Next Article in Journal
State Characterization of Lithium-Ion Battery Based on Ultrasonic Guided Wave Scanning
Previous Article in Journal
Predicting the Optimal Performance of a Concentrated Solar Segmented Variable Leg Thermoelectric Generator Using Neural Networks
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

What Drives Petrol Price Dispersion across Australian Cities?

by
Arezoo Ghazanfari
School of Economics, Finance and Marketing, RMIT University, Melbourne, VIC 3000, Australia
Energies 2022, 15(16), 6025; https://doi.org/10.3390/en15166025
Submission received: 28 June 2022 / Revised: 15 July 2022 / Accepted: 16 August 2022 / Published: 19 August 2022

Abstract

:
Petrol directly impacts the ability of and extent to which households can engage in day-to-day activities and ultimately directly influences the aggregate economic activity. Petrol price increases can lead to major economic disruption, especially among the most vulnerable, such as low-income families. In Australia, petrol prices differ substantially between metropolitan and regional areas, and regional drivers must pay more for purchasing petrol than those in capital cities. This research explored why retail petrol prices vary from one city to another within and between Australian regions. In this study, clustering methods and panel models will be used to identify factors that cause price differences. The findings revealed that a considerable part of the price differences arose from specific characteristics of cities that influence the demand and supply of petrol, thereby causing variations in price decisions. Petrol prices were substantially influenced by wholesale petrol prices, oil prices, petrol and diesel vehicles, population density, station density, and public transport accessibility. These factors are the main determinants that contribute significantly to price variations between Australian cities. The findings provide critical information for economic agents that interact in this market. From a social welfare perspective, government authorities can consider these factors to improve living standards and consumers’ welfare under price pressure in regional cities.

1. Introduction

Transport costs in Australia account for a significant proportion of household budgets and are also a critical cost for businesses. Given the strong dependency of Australians on roads and the essential role of petrol in the family budget and business profits, the demand for understanding petrol price behavior has increased over the last decade. According to the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC), petrol prices vary significantly between cities, and some areas have higher prices than others [1]. The main questions that arise are, first, why do retail petrol prices differ from city to city, and second, why do consumers have to pay more for petrol in some areas? Despite the importance of these questions, they have not received much attention from researchers. In particular, no significant studies have explicitly investigated the factors that influence petrol prices in regional markets in Australia. Focusing on Western Australia (WA), the purpose of this study was to address the following questions:
  • What determines the price variation between cities in WA?
  • What is the correlation between petrol prices and city-specific characteristics?
  • Which factors result in cross-sectional price variations?
According to the ACCC [2], petrol price differences result from less competition, high profiteering power, high distribution costs, and low petrol sales. Besides the factors already mentioned, other elements cause price variation that could be explained by demand-side factors, daily changes in purchasing patterns, and city characteristics. Researchers have primarily investigated the effects of station characteristics (such as brand) and upstream cost shocks (such as crude oil price) on retail petrol prices among stations, cities, regions, and even countries. However, fewer studies have examined the impact of local characteristics associated with different petrol price patterns. This study applied cluster analysis to find factors that drove the petrol price dispersion between different locations.
The contribution of this research is to provide the following novel results. The findings extend the understanding of the Australian regional petrol markets. It was one of the first studies to examine the effect of city-specific features on petrol prices in regional Western Australian cities. It was also the first study to use a novel dataset. The micro-level dataset used in this study determined the extent of price differences between cities in WA. By examining petrol prices alongside city-specific features, we were also able to distinguish critical factors associated with high petrol prices in some cities and also different price patterns between urban and rural areas. Moreover, the dataset contained city-level information, which helped to avoid possible biases that may result from considering specific cities or metropolitan areas. A particular feature of the database was that it provided a detailed picture of petrol prices across all rural and urban areas in WA, revealing significant explanatory variables that influence prices. Accordingly, this study shed light on the regional petrol markets accurately and transparently.
The practical implications of this study can be represented as follows. First, this study’s findings help regional authorities to understand the retail petrol markets more accurately. To establish effective policies, they need comprehensive information on pricing behaviors. Second, given that price patterns make price comparisons between cities more complicated, the findings of this study help to identify those cities with the higher petrol prices on average after controlling for other influencing factors. It seems that there is collusion or monopoly power in the retail petrol markets in these cities, which push prices higher. Thus, these areas should come under closer scrutiny by authorities. Regional authorities can focus mainly on these cities to conduct the best policies to decrease prices and increase living standards for their citizens. Finally, this study contributes to the regional petrol markets by determining factors that influence prices. The findings provide critical information for economic agents and decision makers that interact in this market. From a social benefit perspective, economic agents can consider these factors to improve living standards and the welfare of consumers under price pressure in some regional cities. For instance, in those areas with significantly higher prices, strategies that will enhance public transport facilities would be more effective at increasing consumer welfare.
This paper is classified into several parts as follows. Section 2 provides an explanation of the relevant theoretical concepts and a review of the related literature. Section 3 presents the empirical framework of this study. In Section 4, the data are described, and the estimated results are presented in Section 5. Finally, Section 6 includes the conclusion of this paper.

2. Background and Literature

There are a few governmental reports and theoretical or empirical studies that examined the reasons for cross-sectional differences in the prices of petrol between geographical locations. As reported by the ACCC [3], there is geographic price discrimination in the Australian retail petrol market because “company data also shows that margins in regional areas are generally higher than in metropolitan cities. Higher margins in country areas have affected the strategy of some businesses such as United Petroleum, which states that it is looking to expand its business by focusing on regional rather than metropolitan sites because there is less competition, lower volumes, and higher margins in regional areas”.
The ACCC reported that lower population and demand in regional areas lead to fewer petrol stations, causing less competition in the retail petrol market [4]. Therefore, we expect that less competition in Australian retail markets results in higher petrol prices in rural and regional areas. Previous literature also revealed a significant relationship between the petrol price and the market structure in different geographical locations, i.e., [5,6,7,8]. As mentioned by Tappata and Yan [9], in less-populated cities with lower station density, there is less competition, such as oligopolistic markets, resulting in higher petrol prices. Kvasnička et al. [10] examined the effect of station density on retail petrol prices in the Czech Republic and found that station density negatively affects petrol prices. Considering the impact of competition on price-setting decisions, Valadkhani et al. [11] examined the impact of upstream cost shocks on the retail petrol prices in Sydney. They found that passthrough is faster among stations with more intense local competition. Therefore, this study examined the impact of competition on retail petrol prices in different WA cities.
Moreover, the ACCC [12] suggested that high petrol prices in regional areas can stem from factors such as supply-side determinants (i.e., international oil price, wholesale price, the Australian/US dollar exchange rate, and higher distribution costs), demand-side factors (i.e., purchasing power, petrol demand, and lower sales of petrol), stations’ locations (i.e., stations in busy highways with higher turnover), and city characteristics (i.e., population). This study examined the impact of all these factors on petrol prices.
The empirical literature chiefly analyzed the effect of station characteristics or international factors on petrol prices, i.e., [13,14,15,16,17,18,19,20,21]. For instance, Haucap et al. [22] found that station characteristics and cost shocks are the most critical factors that affect prices in Germany. Yilmazkuday [23] examined the price differences between stations in the USA using a dataset containing 38,245 price data points. They found that crude oil prices (51%), refinery-specific costs (33%), state taxes (12%), and spatial factors (i.e., land prices, 4%) had the most significant impact on the price disparity between states. However, these studies looked only at price variations at individual stations rather than analyzing price uniformity over a wide geographical area.
Another strand of literature was undertaken to examine the reasons for the petrol price disparity between states, regions, or cities. Most of these studies analyzed the effect of upstream costs, such as wholesale or oil prices, on retail petrol prices [24]. At the country level, Rietveld and van Woudenberg [25] examined the effect of fuel taxes on differences in fuel prices between countries. They used a dataset of diesel and petrol prices for 100 countries to find that tax differences caused significant variations in fuel prices. Burke and Nishitateno [26] also analyzed the price elasticity of petrol demand for 132 countries from 1995 to 2008. They found that differences in petrol consumption and the economy primarily caused different fuel prices.
At the state level, Chouinard and Perloff [27] used a panel dataset containing monthly observations of retail and wholesale petrol prices, oil prices, taxes, demographic factors, state characteristics, and environmental regulations to examine disparities at the state level in the USA from 1989 to 1997. Their focus was on understanding why prices increase and why petrol prices are higher in some states than others. Their findings show that crude oil price, demand variation, tax rates, environmental regulations, and market power are the essential elements that lead to price variances between states in the USA. At the regional level, Bello and Contín-Pilart [28] specified the effect of cost parameters, demographic factors, demand-side variables, and taxes that contribute to price formation in the Spanish markets. According to their findings, price differences were mainly caused by differences in taxation between regions.
However, these studies had some limitations. These studies focused on the variations in petrol prices between broader geographical divisions, such as between states, countries, or regions. There are apparent dissimilarities between countries, states, or regions, resulting in price differences, such as regulations or taxation. A question that remains unanswered is why cities within a particular state and a specific region have substantially different petrol prices. Second, previous studies focused mainly on the impact of taxes, costs, or supply-side factors on price variations. However, it is expected that the specific characteristics of cities can influence the prices of petrol, which was scrutinized in this analysis. Third, these studies focused only on regional petrol markets in European countries or the USA while omitting the Australian market. In this study, we investigated why petrol prices differ between cities in Australia, which is a question that has so far been overlooked. It must be noted that Australians are highly dependent on petrol, especially in regional areas. Additionally, petrol prices have a considerable impact on family budgets and business profits and play a crucial role in the financial decisions of businesses and the quality of life and welfare of households. For this reason, understanding why petrol prices differ between locations in Australia is essential, especially for people who live in cities with high petrol prices. By reviewing government reports, as well as theoretical and empirical literature, the following primary hypotheses were examined:
Hypothesis 1.
The price of petrol is influenced by city-specific characteristics.
Hypothesis 2.
Petrol prices and competition are negatively correlated.
Hypothesis 3.
An increase in the demand for petrol leads to an increase in its price.
Hypothesis 4.
An increase in the initial costs of petrol (such as upstream costs, exchange rate, and distribution costs) results in an increase in the petrol price.
The empirical verification of these hypotheses was undertaken using the methodological framework explained in the next section.

3. Empirical Framework

3.1. Cluster Analysis

This study’s main objective was to determine factors that influence retail petrol prices. To find determinants, first, we needed to classify cities based on their characteristics and then find out how petrol prices correlated with the cities’ characteristics. To achieve this, the study used cluster analysis as the best method for grouping cities by their characteristics. Cluster analysis is mostly applied to market segmentation [29]. It lets us create clusters of cities with similar geographic, economic, and demographic features, as well as the same petrol prices [30]. The clustering method was used by a few energy scholars in their analysis, such as Gillingham [31] and Liu et al. [32]. In this study, both hierarchical and non-hierarchical methods were applied.

3.1.1. K-Means Clustering Method

The K-means method was applied to classify cities into groups with similar features. This approach is a well-known partitioning method for clustering that was developed by Steinhaus [33], Ball and Hall [34], and Lloyd [35] in different streams [36]. The K-means method is a simple, powerful, and efficient technique with some advantages compared with other clustering techniques. First, this method is relatively simple to apply and comparatively faster than non-hierarchical clustering methods. The hierarchical clustering method cannot handle an extensive dataset easily, while the K-means method can computationally cluster a large dataset quickly. This is because the time complexity of the K-means model is linear while the hierarchical model is quadratic. Second, compared with other clustering models, such as principal component analysis (PCA), which aims to cluster by similarities between the variables (columns) of a dataset, K-means analysis clusters observations according to similarities between rows. Third, the K-means method can easily create clusters of different sizes and shapes, such as elliptical clusters. Fourth, the non-hierarchical clustering methods, such as K-means, are more stable than hierarchical clustering. Considering all these advantages, the K-means method was the more appropriate method for clustering cities for this study, and thus, it was applied in the analysis. There are three stages involved in using the K-means clustering algorithm, as follows:
Stage 1:
The first stage of performing the K-means model is selecting the optimal number of clusters (the value of k). It must be noted that k indicates the number of groups or categories that we want the dataset to be divided into. Accordingly, we could classify the data into distinct groups with very similar features and characteristics. There exist different approaches to finding the optimal number of clusters. This study applied the elbow criterion, the gap statistic, the silhouette, the sum of squares, the Calinski criterion, NbClust, and a modified BIC criterion to identify the optimal number of clusters. We used different methods for checking the robustness to find the best value for k.
Stage 2:
After determining the optimal number of clusters (k), it is necessary to find the clusters’ centroids, which are computed based on the means of the data points in each cluster. The Euclidean distance is applied to capture the cluster centroids. The Euclidean distance calculates the distance between two given points (i.e., p and q) in two dimensions ((p = (p1, p2) and q = (q1, q2)) to specify the intra- and inter-cluster similarity using the following formula:
d p , q = d q , p = p 1 p 2 2 + q 1 q 2 2  
Equation (1) is equivalent to the Pythagorean theorem and it can be re-written as follows:
d p , q = r 1 2 + r 2 2 2 r 1 r 2 cos θ 1 θ 2  
where:
(r1, θ1)—the polar coordinates of the point p;
(r2, θ2)—the polar coordinates of the point q.
Based on the Euclidean equation mentioned in Equations (1) and (2), we could calculate the Euclidean distance of each point in the dataset with the k identified points.
Stage 3:
In the last stage, k clusters of cities were created by assigning the point of each data to its nearest cluster. In the K-means model, observations are considered as vectors of variables’ values. In this method, N objects (attributes) are divided into different predefined clusters (k = 1,2, …, K), with each object belonging to the cluster with the nearest mean [37]. The main objective of the K-means clustering method is to minimize the sum of the squares of the distance between observations and their nearest mean. Therefore, the sum of the squared function for the kth cluster is defined as follows in Equation (3):
E S S k = arg   min c i C d i s t (   x i , c k ) 2 = arg   min   k = 1 K i = 1 9 x i c k 2
where:
xi—a vector of ith variable (i.e., distribution cost based on the distribution distance in km), where i = 1, 2, …, 9;
ck—the centroid for the kth cluster, where k = 1,2, …, K;
dis—the Euclidean distance.
In the K-means model, these steps are repeated until the same k points or centers are assigned to clusters in consecutive stages. Therefore, in this study, we used the K-means clustering method to classify cities based on their characteristics.

3.1.2. Hierarchical Clustering Method

In this study, hierarchical cluster analysis was performed to check the robustness of the results of the K-means model following Valadkhani et al. [29]. The hierarchical clustering algorithm divides objects into groups with similar characteristics that are distinct from each other. In the first stage of the hierarchical method, each observation is placed in a separate cluster. Then, two steps are performed repeatedly as follows: (1) the model recognizes the two groups (clusters) that are the closest together and then (2) it merges the two most similar clusters. This procedure continues until all the clusters are combined, and at the last stage, only one cluster exists. The results of the hierarchical clustering analysis are generally illustrated in a tree diagram (dendrogram). Hierarchical algorithms are performed as follows:
  • Find the smallest element dij remaining in D. The distance between clusters i and j are represented as dij (let cluster i contain ni objects).
  • Merge clusters i and j into a single new cluster.
  • Compute a new set of distances dkm using the distance equation as follows:
d k m = α i d i m + α j d j m + β d i j + γ d i m d j m  
where m is any cluster other than k. It must be noted that new distances replace dim and djm in D (nk = ni + nj).
4.
Steps one to three are repeated (N − 1 iterations) until D includes only one cluster that contains all objects.

3.2. ANOVA Test

We classified cities into groups with similar characteristics and applied an ANOVA test to determine whether petrol prices differed significantly between clusters. The Kruskal–Wallis H test was used to analyze variances in this study. It must be noted that the size of the sample was too small, and the normal distribution assumption was not held in the dataset, where a normal/Gaussian distribution should be analyzed with the ANOVA test. Therefore, non-parametric methods, such as the Kruskal–Wallis H test, are more powerful than conventional ANOVA for analyzing a non-normal/non-Gaussian distribution. Therefore, this study used a Kruskal–Wallis H test to analyze the variances. The Kruskal–Wallis H test, sometimes called the “one-way ANOVA on ranks”, is a non-parametric method that is used to specify whether there are statistically significant differences between two or more groups of an independent variable on a continuous or ordinal dependent variable [38,39]. The process for the Kruskal–Wallis H test is as follows:
  • Data for all groups are sorted in ascending order.
  • Ranks are allocated to the sorted data points.
  • The statistic H is estimated as
H = 12 N N + 1   R i 2 n i 3 N 1  
where:
N—total number of data;
nj—size of the jth group;
Rj—total sum of ranks in the jth group.
4.
The critical chi-square value for the (k − 1)th degree of freedom is calculated, where k is the number of groups.
5.
Finally, the decision on whether to reject the null hypothesis is made by comparing the value of H with the critical chi-square value. The null hypothesis is rejected if the H statistic is bigger than the critical chi-square value. The null hypothesis is that the medians are equal. Otherwise, the null hypothesis is not rejected if the H statistic is not bigger than the critical chi-square value [40].

3.3. Regression Analysis

The following model was used to estimate the coefficients of variables that affect petrol prices at city levels:
Retail petrol price = f (upstream costs (wholesale or oil price), supply-side factor (distribution cost), competition (station density), demand-side factors (petrol vehicles, diesel vehicles), characteristics of cities (population density, businesses density, public transport, commuting distance)).
It should be noted that upstream cost shocks (wholesale petrol price or crude oil price) are not considered in the cluster analysis due to this variable’s similarity between cities. However, previous studies mentioned that upstream costs significantly impact retail petrol prices, and when they change, stations pass these cost changes onto their customers through their prices, i.e., [27]. Hence, it was expected that the upstream costs would significantly affect the retail petrol price, and the effects could vary between different cities. Thus, this section presents the method used to examine the impact of the wholesale petrol price (or crude oil price) on the retail petrol price separately. It was anticipated that the coefficient (β) of the wholesale petrol price (or oil price) varied between cities. Equation (6) presents this simplistic specification as follows:
p i t = i + β i w p i t + ε i t
where:
pit—natural logarithm of the average retail petrol prices (based on cents per liter (CPL)) for the ith city at time t, where i = 1, 2, …, 44;
wpit—natural logarithm of the wholesale petrol price (CPL) or the crude oil price (based on Australian dollars per barrel);
εit—a stochastic residual term.
In the next part, we incorporated a set of variables, including demand-side and supply-side factors, as well as city features, into Equation (6) to find the coefficient of all these factors on the retail petrol prices. These variables only changed between cities and were stable over the sample period, just like commuting distance. The effect of these new time-invariant variables could be estimated by the fixed-effects (FE) Equation (7) as follows:
p i t = α + β w p i t + j = 1 9 γ j d i j + µ i + ε i t  
where wpit is the time-varying variable of wholesale petrol price for the ith city at time t (t = 1,…, 608, and i = 1,…, 44); µi refers to individual city-specific effects that are constant over time; dij is the jth time-invariant variable for the ith city, which only changes between cities, not over time; and εit is an independent and identically distributed (i.i.d) error term with a mean of zero and a variance of δ2. In Equation (7), it was assumed that µi is uncorrelated with variables wp and d for all time, as shown in Equation (8):
E µ i | w p i t , d i = 0  
However, the unobserved individual city-specific effects showed the impact of features in each city, which were not considered in the dataset. Thus, the time-invariant variables, which were city-specific factors, were more likely to be associated with unobserved individual city-specific effects, leading to endogeneity issues. The random-effects (RE) model assumes no correlation between explanatory variables and the random individual effects; therefore, this model could not be applied in this study. In contrast, an FE model considers that the explanatory variables are correlated with the random individual effects [41], but the FE model has a significant disadvantage in that it does not estimate the coefficient of time-invariant variables, and thus, could not be used in this study. The RE model can calculate the coefficient of constant variables over time, but the estimates may be biased because of the existence of correlations in our model.
The Hausman and Taylor (HT) model can be suitable for combining FE and RE models [42]. The HT method can estimate a model with several explanatory variables correlated with the individual city-specific effects [43]. Furthermore, estimated coefficients related to the exogenous time-varying variables are more efficient in an HT model than in an FE model. However, an HT model is problematic in that it is difficult to specify the endogenous and exogenous variables, and the wrong definition can lead to biased results [44]. Thus, the within–between or hybrid model is most appropriate in the context of this study to estimate both types of explanatory variables: time-varying and time-invariant. The Equation (9) of the FE model can be expressed in its demeaned form as follows:
p i t p i ¯ = α + β w p i t w p i ¯ + j = 1 9 γ j ( d i j d i j ¯ = 0 ) + ( µ i µ i ¯ = 0 ) + ( ε i t ε i ¯ )  
As seen above, when we demeaned everything in Equation (10), all the time-invariant variables dropped out of the model. The following model may, therefore, be used as the “within” estimator:
p i t p i ¯ = α + β w p i t w p i ¯ + ( ε i t ε i ¯ )
Hence, as stated before, an FE model could not estimate the effect of time-variant variables used in this research. However, following Schunck [45], we could decompose the time-varying variables into a between ( w p i ¯ = n i 1 t = 1 n i x i t ) and cluster format ( w p i t w p i ¯ ) to test the within effects in the RE model. Following Allison [46], the within–between (or hybrid) model is given in Equation (11) as follows:
p i t = α + β 1 w p i t w p i ¯ + j = 1 9 γ j d i j + β 2 w p i ¯ + µ i + ε i t
where:
pit—the average retail petrol prices (CPL) for the ith city at time t, where i = 1, 2, …, 44, and t = 1, …, 608;
wpit—wholesale petrol price (CPL);
w p i   ¯ —cluster mean of the wholesale petrol price for the ith city;
dijjth time-invariant variable affiliated to the ith city;
µi—individual city-specific effects of unobserved variables;
εit—a stochastic residual term.
Following Raudenbush and Bryk [47], this study used a similar model to the within–between model, which was named the “contextual” model, as follows:
p i t = α + β 1 w p i t + j = 1 9 γ j d i j + β 2 w p i ¯ + µ i + ε i t
In this model, β1 was not changed, while β2 was changed. The estimated β2 showed the difference between the within and between effects in the model and it could be interpreted as a contextual effect.

3.4. Determinants of Petrol Prices

This study examined the impacts of the following factors that may lead to price differences.

3.4.1. Supply-Side Factors

Upstream cost shocks (changing the price of wholesale petrol and oil) have a significant effect on retail petrol prices. In Australia, crude oil is mostly imported, and the cost of imported oil is based on the US dollar. Hence, the exchange rate from the US dollar to the Australian dollar can indirectly affect retail petrol prices. We examined the effect of wholesale petrol prices and crude oil prices on retail petrol prices across all WA cities. It must be noted that the impact of the USD/AUD exchange rate was considered in this study by converting the price of crude oil from the US dollar to the Australian dollar.
Petrol prices in regional areas can also be higher due to higher transportation and distribution costs [48]. When purchasing petrol from refineries and delivering that to retailers, the shipping cost becomes a critical factor that affects the price of petroleum products. The distance between a retailer and its nearest wholesaler is used as a proxy for transportation costs and is expected to impact petrol prices positively. Consequently, marginal costs can be larger in cities located far away from wholesalers due to higher transportation costs [49]. Tanker trucks deliver petroleum products to petrol stations in distant locations in remote areas. Caltex Australia, for example, measured that the cost of delivery was typically 1.5 to 3.0 CPL higher in regional areas than in capital cities [50]. Pennerstorfer [18] found that distance (a proxy for distribution cost) did not significantly influence petrol prices in Austria, while Valadkhani and Babacan [29] found that the distance between the wholesaler and retailer had a significant positive impact on variations in cross-sectional margins.

3.4.2. Competition

The ACCC [2] reported that the lack of a regular petrol price cycle in most regional locations stems from having less competition in the retail markets. According to the literature, there is a positive relationship between retail petrol prices and the structure of the market in different geographical locations. Tappata and Yan [9] mentioned that the retail petrol markets are less competitive, with low station concentrations in regional areas. For instance, stations located in highly competitive markets should compete with their prices to gain market share, while in the less-populated cities with low station density, there are low levels of competition (like oligopolistic markets) and lower search friction; thus, petrol prices are higher in these cities. Accordingly, this study examined the impact of competition on retail petrol prices.

3.4.3. Demand-Side Factors

Demand and supply imbalances can affect prices in the retail petrol market. Demand shortages can push prices upward and, conversely, prices decrease if the supply exceeds demand. There are different levels of dependency on fuel types between various Australian locations. Diesel is preferred by the mining and agricultural sectors, while the road transport sector prefers petrol. According to the ABS [51], WA has a rich natural resource base, and regional cities are more dependent on agricultural and mining industries. Because of this, diesel demand is higher than petrol demand in some regional cities in WA, resulting in higher petrol prices there. Valadkhani and Babacan [24] found that the number of cars in the vicinity of retailers is a major factor that can result in variations in cross-sectional margins. Vita [52] found that the number of motor vehicles per population has a positive effect on the retail price of petrol at a state level in the USA, while Alm et al. [53] found that the number of vehicles per capita does not have a significant effect on the retail price between states in the USA.

3.4.4. City-Specific Characteristics

Regional factors, including geographic conditions, residential densities, commercial activities, transport availability, and commuting flows, can result in different petrol prices in various areas [54,55]. The density of the population and the population size were found to significantly affect petrol demand. However, the impact of the population (or population density) on retail petrol prices is ambiguous. As Vitae [52] mentioned, an increase in population may increase the demand for petrol, leading to a rise in petrol prices. In addition, highly populated areas have more traffic congestion, which leads to higher fuel consumption per kilometer and higher rental values. These two factors can lead to higher petrol prices in cities.
On the other hand, population density can negatively influence petrol prices. There are alternative transportation modes in populated cities, resulting in a petrol demand reduction. It is expected that the price of petrol will decrease with increasing demand. Moreover, as Valadkhani and Babacan [24] stated, there is a positive relationship between population density and the size of the market (the larger the population density, the greater the market). There are more petrol stations in highly populated cities, leading to greater competition in the market. Hence, retailers can gain a high level of profits through higher volumes of petrol sales rather than only higher margins. However, in less-populated regional cities, where the size of the market is small, petrol demand and competition are limited. Thus, retailers must set higher prices for petrol to cover their costs, keep their businesses, and make profits. This study examined the effect of population density on petrol prices to determine whether population density positively or negatively affects petrol prices.
Although public transportation accessibility can affect petrol demand, its effect on petrol prices is ambiguous. When public transport services increase, the use of private vehicles decreases, with a subsequent decrease in demand for petrol. Therefore, by increasing the number of public transport facilities (which results in reducing the demand for petrol), the price of petrol is expected to decrease. Regional residents who live in isolated areas are generally unable to use public transportation; therefore, they must rely on their own vehicles to get around. Petrol is a supplementary commodity for vehicles and depending on private cars instead of public transport can increase dependency on petrol. Hence, the use of private vehicles in cities with low access to public transport facilities and fewer stations can create a kind of monopoly power or collusion in the retail market, enabling stations to sell their petrol at higher prices. Therefore, this factor can have both a positive and a negative impact on petrol prices, a phenomenon which was examined in this study.
Commuting distance is another determinant that can affect petrol prices across Australian cities. For example, Cooper and Jones [16] found that petrol prices are higher in locations with longer routes in Lexington, Kentucky. The effect of this factor on retail petrol prices was estimated in this study.
It must be noted that other factors, such as the quality of roads, may also be significant, but data for these variables are not available at the city level.

4. Data

The daily retail prices of petrol were sourced from the FuelWatch website, which is affiliated with the Western Australian Government and administered by the Department of Mines, Industry Regulation and Safety. Except for the Perth metropolitan area, cities were distributed within nine regions in WA, as presented in Table 1. The sample period for all locations in the dataset spanned from 1 January 2017 to 31 August 2018.
There are different types of transport fuel in Australia, but this study focused on unleaded petrol (ULP) as the top petroleum product purchased by drivers. The prices of ULP are based on cents per liter (CPL). It must be noted that most cities have more than one petrol station, and thus, we used the average price of all stations in each city. Figure 1 presents the geographical divisions of cities and regions. While WA has over 50 cities, complete information for 44 cities was available.
There are two proxies for the upstream cost: crude oil and wholesale petrol prices. In WA, petrol is supplied by seven wholesalers in different locations, as follows: one in Broome city in the Kimberley region, one in Port Hedland in the Pilbara region, one in Esperance city in the Esperance region, two in Perth, one in Geraldton in the Midwest region, and one in Albany in the Great Southern region. The daily wholesale petrol prices were obtained from FuelWatch beginning on 1 January 2017 and ending on 31 August 2018. Following Valadkhani and Babacan [29], the distance between retailers and wholesalers was considered a proxy for the transport cost. It was assumed that petrol stations in each city purchased petrol from their nearest wholesaler; therefore, we matched the retail prices of petrol in each city to their nearest wholesalers based on the distance. It was expected that the greater the distance between a city and its wholesaler, the higher the transport and distribution costs. We used the Google Maps website and GIS software to find the latitude and longitude and evaluate the distance between retailers and their corresponding wholesalers.
The daily price of oil was extracted from the “Federal Reserve Economic Data Centre”. The oil data was based on the US dollar per barrel; thus, data for the daily exchange rate was applied to adapt the US price of oil to the Australian dollar per barrel. The USD/AUD exchange rate was gained from the Reserve Bank of Australia’s website.
All information about city-specific characteristics was extracted from the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS). Variables including business density, population density, commuting distance, and public transport accessibility are city-specific characteristics [56]. We used the data of the “method of travel to work by employed persons who used tram, train, and bus facilities” as a proxy of the level of public transport accessibility. The ABS contains information related to the number of businesses and households in each city [57]. We calculated the business density and population density using the number of businesses and the number of households in each city divided by the size of each city’s area, respectively. The number of businesses in each city was applied to capture the effects of demand changes as a result of business activity [58].
The station density variable (the number of stations per km2) was considered a proxy for competition. This variable was applied to capture the effects of competition on retail petrol prices. Moreover, there were different levels of fuel consumption between Australian states and cities, reflecting different levels of petrol demand and resulting in different petrol prices. Following Vita [52] and Alm et al. [53], we applied the “total number of registered petrol vehicles divided by city population” as a proxy for petrol demand and “total number of registered diesel vehicles divided by city population” as a proxy for diesel demand. The summary statistics for all variables are presented in Table 2.

5. Results

5.1. Cluster Analysis

This study used cluster analysis to classify cities based on their characteristics. The attributes were station density (number of stations per km2), business density (number of businesses per km2), population density (number of households per km2), petrol demand (petrol cars per population), diesel demand (diesel cars per population), public transport, commuting distance, and distribution cost. The histograms of attributes are presented in Figure 2.
The first step in performing a K-means model is identifying the optimal numbers of clusters. To this end, we use different tests, including the silhouette, elbow, affinity propagation algorithm, Calinski criterion, modified BIC criterion, gap statistic, and NbClust tests. Based on the results from all these tests, the optimal number of clusters was three (k = 3). Therefore, this study clustered cities into three groups using the K-means model. It must be noted that in the dataset, the attributes had different units (e.g., kilometers, persons, and numbers) or different scales (e.g., 0–5 vs. 0–1000), which were not comparable. Thus, all variables were standardised by converting them to a unitless measure. To do this, we used the scale function that estimated the z-score. After that, we classified the 44 cities into three clusters. Figure 3 shows that cluster two only contained Perth city. Eight cities, namely, Kambalda, Norseman, Coolgardie, Kununurra, Fitzroy, East Pilbara, Ravensthorpe, and Meekatharra, were placed in cluster one. The remaining cities were placed in cluster three.
Moreover, following Valadkhani et al. [24], a hierarchical cluster analysis was conducted for the robustness check. Figure 4 illustrates the hierarchical clustering of cities. As shown, the results were in line with the findings of the K-means cluster. For instance, all cities in cluster one in the K-means model were allocated to one specific group in the hierarchical cluster. The only dissimilarity in results was the location of Ravensthorpe. Except for this city, all cities were placed in similar clusters using both the hierarchical method and the K-means model.
For a better understanding of the differences between the three clusters, by extracting and adding the clusters to the initial data, we were able to derive some descriptive statistics about the cluster means at the cluster level. Table 3 displays the summary statistics of the cluster means. In Figure 5, the information presented in Table 3 was used to display the differences between the clusters and the cluster means of their attributes more visibly. As demonstrated, Perth, which was located in cluster two, had features that were in complete contrast with the other cities. Perth had the highest population density and business density in WA, which was not comparable to other cities. Furthermore, it had the largest number of stations in WA. The total number of stations in Perth was more than the total number of stations in all WA regional cities. This showed that the retail petrol markets in regional areas were less concentrated (the number of stations in cities ranged from one station to 22 stations). In regional areas, the lack of stations reduced competition, which led to higher prices. Therefore, it was expected that petrol prices were higher in regional cities than in Perth.
Two variables were applied as a proxy for petrol and diesel demand: the number of vehicles using petrol per person (petrol vehicles/population) and the number of vehicles using diesel per person (diesel vehicles/population). As displayed in Figure 5, Perth had the lowest level of petrol vehicles/population and diesel vehicles/population compared with other cities. Moreover, cities in cluster one had characteristics opposite to Perth’s features. These cities, for instance, had the lowest level of petrol consumption and the highest level of diesel demand. Moreover, cities in clusters one and three had fewer public transport options than Perth.
The commuting distance and distribution costs were also significantly higher in regional cities compared with Perth. The stations located in clusters one and three were further from their nearest wholesalers and needed to pay more for transportation and distribution. They passed this cost to their consumers by increasing their prices. A lower population density and business activity resulted in less demand for petrol in regional areas than in metropolitan areas. Therefore, selling volumes were remarkably low in regional cities, forcing retailers to increase their prices to maintain their businesses. Generally, it can be argued that the margins of the retail petrol price depend on factors including distribution costs, sale volumes, the cost of storing fuel, and the level of competition. In regional areas, retailers have to pay more for transport, storage, and maintenance; therefore, they must mark up their prices to profit and retain their clients.
In the previous section, cities were grouped according to similar characteristics. This study focused on finding factors that influenced petrol prices and caused price variances. Thus, in this part, it was vital to determine whether there was any significant difference in prices between the clusters. Consequently, we applied the Kruskal–Wallis test to find whether prices differed significantly between the clusters. The dataset contained the average prices of petrol for each WA city. Cities were classified into three clusters. This study tested the clusters to see whether there was a significant difference between the price means. The results related to the Kruskal–Wallis test are presented in Table 4. The p-value was less than the significance level of 0.05, which meant that there were significant differences in prices between the clusters. Each cluster had cities with similar characteristics, resulting in identical petrol prices. In addition, the mean petrol price varied between clusters.
Table 5 shows all the clusters, cities, and their characteristics. It also shows the average petrol prices in each city. Petrol prices differed significantly between cities, as shown in the graph. Perth had the lowest price of petrol, followed by cities located in cluster three. In contrast, cities in cluster one had higher petrol prices than Perth and most cities in cluster three. This indicated that petrol prices were similar between cities with similar characteristics. It can be argued that supply-side factors, demand-side factors, and city characteristics played significant roles in the petrol-pricing behavior of the cities.
Cities located in cluster one had lower station densities, population densities, business densities, and public transport facilities. In contrast, they had higher distribution costs and commuting distances than other cities. Generally, the findings showed that retail petrol prices tended to be more expensive in less-populated cities with fewer population and business densities, where the number of stations was low and distribution costs and commuting distances were high. The results were in line with the hypotheses stated in this research. For instance, as mentioned in hypothesis (2), cities with low-competition retail markets (low station density as a proxy of competition) had higher petrol prices.

5.2. Regression Analysis

Due to the identical size of this variable between the cities, the wholesale petrol price (or crude oil price) was not included in the cluster analysis. It was expected that changes in the wholesale prices (or crude oil prices) had varying effects on the retail prices in each city, causing different pricing behaviors. Hence, we examined models A and B using Equation (6) to identify the effect of the wholesale price (or crude oil price) on retail petrol prices across cities. Table 6 presents the estimated results by considering the wholesale petrol price as an explanatory variable, and Table 7 presents the results of the same estimation by considering crude oil prices as an explanatory variable.
The estimated coefficients for αi and βi for each city were statistically significant at the 1% level when the explanatory variable was the wholesale price (see Table 6) or crude oil price (see Table 7). The effect of crude oil price and wholesale price on the retail petrol price was positive for all cities, which meant that an increase in the price of supplied petrol (crude oil or wholesale petrol) increased the retail prices, and the inverse behavior occurred when the prices decreased. This result was in line with hypothesis 4: when the cost of the supply-side factors increased, the price of petrol increased.
Moreover, the findings supported the view that cities had different reactions to changes in the wholesale or crude oil prices. As illustrated in Table 6 and Table 7, the coefficients of the wholesale petrol prices or crude oil prices differed between cities, resulting in different prices. For instance, the wholesale price had the lowest coefficient regarding retail prices in Broome, Fitzroy, Cunderdin, Tammin, and Meekatharra. In contrast, the highest coefficients belonged to Port Hedland, Capel, Manjimup, Albany, and Geraldton. Despite the fact that Perth, Murray, Mandurah, and Geraldton had the lowest petrol prices, changes in crude oil prices and wholesale petrol prices were not the only reasons. Therefore, if these factors produced different petrol prices in these cities, the crude oil price coefficients would have been higher in these cities than elsewhere, but they were not. There were additional factors, such as city characteristics, that caused city-specific price variations. In addition, the estimated coefficients showed that retail petrol prices were more correlated with wholesale petrol prices than with crude oil prices.
In this section, we incorporated the variables considered in the cluster analysis into panel models to estimate the extent of their effect on petrol prices between cities. We considered three models: fixed-effects, random-effects, and hybrid models. As mentioned earlier, the main disadvantage of fixed-effects models is their inability to evaluate the effect of time-invariant variables, which are constant over time. The random-effects model can estimate the coefficients of time-invariant variables, but it may be biased by the correlation between the explanatory variables and the random individual effects. Allison [46] suggested a hybrid model to overcome these drawbacks. Hybrid models are good alternatives to standard random-effects and fixed-effects models because they provide estimates of time-variant variables and allow for the inclusion of time-invariant variables. The results of the fixed-effects, random-effects, and hybrid models are presented in Table 8 and Table 9.
In Table 8, the upstream costs were proxied by the wholesale petrol price as an explanatory variable. Moreover, the crude oil price was considered a proxy for the upstream cost in Table 9 for the robustness check. The variables were statistically significant, with positive or adverse effects. It appears that the results were robust with the use of different upstream cost proxies and the findings were in line with the results of the clustering analyses. A comparison of the estimates from the fixed-effects model (model one) with those from the random-effects model (model two) and the hybrid model (model three) showed that the estimated results related to the time-variant variables (wholesale price and crude oil price) were the same between different models. Moreover, the estimated coefficients for time-invariant variables were almost similar in both the random-effects and hybrid models; there was a slight difference only in the coefficients’ size, not in their signs. However, the effects of the time-invariant variables were inferred in accordance with the estimated results of the hybrid model considered in this study.
As presented in Table 8, the coefficient of the wholesale price on the retail petrol price was positive and significant (0.838), which implied that when the upstream costs increased, petrol stations needed to pay more for petrol, and thus, they passed this cost on to their consumers by increasing their prices. Furthermore, an increase in the number of petrol vehicles per capita was associated with higher petrol prices (petrol vehicles/population = 0.05), while an increase in the number of diesel vehicles per capita was associated with lower petrol prices (petrol vehicles/population = −0.024). This indicated a positive relationship between the number of petrol vehicles and petrol prices. The estimated results also showed that an increase in the demand for diesel vehicles could cause an increase in the demand for diesel and a decrease in the demand for petrol, leading to a decrease in petrol prices. These results supported hypothesis 3.
Population density (0.006) positively affected the retail prices of petrol. This result was in line with the findings of Vita [52], Chouinard and Perloff [27], Alm et al. [53], and Bello and Contín-Pilart [28]. The results meant that high-population-density cities had a greater demand for petrol, leading to higher prices.
In Table 8, the effect of station density as a proxy for the competition was significant and negative (−0.433), which meant that stations located in highly competitive markets had lower petrol prices. In cities such as Perth and Mandurah, the station density was higher than in other markets, and these cities had lower petrol prices. This finding revealed the validity of hypothesis 2. As a result, competition and petrol prices were negatively correlated. The price of petrol was lower in cities with more fuel stations. This result was in line with previous studies. For instance, Van Meerbeeck [5] and Yilmazkuday and Yilmazkuday [23] found a negative relation between station density and petrol prices. Moreover, Valadkhani and Babacan [29] found that the station density had a negative effect on the variations in the gross margin series in Australia.
The effect of public transport accessibility on the retail petrol price was significantly negative (−0.059). A sustainable transportation system would reduce reliance on private cars. In regional and remote areas, there are inadequate transportation facilities, and their citizens are highly dependent on using their own cars, which has led to a greater dependence on petrol. Therefore, it can be argued that the rising demand for private vehicles in cities with low public transport accessibility increases the demand for petrol, resulting in an increase in petrol prices. In addition, the results showed that business density, distribution costs, and commuting distance did not significantly impact the petrol price variations between cities. According to the estimated results, it can be argued that petrol/diesel vehicles per capita, station density, public transport, and population density were the significant determinants that resulted in the petrol price variations between cities. The findings were precisely in line with the hypotheses set out at the beginning of this paper. The results reported in Table 9 were similar to those in Table 8. The only difference was in the commuting distance variable, which was significant in the second analysis (0.07).

6. Conclusions

In contrast with the previous literature, by taking a regional perspective, this study aimed to answer the following two main questions: Why do petrol prices vary between cities? Which factors result in cross-sectional price variations? This study included new research that analyzed the determinants that affect petrol prices at the city level. This study classified cities into distinct groups by considering the similarities between the city-specific characteristics. This study examined a wide range of factors that lead to price disparities in petrol in WA’s cities. In this study, cities were classified into three distinct groups and the Kruskal–Wallis test revealed a significant price difference in retail petrol prices between the clusters. The results showed that cities with similar characteristics and an identical range of petrol prices were placed in the same clusters. For instance, Kambalda, Norseman, Coolgardie, Kununurra, Fitzroy, East Pilbara, Ravensthorpe, and Meekatharra were in cluster one due to their similar features. Since these cities were located in remote regions with few public transportation options, their residents relied on their private transportation.
This study found that the characteristics of cities, as well as the demand- and supply-side factors, had a significant effect on price variations. It was also found that an increase in the initial cost of petrol (wholesale petrol prices or oil prices) had a significant positive effect on retail petrol prices. This finding was significant because it showed how different cities responded differently to variations in the wholesale or crude oil prices.
Furthermore, we estimated the coefficient of factors that resulted in petrol price differences between all WA cities. Wholesale price, oil price, petrol/diesel vehicles per capita, station density, population density, and public transport accessibility were the main determinants that contributed substantially to the variations in petrol prices between cities. It can be argued that a substantial part of the price disparity stemmed from the specific characteristics of cities, which affected the supply and demand of petrol and affected the pricing decisions at petrol stations. It should be noted that there was a difference of around 33 cents per liter (CPL) between the highest and the lowest petrol prices, which was not negligible. Therefore, this study can be used to enhance the market efficiency and showed that some cities need to be taken into consideration from a social welfare perspective. It also contributed significantly to the understanding of regional petrol markets in Australia. This study complements reports by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission that state petrol prices differ between Australia’s cities and towns.
Petrol prices in regional Australian cities are higher than in capital cities. Consequently, high prices place financial pressures on consumers, mainly on households living in regional and remote cities where public transportation facilities are limited. Furthermore, regional Australian citizens experience the effects of high petrol prices more severely because they must drive long distances to reach destinations, and they have fewer options of where to buy petrol than residents of metropolitan areas where there are plenty of petrol stations. Thus, the petrol price plays a vital role in regional cities. The practical implications of this study can be represented as follows. First, the findings help regional agents to understand the retail petrol markets more accurately. The findings provide critical information for economic agents that interact in this market. To assist drivers in regional areas that are under price pressure, they can consider factors that affect petrol prices and improve these factors. For example, in cities with significantly higher petrol prices, improving public transport facilities would increase consumer satisfaction more effectively.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

https://www.fuelwatch.wa.gov.au/, accessed on 1 January 2021.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Australian Competition and Consumer Commission. Report on the Australian Petroleum Market, December Quarter 2021; ACCC: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  2. Australian Competition and Consumer Commission. Report on the Australian Petroleum Market, December Quarter 2019; ACCC: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  3. Australian Competition and Consumer Commission. Petrol Prices and Australian Consumers: Report of the ACCC Inquiry into the Price of Unleaded Petrol; ACCC: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  4. Australian Competition and Consumer Commission. Fuel in Regional Australia; ACCC: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  5. Van Meerbeeck, W. Competition and local market conditions on the Belgian retail gasoline market. Economist 2003, 151, 369–388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Hosken, D.; Mcmillan, R.; Taylor, C. Retail gasoline pricing: What do we know? Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2008, 26, 1425–1436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Taylor, C.T.; Kreisle, N.M.; Zimmerman, P.R. Vertical relationships and competition in retail gasoline markets: Empirical evidence from contract changes in Southern California: Comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 1269–1276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Ghazanfari, A. Regional Patterns for the Retail Petrol Prices. Int. J. Energy Econ. Policy 2021, 11, 383–397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Tappata, M.; Yan, J. Competition in retail petrol markets. Aust. Econ. Pap. 2017, 56, 201–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Kvasnička, M.; Staněk, R.; Krčál, O. Is the retail gasoline market local or national? J. Ind. Compet. Trade 2018, 18, 47–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Valadkhani, A.; Anwar, S.; Ghazanfari, A.; Nguyen, J. Are petrol retailers less responsive to changes in wholesale or crude oil prices when they face lower competition? The case of Greater Sydney. Energy Policy 2021, 153, 112278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Australian Competition and Consumer Commission. Petrol Price Cycles in Australia; ACCC: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  13. Eckert, A.; West, D.S. Retail gasoline price cycles across spatially dispersed gasoline stations. J. Law Econ. 2004, 47, 245–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Barron, J.M.; Taylor, B.A.; Umbeck, J.R. Number of sellers, average prices, and price dispersion. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2004, 22, 1041–1066. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Clemenz, G.; Gugler, K. Locational choice and price competition: Some empirical results for the Austrian retail gasoline market. Empir. Econ. 2006, 31, 291–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Cooper, T.E.; Jones, J.T. Asymmetric competition on commuter routes: The case of gasoline pricing. South. Econ. J. 2007, 17, 483–504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Houde, J.-F. Spatial differentiation and vertical mergers in retail markets for gasoline. Am. Econ. Rev. 2012, 102, 2147–2182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Pennerstorfer, D. Spatial price competition in retail gasoline markets: Evidence from Austria. Ann. Reg. Sci. 2009, 43, 133–158. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Zimmerman, R. The competitive impact of hypermarket retailers on gasoline prices. J. Law Econ. 2012, 55, 27–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Ghazanfari, A.; Razmjoo, A. The effect of market isolation on competitive behavior in retail petrol markets. Sustainability 2022, 14, 8102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Noel, M.D.; Qiang, H. The role of information in retail gasoline price dispersion. Energy Econ. 2019, 80, 173–187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Haucap, J.; Heimeshoff, U.; Siekmann, M. Price Dispersion and Station Heterogeneity on German Retail Gasoline Markets; DICE Discussion Paper; DICE: Düsseldorf, Germany, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  23. Yilmazkuday, D.; Yilmazkuday, H. Understanding gasoline price dispersion. Ann. Reg. Sci. 2016, 57, 223–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Valadkhani, A.; Chen, G.; Anderson, J. A cluster analysis of petrol profit margins across various regional and urban locations in Australia. Australas. J. Reg. Stud. 2014, 20, 159–184. [Google Scholar]
  25. Rietveld, P.; van Woudenberg, S. Why fuel prices differ. Energy Econ. 2005, 27, 79–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Burke, J.; Nishitateno, S. Gasoline prices, gasoline consumption, and new-vehicle fuel economy: Evidence for a large sample of countries. Energy Econ. 2013, 36, 363–370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Chouinard, H.H.; Perloff, J.M. Gasoline price differences: Taxes, pollution regulations, mergers, market power, and market conditions. BE J. Econ. Anal. Policy 2007, 7, 1–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Bello, A.; Contín-Pilart, I. Taxes, cost and demand shifters as determinants in the regional gasoline price formation process: Evidence from Spain. Energy Policy 2012, 48, 439–448. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Valadkhani, A.; Babacan, A. Modelling how much extra motorists pay on the road? A cross-sectional study of profit margins of unleaded petrol in Australia. Energy Policy 2014, 69, 179–188. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Iglesias, F.; Kastner, W. Analysis of similarity measures in times series clustering for the discovery of building energy patterns. Energies 2013, 6, 579–597. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Gillingham, K. Identifying the elasticity of driving: Evidence from a gasoline price shock in California. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2014, 47, 13–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Liu, D.; Wang, J.; Wang, H. Short-Term wind speed forecasting based on spectral clustering and optimised echo state networks. Renew. Energy 2015, 78, 599–608. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Steinhaus, H. Sur la division des corps materiels en parties. Bull. Acad. Polon. Sci 1956, 1, 801. [Google Scholar]
  34. Ball, G.H.; Hall, D.J. ISODATA, a Novel Method of Data Analysis and Pattern Classification; Stanford Research Institute: Menlo Park, CA, USA, 1965. [Google Scholar]
  35. Lloyd, S. Least squares quantization in PCM. IEEE Trans. Inf. Theory 1982, 28, 129–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Guha, P. Application of multivariate-rank-based techniques in clustering of big data. Vikalpa 2018, 43, 179–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Kaur, N.; Sahiwal, J.K.; Kaur, N. Efficient K-Means clustering algorithm using ranking method in data mining. Int. J. Adv. Res. Comput. Eng. Technol. 2012, 1, 85–91. [Google Scholar]
  38. Kruskal, W.H.; Wallis, W.A. Use of ranks in one-criterion variance analysis. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1952, 47, 583–621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Corder, G.W.; Foreman, D.I. Nonparametric Statistics for Non-Statisticians; John Wiley & Sons: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  40. Hoffman, J.I. Biostatistics for Medical and Biomedical Practitioners; Academic Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  41. Baltagi, B.H.; Liu, L. The Hausman–Taylor panel data model with serial correlation. Stat. Probab. Lett. 2012, 82, 1401–1406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Breusch, T.; Ward, M.B.; Nguyen, H.T.M.; Kompas, T. On the fixed-effects vector decomposition. Political Anal. 2011, 19, 123–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Hausman, J.A.; Taylor, W.E. Panel data and unobservable individual effects. Econom. J. Econom. Soc. 1981, 49, 1377–1398. [Google Scholar]
  44. Bell, A.; Jones, K. Explaining fixed effects: Random effects modelling of time-series cross-sectional and panel data. Political Sci. Res. Methods 2015, 3, 133–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Schunck, R. Within and between estimates in random-effects models: Advantages and drawbacks of correlated random effects and hybrid models. Stata J. 2013, 13, 65–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Allison, D. Fixed Effects Regression Models; SAGE Publications: New York, NY, USA, 2009; p. 160. [Google Scholar]
  47. Raudenbush, S.W.; Bryk, A.S. Hierarchical Linear Models: Applications and Data Analysis Methods; SAGE Publications: New York, NY, USA, 2002; Volume 1. [Google Scholar]
  48. Australian Competition and Consumer Commission. Fuel Facts: What Drives Fuel Prices in Regional Australia; ACCC: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  49. Australian Institute of Petroleum. Inquiry into Fuel Prices in Regional Victoria; The Victorian Economic, Education, Jobs and Skills Committee: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  50. Australian Bureau of Statistics. Census Data by Geography; Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2018.
  51. Australian Bureau of Statistics. Survey of Motor Vehicle Use, Australia; Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra, ACT, Australia, 2018.
  52. Vita, M.G. Regulatory restrictions on vertical integration and control: The competitive impact of gasoline divorcement policies. J. Regul. Econ. 2000, 18, 217–233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Alm, J.; Sennoga, E.; Skidmore, M. Perfect competition, urbanization, and tax incidence in the retail gasoline market. Econ. Inq. 2009, 47, 118–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Lee, S.-Y. Spatial Competition in the Retail Gasoline Market: An Equilibrium Approach Using SAR Models; Department of Economics, The Ohio State University: Columbus, OH, USA, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  55. Li, T.; Sipe, N.; Dodson, J. Social and spatial effects of transforming the private vehicle fleet in Brisbane, Australia. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2017, 51, 43–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Balaguer, J.; Ripollés, J. Do classes of gas stations contribute differently to fuel prices? Evidence to foster effective competition in Spain. Energy Policy 2020, 139, 111315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Radchenko, S. Oil price volatility and the asymmetric response of gasoline prices to oil price increases and decreases. Energy Econ. 2005, 27, 708–730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Tsuruta, Y. What affects intranational price dispersion? The case of Japanese gasoline prices. Jpn. World Econ. 2008, 20, 563–584. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Local government cities and regional boundaries. Source: Western Australia Mineral and Petroleum: Statistics Digest 2016–2017, p. 67.
Figure 1. Local government cities and regional boundaries. Source: Western Australia Mineral and Petroleum: Statistics Digest 2016–2017, p. 67.
Energies 15 06025 g001
Figure 2. Histograms of attributes.
Figure 2. Histograms of attributes.
Energies 15 06025 g002
Figure 3. The K-means clustering of cities.
Figure 3. The K-means clustering of cities.
Energies 15 06025 g003
Figure 4. Hierarchical clustering of cities.
Figure 4. Hierarchical clustering of cities.
Energies 15 06025 g004
Figure 5. Cluster means of attributes in each cluster. Note: this figure used the information presented in Table 3 to show the cluster means of attributes in each of the three clusters more visibly.
Figure 5. Cluster means of attributes in each cluster. Note: this figure used the information presented in Table 3 to show the cluster means of attributes in each of the three clusters more visibly.
Energies 15 06025 g005
Table 1. Western Australian cities.
Table 1. Western Australian cities.
RegionCity/Town
PilbaraEast Pilbara, Karratha, Port Hedland
KimberleyBroome, Fitzroy, Kununurra
GascoyneCarnarvon, Exmouth
MidwestIrwin, Geraldton, Meekatharra
Goldfield–EsperanceKalgoorlie/Builder, Coolgardie, Esperance, Kambalda, Norseman, Ravensthorpe
WheatbeltCunderdin, Dalwallinu, Dandaragan, Meckering, Moora, Narrogin, Northam, Tammin, Williams, York
SouthwestBunbury, Manjimup, Bridgetown/Greenbushes, Busselton, Capel, Dardanup, Donnybrook/Balingup, Harvey, Augusta
PeelMurray, Waroona, Mandurah
Great SouthernAlbany, Denmark, Kojonup, Mt Barker
PerthPerth
Source: FuelWatch.
Table 2. Summary statistics of the characteristics of 44 cities in WA.
Table 2. Summary statistics of the characteristics of 44 cities in WA.
VariablesMeanStd DevMinMaxKurtosisSkewnessRange
Station density0.0050.0110.0000.05714.7813.6830.057
Population density22.35764.6330.000320.90014.0943.746320.900
Business density1.1934.4070.00028.39035.7525.82028.390
Petrol cars/population0.5700.3220.1742.25717.3503.3112.083
Diesel cars/population0.4360.2800.0101.6306.7361.9511.620
Public transport0.0340.0690.0000.3359.4753.0410.335
Distribution cost206.202221.3290.4001184.6008.5052.5351184.200
Commuting distance23.55913.9015.00067.8001.8741.36162.800
Table 3. Descriptive statistics of attributes at the cluster level.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics of attributes at the cluster level.
Clusters/Features123
Station density−0.330124.924333−0.05745
Population density−0.342464.619029−0.0452
Business density−0.268146.171106−0.11053
Petrol cars per person−0.83292−1.198090.255716
Diesel cars per person0.063911−1.356420.022977
Public transport−1.519680.4208180.389892
Distribution cost 1.079932−0.89325−0.25959
Commuting distance1.485641−1.33508−0.35399
Note: As mentioned earlier, all attributes were standardized and converted to a unitless measure.
Table 4. Kruskal–Wallis test.
Table 4. Kruskal–Wallis test.
Kruskal–Wallis Rank Sum Test
Kruskal–Wallis chi-squared = 14.334df = 2p-value = 0.0007
Table 5. Results for cities ranked based on cluster.
Table 5. Results for cities ranked based on cluster.
ClusterCitiesRegionMean Petrol PricesStation DensityPopulation DensityBusiness DensityPetrol Vehicles/PopDiesel Vehicles/PopPublic TransportCommuting DistanceDistribution Cost
1FitzroyKimberley164.440.000070.10.0020.1920.1320.52342.1768.8
1MeekatharraMidwest154.750.0016100.0010.3271.630.29254452.9
1NorsemanGoldfield154.110.00012000.2420.4010.69356.1180.8
1RavensthorpeGoldfield146.830.000110.20.0260.5680.3970.53236.1165.8
1East-PilbaraPilbara145.930.00518000.1750.3750.27267.8450
1KambaldaGoldfield143.360.0003900.0010.2290.3420.77148.1290.6
1KununurraKimberley142.890.000010.10.0060.3640.1850.58728.51184.6
1CoolgardieGoldfield138.910.000020.10.0040.1740.1820.58545.7324.8
3KojonupGreat Southern137.040.000040.70.1730.6360.4680.75717.7149.8
3MooraWheatbelt133.540.00130.60.10.590.8890.76720.1148.3
3DalwallinuWheatbelt143.040.00210.20.1270.8750.3490.72323.2217.6
3CarnarvonGascoyne145.970.000310.10.0140.4510.4190.6639.3442.8
3EsperanceGoldfield138.950.000130.30.0391.0010.3830.82913.98.4
3ExmouthGascoyne158.670.000040.40.0430.4360.2570.6526.1498.1
3KalgoorlieGoldfield141.730.000030.30.0210.5730.4650.79910.2339.1
3Mt BarkerGreat Southern134.580.000381.10.1490.6410.4050.87824.450.6
3BroomeKimberley154.090.000550.30.0230.4130.010.6927.3462.1
3IrwinMidwest136.120.000131.50.1680.6140.1540.82718.650
3Port HedlandPilbara146.160.004810.80.0370.4360.4980.7110.62.2
3KarrathaPilbara149.890.002991.50.0630.4440.4450.30219.5188.7
3B-TownSouthwest137.620.0113.50.3690.6480.3230.83419.1200.4
3ManjimupSouthwest138.140.000151.30.1750.5690.5970.82215183.3
3CunderdinWheatbelt136.130.000910.60.0750.6610.6430.78221127.5
3MeckeringWheatbelt136.130.000450.60.0750.6610.7060.81821107.3
3TamminWheatbelt134.670.00080.40.0440.5640.7150.69619.8150
3NarroginWheatbelt133.540.000943.10.2990.5730.480.83810.3152.6
3WilliamsWheatbelt134.380.000540.40.0760.6010.1150.7521.3136.2
3GeraldtonMidwest138.410.00534139.10.0620.1990.5830.8566.60.4
3AlbanyGreat Southern137.570.000018.80.8060.8570.1780.86720.51.9
3DenmarkGreat Southern137.560.00023.30.3972.2570.8230.8121950.1
3WaroonaPeel137.170.0010250.3750.6450.9570.8827.869.3
3MandurahPeel134.410.000622598.3760.6280.5280.87125.533.5
3MurrayPeel136.480.0029510.40.6590.540.5290.8852832.4
3AugustaSouthwest138.740.032967.40.9430.590.2960.82414257.3
3BusseltonSouthwest1370.0095126.82.7480.5810.3120.85419.2162.1
3CapelSouthwest138.070.0025632.32.0360.550.4010.83321.2130.1
3DardanupSouthwest137.160.0015627.31.4970.5160.480.86218.4129.9
3D-BrookSouthwest138.150.005213.90.4510.6010.3140.78429.4248.5
3HarveySouthwest135.090.0001516.10.9130.6040.5970.85822.695
3YorkWheatbelt133.780.030911.70.1860.7430.2060.82424.378
3NorthamWheatbelt135.660.007047.80.5580.6320.2670.87419.977.1
3BunburySouthwest138.110.0125595.21.9170.6770.2930.88513122.4
3DandaraganWheatbelt135.930.001840.50.0750.620.4180.73635.4143.1
2PerthPerth131.390.05749320.928.390.1840.0570.80958.5
Table 6. The relationship between the retail petrol price and wholesale petrol price. Model A: logpit = αi + βi logxit + εit.
Table 6. The relationship between the retail petrol price and wholesale petrol price. Model A: logpit = αi + βi logxit + εit.
Cityαiβi (xit = Wholesale Price) R 2 ¯ AICSchwarz CriterionHQC
Coef.Std. Errorp-ValueCoef.Std. Errorp-Value
Exmouth1.7280.0650.0000.6780.0130.0000.687−4.642−4.634−4.639
Fitzroy5.2080.0050.0000.0170.0010.0000.320−9.996−9.982−9.991
Coolgardie0.6210.0490.0000.9000.0100.0000.866−4.629−4.621−4.626
Esperance0.7630.0210.0000.8690.0040.0000.916−5.227−5.223−5.226
Albany0.0820.0120.0001.0060.0020.0000.929−5.116−5.114−5.115
Denmark0.7240.0480.0000.8760.0100.0000.863−4.653−4.644−4.650
Kojonup0.4900.0320.0000.9250.0070.0000.913−5.067−5.061−5.065
Mt Barker0.7060.0430.0000.8760.0090.0000.840−4.475−4.468−4.472
Irwin1.3730.0230.0000.7480.0050.0000.849−4.864−4.861−4.863
Waroona0.6860.0240.0000.8700.0050.0000.943−5.634−5.628−5.631
Augusta2.0790.0200.0000.5980.0040.0000.786−4.884−4.882−4.883
B-Town0.6120.0340.0000.8960.0070.0000.896−4.927−4.921−4.924
Bunbury0.8940.0260.0000.8400.0050.0000.820−4.421−4.419−4.420
Busselton1.3870.0150.0000.7390.0030.0000.871−5.067−5.065−5.066
Capel0.2210.0410.0000.9770.0090.0000.810−4.053−4.050−4.052
Dardanup0.8980.0250.0000.8330.0050.0000.891−5.027−5.023−5.025
D-Brook1.2350.0230.0000.7690.0050.0000.913−5.436−5.431−5.434
Manjimup0.1340.0250.0000.9960.0050.0000.858−4.365−4.363−4.364
Harvey1.1320.0280.0000.7870.0060.0000.836−4.661−4.658−4.660
Cunderdin2.5960.0780.0000.4830.0160.0000.591−4.373−4.358−4.367
Meckering1.7330.0950.0000.6620.0200.0000.651−3.996−3.981−3.990
Tammin2.5400.1060.0000.4920.0220.0000.449−3.762−3.747−3.756
Dandaragan1.5040.0250.0000.7230.0050.0000.939−5.941−5.933−5.938
Moora0.5830.0210.0000.8990.0040.0000.960−5.940−5.934−5.938
Narrogin0.4090.0300.0000.9330.0060.0000.926−5.222−5.216−5.219
Williams0.4790.0350.0000.9220.0070.0000.896−4.869−4.863−4.866
York0.8110.0460.0000.8520.0100.0000.868−4.757−4.749−4.754
Norseman1.3140.0180.0000.7760.0040.0000.973−6.647−6.639−6.644
Broome3.9290.0080.0000.0090.0000.0000.852−4.113−4.109−4.112
Meekatharra2.6210.0240.0000.5040.0050.0000.845−5.616−5.610−5.613
Karratha1.4140.0320.0000.7490.0070.0000.807−4.561−4.557−4.559
Carnarvon2.4280.0220.0000.5320.0050.0000.812−5.279−5.275−5.277
Kalgoorlie/Builder1.7070.0190.0000.6740.0040.0000.818−4.849−4.847−4.848
Kambalda1.1170.0810.0000.8000.0170.0000.788−4.305−4.290−4.299
Ravensthorpe2.0070.0590.0000.6230.0120.0000.678−4.243−4.235−4.240
Kununurra1.7730.0320.0000.6690.0070.0000.807−4.788−4.783−4.786
Port Hedland0.4690.0290.0000.9410.0060.0000.829−4.256−4.253−4.255
East Pilbara1.4180.0710.0000.7490.0150.0000.810−4.580−4.566−4.575
Dalwallinu1.7160.0270.0000.6750.0060.0000.852−5.091−5.086−5.089
Geraldton0.0310.0360.0001.0130.0080.0000.731−3.530−3.528−3.529
Mandurah0.5500.0550.0000.9060.0120.0000.480−2.674−2.672−2.673
Murray0.5500.0650.0000.9060.0140.0000.480−2.674−2.671−2.673
Northam0.5580.0170.0000.9040.0030.0000.983−6.790−6.782−6.787
Perth0.7300.0210.0000.8680.0040.0000.449−2.634−2.633−2.634
Table 7. The relationship between the retail petrol price and crude oil price, Model A: logpit = α + βi logxit+ εit.
Table 7. The relationship between the retail petrol price and crude oil price, Model A: logpit = α + βi logxit+ εit.
Cityα0 βi (xit = Crude Oil Price) R 2 ¯ AICSchwarz CriterionHQC
Coef.Std. Errorp-ValueCoef.Std. Errorp-Value
Exmouth4.0230.0140.0000.2420.0030.0000.810−5.143−5.135−5.140
Fitzroy4.2930.0200.0000.1870.0050.0000.355−3.613−3.609−3.611
Coolgardie3.2730.0190.0000.3850.0040.0000.862−4.598−4.589−4.595
Esperance3.2410.0110.0000.3930.0030.0000.856−4.512−4.508−4.511
Albany3.1840.0080.0000.4040.0020.0000.773−3.895−3.894−3.895
Denmark3.2170.0210.0000.3960.0050.0000.847−4.416−4.407−4.413
Kojonup3.1330.0180.0000.4150.0040.0000.839−4.266−4.259−4.263
Mt Barker3.1330.0180.0000.4150.0040.0000.839−4.266−4.259−4.263
Irwin3.4340.0160.0000.3440.0040.0000.655−3.636−3.633−3.635
Waroona3.6000.0550.0000.3060.0130.0000.241−2.077−2.071−2.074
Augusta3.7180.0120.0000.2820.0030.0000.634−3.942−3.939−3.941
B-Town3.5110.0190.0000.3280.0040.0000.758−4.228−4.222−4.226
Bunbury3.3760.0100.0000.3600.0020.0000.825−4.454−4.451−4.453
Busselton3.5380.0090.0000.3200.0020.0000.737−4.166−4.164−4.166
Capel/Colie3.3940.0150.0000.3560.0030.0000.775−4.160−4.156−4.158
Dardanup3.3540.0160.0000.3640.0040.0000.751−3.986−3.982−3.985
D-Brook3.5810.0110.0000.3130.0030.0000.865−5.037−5.033−5.036
Manjimup3.2950.0140.0000.3790.0030.0000.702−3.654−3.652−3.653
Harvey3.2750.0170.0000.3780.0040.0000.728−3.784−3.780−3.783
Cunderdin4.0360.0310.0000.2040.0070.0000.574−4.333−4.318−4.327
Meckering3.7150.0380.0000.2780.0090.0000.626−3.927−3.912−3.921
Tammin4.0360.0420.0000.2010.0100.0000.409−3.692−3.678−3.687
Dandaragan3.4160.0550.0000.3470.0130.0000.377−2.472−2.464−2.469
Moora3.3100.0140.0000.3680.0030.0000.872−4.779−4.773−4.777
Narrogin3.2770.0140.0000.3750.0030.0000.877−4.784−4.778−4.782
Williams3.1740.0150.0000.4010.0030.0000.882−4.697−4.691−4.695
York3.2890.0250.0000.3730.0060.0000.779−4.088−4.080−4.085
Norseman3.6770.0140.0000.3160.0030.0000.886−5.215−5.207−5.212
Broome3.1430.0160.0000.4400.0040.0000.789−3.821−3.818−3.820
Meekatharra4.1460.0100.0000.2080.0020.0000.805−5.411−5.405−5.409
Karratha3.6010.0110.0000.3270.0030.0000.838−4.737−4.733−4.735
Carnarvon4.0870.0090.0000.2080.0020.0000.748−5.086−5.082−5.084
Kalgoorlie/Builder3.5690.0110.0000.3210.0020.0000.716−4.055−4.053−4.054
Kambalda3.5010.0330.0000.3380.0080.0000.768−4.219−4.204−4.213
Ravensthorpe3.8890.0260.0000.2550.0060.0000.601−3.996−3.988−3.993
Kununurra4.0880.0170.0000.2030.0040.0000.510−4.088−4.084−4.087
Port Hedland3.3430.0120.0000.3810.0030.0000.797−4.158−4.156−4.157
East Pilbara4.1260.0260.0000.1970.0060.0000.376−3.603−3.597−3.601
Wubin/Dalwallinu3.6200.0130.0000.3120.0030.0000.809−4.634−4.629−4.632
Geraldton3.3260.0180.0000.3720.0040.0000.548−3.029−3.027−3.028
Mandurah3.3000.0220.0000.3710.0050.0000.436−2.582−2.580−2.582
Murray3.2990.0730.0000.3720.0170.0000.441−2.596−2.581−2.590
Northam3.2460.0360.0000.3860.0080.0000.635−3.313−3.304−3.310
Perth3.2880.0080.0000.3740.0020.0000.480−2.746−2.745−2.746
Table 8. Determinants that influenced the retail petrol price at a city level when considering the wholesale petrol price as a proxy for the upstream cost.
Table 8. Determinants that influenced the retail petrol price at a city level when considering the wholesale petrol price as a proxy for the upstream cost.
VariablesModel 1: Fixed EffectsModel 2: Random EffectsModel 3: Hybrid Model
Coeff.S.E.Coeff.S.E.Coeff.S.E.
Wholesale price 0.838 ***0.00270.838 ***0.00270.838 ***0.003
Mean (wholesale price) 0.618 ***0.168
Station density −0.220 **0.6173−0.433 **0.638
Population density 0.004 *0.01000.006 *0.01
Business density 0.0070.00810.0080.008
Petrol vehicles/population 0.053 *0.03120.05 *0.031
Diesel vehicles/population −0.030 *0.0141−0.024 *0.015
Public transport −0.049 *0.0224−0.059 *0.024
Distribution cost 0.0040.00810.0070.008
Commuting distance 0.0070.00910.0040.013
Adj R20.780.780.86
Note: * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. The natural logarithms of all variables were considered in the models.
Table 9. Determinants that influenced the retail petrol price at a city level when considering the crude oil price as a proxy for the upstream cost.
Table 9. Determinants that influenced the retail petrol price at a city level when considering the crude oil price as a proxy for the upstream cost.
VariablesModel 1: Fixed EffectsModel 2: Random EffectsModel 3: Hybrid Model
Coeff.S.E.Coeff.S.E.Coeff.S.E.
Wholesale price 0.332 ***0.0010.332 ***0.0010.332 ***0.001
Mean (wholesale price) 0.123 ***0.015
Station density −0.040 **0.0119−0.04 **0.012
Population density 0.014 *0.01160.015 *0.012
Business density 0.0110.00910.0110.009
Petrol vehicles/population 0.043 *0.03500.043 *0.035
Diesel vehicles/population −0.01 *0.0151−0.01 *0.015
Public transport −0.10 *0.0253−0.11 *0.025
Distribution cost 0.0110.00870.0110.009
Commuting distance 0.07 *0.02160.07 *0.022
Adj R20.770.770.86
Note: * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. The natural logarithms of all variables were considered in the models.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Ghazanfari, A. What Drives Petrol Price Dispersion across Australian Cities? Energies 2022, 15, 6025. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15166025

AMA Style

Ghazanfari A. What Drives Petrol Price Dispersion across Australian Cities? Energies. 2022; 15(16):6025. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15166025

Chicago/Turabian Style

Ghazanfari, Arezoo. 2022. "What Drives Petrol Price Dispersion across Australian Cities?" Energies 15, no. 16: 6025. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15166025

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop