1. Introduction
A consumer’s attitude towards risk has been a central topic in financial economics and particularly asset pricing. A notable long-standing discrepancy between asset pricing models and data is the equity premium puzzle (
Mehra and Prescott 1985;
Weil 1989), according to which the implied risk aversion is implausibly high. For a reasonable level of relative risk aversion, the conventional consumption-based capital asset pricing model (C-CAPM) calibrates an equity risk premium and a risk-free rate that do not match the historically observed levels.
Several revisions and elaborations of theory have been proposed trying to provide a possible explanation on why investors may demand such a high equity premium for holding risky assets. It has to be noted that no resolution proposed in the finance literature has fully resolved this anomaly, at least not single-handedly. We focus on the strands of literature involving habit formation and uninsurable income risk. Specifically, we examine the importance of habit formation for individuals’ portfolio allocations when a background risk is present.
Habit formation models modify preferences so that the agent can be sensitive to relatively poor consumption outcomes. In this type of models, utility depends on consumption relative to a reference level of consumption (
Sundaresan 1989;
Abel 1990;
Constantinides 1990;
Ferson and Constantinides 1991;
Campbell and Cochrane 1999). Habit formation works in the following way. When the agents’ consumption is closer to the habit level, agents fear further negative shocks since their utility is concave. A given percentage change in consumption produces a much larger percentage change in habit-adjusted consumption than in consumption itself. In this way, small fluctuations in consumption growth can generate large variations in habit-adjusted consumption growth and hence explain sizable excess returns on risky assets, even for moderate values of the degree of risk aversion
1.
However, there has been criticism in finance literature on whether incomplete markets can help explain asset pricing puzzles.
Krusell and Smith (
1997) argue that when accounting for market incompleteness, “the explanation of puzzles can be partial at best, unless the heterogeneity generated by the models is quantitatively reasonable”.
Gollier (
2001b) also concludes that, in isolation, background risk cannot explain the equity premium puzzle. On the other hand,
Constantinides and Duffie (
1996) are able to reconcile both the equity premium and the risk-free rate puzzles in an incomplete market setting, using as key ingredient of their model labor income following a random walk with drift. Furthermore,
Semenov (
2017) finds that an additive idiosyncratic background risk can explain the high effective risk aversion and consequently accounts for about 60% of the average equity premium observed in the US economy.
In our paper we explore the effects of external additive (subtractive) habits on the equity risk premium (and the risk-free rate) when a background risk is present, and consumers are heterogeneous in terms of their wealth. The joint hypothesis of consumer heterogeneity and incomplete information adds to the possibility of enriching the asset pricing implications of the representative consumer model. We are motivated by the following: First, the connection between wealth distribution and asset prices has long been recognized in literature. Second, there is controversy on whether background risk could prove to be a useful element in explaining asset pricing puzzles. Third, it has been observed that external habits can indeed contribute to the resolution of several asset pricing anomalies.
We start by building our methodology according to
Gollier’s (
2001a) seminal study, as we account for wealth inequality that is established with a mean-preserving transfer of endowment
2. The literature on wealth inequality and equity premium has been continuously expanding.
Gollier (
2001a) finds, among others, that the combination of wealth inequality with a small background risk biases marginally asset prices towards a larger equity premium. An inverse relationship between the equity premium and wealth inequality is observed in the studies of
Gârleanu and Panageas (
2015) and
Toda and Walsh (
2020). Additionally,
Favilukis (
2013) shows that increasing wage inequality along with lower borrowing constraints and decreasing participation costs can explain the increasing wealth inequality and stock market participation, as well as a declining equity risk premium.
Next, we allow for external habits in the additive (subtractive) form
3. We find that stronger external habits can increase substantially the equity premium when there is large income uncertainty. On the other hand, our theoretical analysis suggests that external habits have a complex effect on the concavity of the absolute risk tolerance and on the concavity of the absolute risk imprudence of the investors, which, subsequently, affect the equity risk premium and the risk-free rate, respectively. It is ambiguous whether wealth inequality will increase or decrease the equity risk premium (risk-free rate) when external habits are present. We show that wealth inequality in a habit economy may increase or decrease the equity premium, when a low background risk is present. The ambiguity of our results extends the findings of
Giannikos and Koimisis (
2021) showing in a complete market setting with external habits, that wealth inequality may decrease (increase) the equity premium when the absolute risk tolerance of investors is convex (concave). That will depend on the magnitude of habit strength and risk aversion of agents in an unequal economy. In addition, we complement
Gollier’s (
2001a) work by showing that wealth inequality continues to have a small role in explain asset pricing puzzles, even after the introduction of external habits.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows:
Section 2 describes the model and methodology,
Section 3 presents the data calibrations and discussion of results and
Section 4 concludes.
2. Model and Methodology
2.1. The Setup
We assume a simple Arrow-Debreu exchange economy with a single perishable good, composed of a large number of agents, , who live for two periods, indexed by and , respectively. In period there is uncertainty about the prevailing state of the world at .
To keep the model simple, we assume that all agents have identical preferences and the same subjective discount factor . Below denotes the derivative of function with respect to its argument. This notation has been used throughout the paper for many functions, including the utility and tolerance . The economy is characterized by the von Neuman-Morgenstern (vNM) utility function on consumption at each period, increasing (), twice continuously differentiable and strictly concave (). It is well known that the standard vNM (or expected) preferences exhibit a strong interdependence between risk and time preferences. The uncertainty is characterized by possible states of nature, indexed by and by the associated state probabilities . This implies that the marginal utility of the good in current and future period is decreasing. A frictionless complete market exists for insurance and credit contracts, taking place at . The equilibrium prices and are paid at for the delivery of unit of the good at and , respectively.
It is also necessary to determine how the agents should allocate their initial endowment of the good between immediate consumption and saving/investment for the future. At date 0, there is inequality in the endowment for each agent, where
is agent
’s endowment of the single consumption good at that period. Agent
is also endowed with a bundle of contingent claims (
). The income per capita in state
is random and equal to:
The preferences of consumers are characterized by external habits in the additive (subtractive) form, where intra-temporal utility is written over the difference between consumption and habit. External habit
is defined as a function of per-capita contemporaneous consumption. Each agent is concerned with her current consumption relative to that of others. The investor’s habit is as follows:
where the per-capita consumption is defined as
and is treated as pure externality because the sum of individual consumption equals the aggregate endowment process, which is exogenous.
The consumption-savings maximization problem after the introduction of habit formation becomes:
s.t.
The competitive equilibrium is satisfied by taking the following first order conditions:
where
is the lagrangian multiplier associated to agent
’s budget constraint.
The market clearing conditions are:
2.2. Preferences
All agents exhibit hyperbolic absolute risk aversion (HARA) utility for wealth at the end of a single time period. This assumption allows us to compare optimal risk sharing rules in the presence of background risk with the linear risk sharing rules that exist in an economy with HARA utility and no background risks. The marginal utility for HARA with habits is given as:
for some constants b and
, subject to the feasibility constraint:
2.3. Background Risk
In the real world, investors are exposed to the double hazard of stock market losses and job loss, especially in a recession period. Investment in equities not only fails to hedge the risk of job loss but accentuates its implications. Investors require a hefty equity premium in order to be induced to hold equities. Given that, a question that rises is whether the existence of this uninsurable risk can be a contributing factor for aggregate asset pricing anomalies, such as the equity premium and risk-free rate puzzles. As long as the preferences are risk vulnerable, then a background risk can contribute to that, although there is skepticism in terms of the magnitude of its effect (
Gollier and Pratt 1996).
Gollier (
2001a) shows that risk vulnerability of preferences implies that in the presence of an independent background risk with a non-positive mean, the indirect utility is more concave than the original utility. Because the CRRA utility exhibits risk vulnerability, this suggests that the model with background risk has the potential to explain the observed equity premium with an economically realistic value of the agent’s original utility function curvature parameter. Risk vulnerability guarantees that any zero-mean background risk raises the aversion towards any other independent risk.
Our model is modified in the following way. We assume that agents in the economy faces a non-hedgeable background risk
4, which creates an element of market incompleteness in the economy. This background risk could for example be associated with labor income or holdings of non-marketable assets and is idiosyncratic among the population of consumers. The agent’s wealth at time 1 is
, where
is the background risk.
The habit utility now becomes . In this case, the amount an investor can consume depends not only on the risky payoff, but also on the background risk. The background risk ỹ is independent of the market portfolio payoff z. Moreover, so that the non-hedgeable income is a pure risk, with a non-positive mean. This background risk is also a time 1 measurable random variable, denoted by , where is a random variable with non-positive mean and unit variance and is a constant measuring the size of the background risk. We also assume that is bounded from below.
The economy with agents having a utility function
and facing the idiosyncratic risk
is equivalent to an economy with agents having a utility function
and no background risk. We denote the absolute risk tolerance of
without habits (non-habit ART) as
and the absolute risk tolerance of
with habits as
. The habit ART equals:
when evaluated at
. Differentiating with respect to
yields:
and
where
Gollier (
2001a) proved that for low background risk the absolute risk tolerance of investors will be concave and therefore wealth inequality will raise the equity risk premium. In an economy with low background risk but with absence of habit formation,
would be negative and
non-negative, reducing our case to
Gollier’s (
2001a)
5.
However, when external habits are present, the dynamics are more complex. This can be shown with a simple numerical example. Assume a CRRA utility function with coefficient of relative risk aversion
. In
Figure 1 and
Figure 2 we have drawn the
and
respectively, when the background risk is distributed as
. For a low background risk (
and no habits (
),
is uniformly decreasing (
Figure 1), implying that the indirect utility function has a concave absolute risk tolerance.
But with the presence of habits, such as in the case of
,
can be decreasing or increasing (
Figure 2), implying that the absolute risk tolerance might be concave or convex.
Proposition. Suppose we have an economy with HARA preferences and habit formation, a level of risk aversion
, and a background risk that is small relative to wealth . Then the absolute risk tolerance of habit-forming agents might be concave or convex, implying that wealth inequality may increase or decrease the equity risk premium6.
Proof: Assuming that
and
is distributed as
, with
and
, then a second order Taylor approximation around
would yield:
transforms as:
which can be rewritten as follows:
Due to the linearity of
, the term
is equal to 0. The term
is expanded as:
where
. Given that preferences are HARA, we have:
where
. The term
becomes:
The interaction of habits with risk aversion can reduce or increase
. When habit formation is absent, term
reduces into form (16) below, denoted as
.
with
.
Comparing and we find that if then > . This is always true for , regardless of the habit strength . Then , where is the reduced form of without habits (see Note 3). This in turn implies that , where is the absolute risk tolerance of an agent with habits and denotes the absolute risk tolerance of an agent without habits. Given that is concave, this should be sufficient to explain that can be concave ( or convex (. □
2.4. Asset Pricing
In an economy with background risk, the equilibrium price of an asset is , where is the asset’s payoff. Risky assets and bonds have payoff vectors and , respectively.
The relative price of a risky asset with respect to bonds is evaluated as:
The risk-free asset provides one unit of consumption good at
with probability
. The price of the bond will be:
where
is the gross risk-free rate,
is the current level of income per capita and
is the income per capita at the maturity of the gross risk-free rate.
Subsequently, the risk-free rate is equal to:
3. Calibration and Results
We also examine numerically the effect on the equity risk premium in an economy with external habits, endowment inequality and background risk. In order to be able to compare our calibration findings with
Gollier’s (
2001a) we explore an economy with similar characteristics. In period
the consumption per capita is certain and equal to
. In period
, two states of the world exist, a recession indexed by 1 and a growth state which is indexed by 2. In state 1 the per capita consumption becomes
with a probability of 61.8%. In state 2 the per capita consumption becomes
with a probability of 38.2%. We also note that our qualitative results do not depend on the probability of a recession, and they do not depend on the particular values of the growth rate of the per capita consumption in each state either. The mean and the variance of the growth rate of this economy are the same as those of the U.S. economy for the period 1889–1978 (See
Table 1 data).
In terms of the wealth distribution of the economy, we run a simulation of two equally weighted classes, poor and rich. The poor are endowed with a share of of the GDP per capita in each state, and the rich are endowed with the rest . Parameter is the coefficient of variation of the wealth distribution. Parameter measures the degree of relative risk aversion evaluated at consumption level and is set at , which is reasonable and consistent with the finance literature. Lastly, we introduce an uninsurable labor income risk , distributed as , i.e., a background risk will yield a 50-50 chance to win or lose . Parameter is the standard deviation of the growth of labor income.
The introduction of external habits has a complex effect on the concavity of the absolute risk tolerance. We find that with low background risk (
wealth inequality may increase or decrease the equity premium in an economy with external habits.
Table 2 provides evidence for the ambiguity of results.
The first column of
Table 2 refers to a non-habit economy (
) and confirms
Gollier’s (
2001a) results. The next three columns refer to a habit economy with weak (
), moderate (
) and strong habits (
.5), respectively. In all cases, the level of income uncertainty is low and kept fixed at
. We observe that, for weak habit strength, wealth inequality (
) will increase the equity risk premium in an incomplete market setting. However, for stronger habits (
equal to
or
), wealth inequality will decrease the equity risk premium. This result extends
Gollier’s (
2001a) findings on the relationship between inequality, income uncertainty and the risk premium. Wealth inequality can decrease the equity risk premium even with a low level of background risk when investors exhibit exogenously habit-forming preferences. However, as we observe, the values for the premium continue to be low, given a low level of background risk.
Next, we examine the effect of habits on the equity risk premium as the level of income uncertainty rises.
Figure 3,
Figure 4,
Figure 5 and
Figure 6 show the equity risk premium as a function of the size of the uninsurable income risk. In the finance literature it has been shown that external habits will raise the equity risk premium in a conventional C-CAPM complete market model with CRRA preferences. In these models, wealth inequality has no effect on asset pricing. Our simulations suggest that in an incomplete market model, where wealth inequality matters, external habits will also increase the equity risk premium.
Figure 3 compares non-habits with habits in an egalitarian economy with background risk, while
Figure 4 compares a non-habit with a habit case in an unequal economy (
). We observe that external habits increase the equity risk premium in both egalitarian and unequal economies. The increase of the premium is substantially higher as the background risk increases. With absence of background risk, the increase in premium can be characterized as marginal. It seems that background risk amplifies the effect of habits.
Another observation that we make is that, when the level of income uncertainty is high, wealth inequality will decrease the equity risk premium even after the introduction of external habits. In the non-habit economy with
, wealth inequality produces a premium below 0.45% (
Figure 4), while in the egalitarian case, the premium is above 0.45% (
Figure 3). With habits the results for the equity premium diverge substantially. Specifically, for habit strength
, the risk premium is slightly above 0.6% in the unequal economy (
Figure 4), while in the egalitarian economy is as high as 0.7% (
Figure 3).
Figure 5 and
Figure 6 extend further our analysis.
Figure 5 replicates
Gollier’s (
2001a) findings and compares an egalitarian with an unequal economy (
) where agents exhibit non-habit preferences (
), while
Figure 6 compares an egalitarian with an unequal economy (
) and refers to the habit scenario (
).
We observe that for a larger income uncertainty (
) and absence of habits (
Figure 5), wealth inequality will decrease the equity risk premium. However, in the scenario of the habit economy (
Figure 6), wealth inequality will decrease the equity risk premium even when a low background risk is present (
.
It seems that the effects that habits have in our model economy are magnified when wealth inequality and a high level of income uncertainty are present. The highest equity premium is generated in an egalitarian economy with habits and large background risk. It becomes evident that even after the introduction of external habits, wealth inequality continues to have a small effect in adjusting the equity premium to its empirically observed levels. We leave potential empirical tests of the above results for future research.
4. Conclusions
The objective of this study is to examine the relationship between asset prices, wealth inequality, external habit formation and market incompleteness in the form of background risk. Wealth inequality is established with a mean preserving transfer of endowment. When consumers have HARA preferences without habits and face no uninsurable risk, the distribution of wealth has no effect on the equity premium and on the risk-free rate. We inquire about whether taking into account the unequal distribution of wealth in an economy with background risk may contribute to the equity premium puzzle, when the preferences of the agents are habit forming.
Stronger external habits can substantially increase the equity risk premium. The highest equity premium is generated in an egalitarian economy with external habits and large background risk. Furthermore, we show that in a habit economy it is ambiguous whether wealth inequality will increase or decrease the equity risk premium when a low background risk is present. Specifically, we extend
Gollier’s (
2001a) findings and show that wealth inequality may decrease the equity risk premium even when an economy has a low level of income uncertainty, as long as external habits are present. However, wealth inequality continues to have a small effect on asset pricing, even after the introduction of external habits.
An explanation for the marginal effect of wealth inequality on asset prices can be attributed to the curvature of the conventional HARA utility function and its variations. Specifications of the C-CAPM where the stochastic discount factor is based on higher order Taylor expansions of arbitrary smooth utility functions, such as the one described by
Harvey and Siddique (
2000), might be able to exhibit essentially arbitrary amounts of curvature. Although follow-up work such as
Post et al. (
2008) and
Poti and Wang (
2010) suggested that, under appropriate restrictions, higher moment C-CAPM type of models might be more limited than what was initially expected, these models do not account for the presence of background risk and wealth inequality. This is clearly a rational and possible application of our work. The evaluation of the effect of background risk and wealth inequality in this case is left to future research.