Health: Does Environment Quality Matter? Environ. Plan. A Econ. Space 2011, 43, 146–165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Jun, Y.; Zhong-Kui, Y.; Peng-Fei, S. Income Distribution, Human Capital and Environmental Quality: Empirical Study in China. Energy Procedia 2011, 5, 1689–1696. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  38. Liu, Q.; Wang, S.; Zhang, W.; Li, J. Income distribution and environmental quality in China: A spatial econometric perspective. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 205, 14–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Liu, F.; Zheng, M.; Wang, M. Does air pollution aggravate income inequality in China? An empirical analysis based on the view of health. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 271, 122469. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Hill, T.D.; Jorgenson, A.K.; Ore, P.; Balistreri, K.S.; Clark, B. Air quality and life expectancy in the United States: An analysis of the moderating effect of income inequality. SSM Popul. Health 2019, 7, 100346. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Stern, N. The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  42. Garnaut, R. The Garnaut Climate Change Review: Final Report; Cambridge University Press: Port Melbourne, Australia, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  43. Weitzman, M.L. On Modeling and Interpreting the Economics of Catastrophic Climate Change. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2009, 91, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Friedman, J.W. A Non-cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1971, 38, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Ostrom, E. A Polycentric Approach for Coping with Climate Change; Policy Research Working Paper 5095; World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  46. Baer, P.; Harte, J.; Haya, B.; Herzog, A.V.; Holdren, J.; Hultman, N.E.; Kammen, D.M.; Norgaard, R.B.; Raymond, L. Climate Change: Equity and Greenhouse Gas Responsibility. Science 2000, 289, 2287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Meyer, A. Contraction and Convergence: The Global Solution to Climate Change; Green Books for the Schumacher Society: Totnes, UK, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  48. Osborne, M.J.; Rubinstein, A. A Course in Game Theory; The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  49. Finus, M. Game Theory and International Environmental Cooperation; Edward Elgar: Cheltenman, UK; Northampton, MA, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  50. Yanase, A. Global environment and dynamic games of environmental policy in an international duopoly. J. Econ. 2009, 97, 121–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Nagase, Y.; Silva, E.C. Acid rain in China and Japan: A game-theoretic analysis. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2007, 37, 100–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Chander, P.; Tulkens, H. A core-theoretic solution for the design of cooperative agreements on transfrontier pollution. Int. Tax Public Financ. 1995, 2, 279–293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  53. Chander, P.; Tulkens, H. Cooperation, Stability, and Self-Enforcement: A Conceptual Discussion. In The Design of Climate Policy; Guesnerie, R., Tulkens, H., Eds.; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2008; pp. 165–186. [Google Scholar]
  54. Boadway, R.; Song, Z.; Tremblay, J.-F. The efficiency of voluntary pollution abatement when countries can commit. Eur. J. Political Econ. 2011, 27, 352–368. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  55. Roemer, J.E. Would Economic Democracy Decrease the Amount of Public Bads? Scand. J. Econ. 1993, 95, 227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Boyce, J.K. Inequality as a cause of environmental degradation. Ecol. Econ. 1994, 11, 169–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  57. Golley, J.; Meng, X. Income inequality and carbon dioxide emissions: The case of Chinese urban households. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 1864–1872. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Wei, S.; Wang, Q. Research on the Effects of Environmental Policies of North and South Countries—Based on the Game Analysis of Carbon Tax and Carbon Tariff. Financ. Trade Econ. 2015, 11, 012. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Caparros, A.; Pereau, J.C.; Tazdait, T. North-South Climate Change Negotiations: A Sequential Game with Asymmetric Information. Public Choice 2004, 121, 455–480. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  60. Mussa, M.; Rosen, S. Monopoly and product quality. J. Econ. Theory 1978, 18, 301–317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Gabszewicz, J.J.; Thisse, J.-F. Price competition, quality and income disparities. J. Econ. Theory 1979, 20, 340–359. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Shaked, A.; Sutton, J. Relaxing Price Competition Through Product Differentiation. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1982, 49, 3–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Wauthy, X. Quality choice in models of vertical differentiation. J. Ind. Econ. 1996, 44, 345–353. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Wei, S.-J.; Wu, Y. Globalization and Inequality: Evidence from within China; NBER Working Paper No. 8611; NBER: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Yao, S.; Zhang, Z.; Feng, G. Rural-urban and regional inequality in output, income and consumption in China under economic reforms. J. Econ. Stud. 2005, 32, 4–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Wan, G.; Lu, M.; Chen, Z. The inequality–Growth Nexus in the Short and Long Run: Empirical Evidence from China. J. Comp. Econ. 2006, 34, 654–667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  67. Im, K.; Pesaran, M.; Shin, Y. Testing for Unit Roots in Heterogeneous Panels. J. Econom. 2003, 115, 53–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Harris, R.; Tzavalis, E. Inference for Unit Roots in Dynamic Panels where the time Dimension is Fixed. J. Econom. 1999, 91, 201–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Donkelaar, V.A.; Martin, R.V.; Brauer, M.; Boys, B.L. Use of Satellite Observations for Long-term Exposure Assessment of Global Concentrations of Fine Particulate Matter. Environ. Health Perspect. 2015, 123, 135–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  70. Bourguignon, F.; Morrisson, C. Inequality and development: The role of dualism. J. Dev. Econ. 1998, 57, 233–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Wang, F.; Shackman, J.; Liu, X. Carbon emission flow in the power industry and provincial CO2 emissions: Evidence from cross-provincial secondary energy trading in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 159, 397–409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Environmental Kuznets curve (EKC).
Figure 1. Environmental Kuznets curve (EKC).
Ijerph 18 08546 g001
Table 1. Summary Statistics of Air Quality Indicators of 113 Key Cities in China (2014–2018).
Table 1. Summary Statistics of Air Quality Indicators of 113 Key Cities in China (2014–2018).
Air Quality IndicatorsObsMeanMediaSDMinMaxUnit Root Test
IPS t-BarHT
z-Statistic
Annual average SO2 concentration (μg/m3)56525.521.016.65 (Haikou, 2015, 2018)123 (Zibo, 2014)−1.6811.408
Annual average NO2 concentration (μg/m3)56537.337.010.312 (Haikou, 2017)67 (Zibo, 2014)−2.201 ***−2.252 **
Average annual PM10 concentration (μg/m3)56590.986.030.535 (Haikou, 2016)224 (Baoding, 2014)−2.002 ***−4.069 ***
95th percentile of average daily CO concentration (μg/m3)5651.991.70.850.8 (Haikou, 2017, 2018; Xiamen, 2017; Quanzhou, 2018)5.8 (Baoding, 2015)−1.629-8.863 **
90th percentile of the daily maximum 8-h average O3 concentration (μg/m3)565149.8149.027.269 (Hefei, 2014)218 (Baoding, 2017)−2.281 ***−4.512 ***
Annual average PM2.5 concentration (μg/m3)56552.052.017.818 (Haikou, 2018)129 (Baoding, 2014)−2.117 ***−3.793 ***
Number of days with air quality reaching or exceeding grade II56525826061.379 (Baoding, 2014)366 (Panzhihua, 2016)−2.332 ***−7.844 ***
Note: Obs indicates the number of observations. SD indicates standard deviation. Min indicates minimum value. Max indicates maximum value. IPS indicates Im, Pesaran and Shin (2003). HT indicates Harris and Tzavalis (1999). Superscripts, **, and *** indicate significant levels of confidence at 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Table 2. Correlation matrix and variance inflation factor (VIF) among the control variables.
Table 2. Correlation matrix and variance inflation factor (VIF) among the control variables.
VariablesURIk,tlnPCGRPi,tlnDPi,tSIPi,tLnCCk,tGRi,tlnFDi,t
URIk,t1
lnPCGRPi,t−0.1241
lnDPi,t−0.2760.1371
SIPi,t0.1070.148−0.1871
lnCCk,t−0.4640.0670.303−0.0921
GRi,t−0.0940.2080.113−0.0490.1621
lnFDi,t−0.1230.6550.359−0.3270.0370.1651
VIF1.3252.5161.3341.5471.3841.0762.930
Note: URI indicates the urban-rural inequality. PCGRP indicates per capita gross regional product. DP indicates the density of the population. SIP indicates the secondary industries proportion. CC indicates coal consumption. GR indicates the greening rate of the urban built-up area. FD indicates per capita loans from financial institutions.
Table 3. Collinearity diagnostics among the control variables.
Table 3. Collinearity diagnostics among the control variables.
DimensionEigenvalueCondition
Index
Variance Proportions
ConstantURIk,tlnPCGRPi,tlnDPi,tSIPi,tlnCCk,tGRi,tlnFDi,t
17.8931.0000.000.000.000.000.000.000.000.00
20.05312.1870.000.000.000.010.520.020.010.00
30.02517.8270.000.190.000.010.080.260.000.00
40.01225.8300.000.020.000.160.000.010.820.00
50.01027.7550.000.200.000.380.030.510.050.00
60.00538.3800.010.330.020.380.000.050.120.06
70.00186.9370.660.220.000.000.120.150.010.33
80.000137.6940.320.040.970.070.240.000.010.60
Note: URI indicates the urban-rural inequality. PCGRP indicates per capita gross regional product. DP indicates the density of the population. SIP indicates the secondary industries proportion. CC indicates coal consumption. GR indicates the greening rate of the urban built-up area. FD indicates per capita loans from financial institutions.
Table 4. Regressions analysis for air pollution and income inequality.
Table 4. Regressions analysis for air pollution and income inequality.
VariablesSO2NO2PM10COO3PM2.5GAQD
Ground MonitoringSatellite Observations
Income InequalityUrban–Rural Inequality URIk,t65.885 ***
(14.431)
2.906
(6.128)
52.685 ***
(19.252)
1.936 ***
(0.553)
−61.216 **
(26.815)
47.220 ***
(12.195)
68.540 ***
(9.718)
−61.609
(41.796)
Social
development
Per capita gross regional product lnPCGRPi,t10.560 **
(4.686)
3.290 *
(1.990)
16.755 ***
(6.252)
0.482 ***
(0.179)
−2.992
(8.708)
11.884 ***
(3.960)
6.066 *
(3.156)
−37.253 ***
(13.573)
Population density lnDPi,t1.585
(2.096)
−0.493
(0.890)
5.506 **
(2.797)
0.032
(0.080)
2.195
(3.895)
4.332 **
(1.771)
0.587
(1.412)
0.998
(6.071)
Source of pollutionSecondary industries proportion SIPi,t0.871 ***
(0.142)
0.155 ***
(0.060)
1.461 ***
(0.190)
0.025 ***
(0.005)
−1.600 ***
(0.264)
0.770 ***
(0.120)
0.494 ***
(0.096)
−2.094 ***
(0.412)
Coal consumption lnCCi,t−3.509
(5.472)
5.218 **
(2.324)
13.351 *
(7.301)
0.389 *
(0.210)
15.615
(10.169)
15.820 ***
(4.625)
4.219
(3.685)
−36.993 **
(15.850)
Greening rate GRi,t0.185
(0.130)
0.093 *
(0.055)
0.293 *
(0.174)
0.004
(0.005)
0.067
(0.242)
0.143
(0.110)
-0.093
(0.088)
−0.663 **
(0.378)
Financial development lnFDi,t−16.192 ***
(3.495)
−2.081
(1.484)
−27.751 ***
(4.663)
−0.747 ***
(0.134)
25.445 ***
(6.494)
−18.755 ***
(2.954)
−14.110 ***
(2.353)
27.366 ***
(10.122)
Intercept term−108.324 *
(59.421)
−25.602
(25.233)
−116.844
(79.275)
−3.819 *
(2.276)
−3.984
(110.416)
−160.914 ***
(50.217)
−87.387 **
(40.015)
881.058 ***
(172.104)
Urban fixed effectYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Sample size535535535535535535535535
Adjusted R20.7160.8660.8540.8420.6420.8230.8460.826
Note: Standard deviation is the estimated value in parentheses. Superscripts *, **, and *** indicate significant levels of confidence at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively. SO2 indicates the annual average sulfur dioxide concentration. NO2 indicates annual average nitrogen dioxide concentration. PM10 indicates the annual average inhalable particulate matter concentration. CO indicates the 95th percentile of daily average carbon monoxide concentration. PM2.5 indicates the annual average concentration of fine particulate matter. GAQD indicates the number of days with air quality reaching or exceeding grade II.
Table 5. TSLS regressions analysis for air pollution and income inequality.
Table 5. TSLS regressions analysis for air pollution and income inequality.
VariablesSO2NO2PM10COO3PM2.5GAQD
Ground MonitoringSatellite Observations
Income
inequality
Urban-rural
inequality URIk,t
30.127 ***
(8.460)
13.042 **
(5.181)
97.159 ***
(19.136)
1.784 ***
(0.449)
−22.270 *
(12.854)
45.952 ***
(10.883)
36.448 ***
(9.540)
−157.248 ***
(36.858)
Social
development
Per capita gross regional product lnPCGRPi,t−10.413 ***
(2.443)
−3.288 **
(1.496)
−17.598 ***
(5.527)
−0.581 ***
(0.130)
3.825
(3.713)
−8.072 ***
(3.143)
−0.337
(2.756)
16.526
(10.646)
Population
density lnDPi,t
0.215
(1.059)
3.471 ***
(0.648)
10.803 ***
(2.395)
0.126 **
(0.056)
1.842
(1.609)
9.262 ***
(1.362)
10.334 ***
(1.194)
−23.313 ***
(4.613)
Source of pollutionSecondary industries
proportion SIPi,t
0.256 ***
(0.077)
0.039
(0.047)
0.389 **
(0.175)
−0.001
(0.004)
−0.078
(0.118)
0.199 **
(0.100)
0.066
(0.087)
-0.368
(0.337)
Coal consumption lnCCi,t9.658 ***
(1.285)
4.942 ***
(0.787)
21.420 ***
(2.908)
0.360 ***
(0.068)
10.712 ***
(1.953)
10.538 ***
(1.654)
9.410 ***
(1.450)
−44.104 ***
(5.601)
Greening rate GRi,t0.035
(0.142)
−0.142 *
(0.087)
−0.411
(0.320)
0.003
(0.008)
0.098
(0.215)
−0.129
(0.182)
−0.104
(0.160)
0.524
(0.617)
Financial development lnFDi,t1.562
(1.692)
5.020 ***
(1.036)
0.348
(3.827)
−0.009
(0.090)
−0.732
(2.571)
−3.437
(2.177)
−5.672 ***
(1.908)
6.663
(7.372)
Intercept term−31.346
(40.304)
−69.704 ***
(24.682)
−180.246 **
91.169)
0.788
(2.139)
86.987
(61.241)
−71.011
(51.849)
−113.085 **
(45.452)
844.158 ***
(175.601)
Urban fixed effectYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Sample size535535535535535535535535
R20.7470.9410.8710.8610.9770.8770.8560.935
IVUrbanization rate
Under Identification Test
(p-value)
48.434 ***
(0.000)
Weak Identification Test52.459 ***
Overidentification Test0.000
Note: Standard deviation is the estimated value in parentheses. Superscripts *, **, and *** indicate significant levels of confidence at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively. SO2 indicates the annual average sulfur dioxide concentration. NO2 indicates annual average nitrogen dioxide concentration. PM10 indicates the annual average inhalable particulate matter concentration. CO indicates the 95th percentile of daily average carbon monoxide concentration. PM2.5 indicates the annual average concentration of fine particulate matter. GAQD indicates the number of days with air quality reaching or exceeding grade II.
Table 6. Regression analysis for EKC hypothesis: SO2 and PM2.5.
Table 6. Regression analysis for EKC hypothesis: SO2 and PM2.5.
VariablesSO2PM2.5
Ground MonitoringSatellite Observations
Urban-rural inequality URIk,t125.708 ***
(12.965)
67.327 ***
(14.401)
119.465 ***
(11.569)
48.910 ***
(12.120)
111.960 ***
(8.830)
69.787 ***
(9.669)
Per capita gross regional
product lnPCGRPi,t
184.394 ***
(66.491)
134.438 **
(83.981)
224.738 ***
(59.334)
157.044 ***
(53.699)
150.678 ***
(45.284)
113.121 ***
(42.844)
Squared term of Per capita gross regional product lnPCGRPi,t2−8.646 ***
(2.985)
−5.596 *
(2.974)
−10.483 ***
(2.664)
−6.556 ***
(2.419)
−7.234 ***
(2.033)
−4.835 **
(1.930)
Population density lnDPi,t——0.980
(2.112)
——3.623 **
(1.777)
——0.064
(1.418)
Secondary industries
proportion SIPi,t
——0.864 ***
(0.142)
——0.762 ***
(0.119)
——0.488 **
(0.095)
Coal consumption lnCCi,t——−3.578
(5.454)
——15.738 ***
(4.590)
——4.159
(3.662)
Greening rate GRi,t——0.197
(0.130)
——0.156
(0.109)
——-0.083
(0.087)
Financial development lnFDi,t——−15.610 ***
(3.496)
——−18.074 ***
(2.942)
——−13.608 ***
(2.347)
Intercept term−1273.248 ***
(371.675)
−798.854 **
(359.566)
−1450.867 ***
(331.667)
−969.884 ***
(302.593)
−1020.639 ***
(253.131)
−683.999 ***
(241.421)
Urban fixed effectYESYESYESYESYESYES
Sample size565535565535565535
Adjusted R20.6790.7180.7770.8260.8240.848
EKCYESYESYESYESYESYES
Turning Point of EKC42,768 RMB164,714 RMB45,214 RMB159,072 RMB33,342 RMB120,347 RMB
Note: Standard deviation is the estimated value in parentheses. Superscripts *, **, and *** indicate significant levels of confidence at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively. SO2 indicates the annual average sulfur dioxide concentration. PM2.5 indicates the annual average concentration of fine particulate matter.
Table 7. Regression analysis for EKC hypothesis: other air pollutants.
Table 7. Regression analysis for EKC hypothesis: other air pollutants.
VariablesNO2PM10COO3GAQD
Urban–rural inequality URIk,t2.639
(6.138)
56.374 ***
(18.977)
1.966 ***
(0.553)
−62.347 **
(26.861)
−64.810
(41.790)
Per capita gross regional product lnPCGRPi,t−19.659
(27.196)
333.577 ***
(84.085)
3.000
(2.452)
−100.112
(119.016)
−312.163 *
(185.165)
Squared term of Per capita gross regional product lnPCGRPi,t21.036
(1.225)
−14.307 ***
(3.787)
−0.114
(0.110)
4.386
(5.360)
12.415
(8.340)
Population density lnDPi,t−0.381
(0.900)
3.959
(2.783)
0.019
(0.081)
2.670
(3.940)
2.340
(6.129)
Secondary industries proportion SIPi,t0.157 ***
(0.060)
1.442 ***
(0.187)
0.024 ***
(0.005)
−1.594 ***
(0.264)
−2.078 ***
(0.411)
Coal consumption lnCCi,t5.231 **
(2.325)
13.173 *
(7.187)
0.387 *
(0.210)
15.670
(10.173)
−36.838 **
(15.827)
Greening rate GRi,t0.091
(0.055)
0.322 *
(0.171)
0.004
(0.005)
0.058
(0.243)
−0.689 *
(0.377)
Financial development lnFDi,t−2.188
(1.490)
−26.265 ***
(4.607)
−0.735 ***
(0.134)
24.990 ***
(6.521)
26.076 ***
(10.145)
Intercept term102.289
(153.250)
−1882.415 ***
(473.816)
−17.854
(13.817)
537.260
(670.651)
2413.114 **
(1043.396)
Urban fixed effectYESYESYESYESYES
Sample size535535535535535
Adjusted R20.8660.8580.8420.6410.827
EKCYESYESYESYESYES
Turning Point of EKC——115,548 RMB——————
Note: Standard deviation is the estimated value in parentheses. Superscripts *, **, and *** indicate significant levels of confidence at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, F.; Yang, J.; Shackman, J.; Liu, X. Impact of Income Inequality on Urban Air Quality: A Game Theoretical and Empirical Study in China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18, 8546. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18168546

AMA Style

Wang F, Yang J, Shackman J, Liu X. Impact of Income Inequality on Urban Air Quality: A Game Theoretical and Empirical Study in China. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2021; 18(16):8546. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18168546

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Feng, Jian Yang, Joshua Shackman, and Xin Liu. 2021. "Impact of Income Inequality on Urban Air Quality: A Game Theoretical and Empirical Study in China" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 18, no. 16: 8546. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18168546

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop