Next Article in Journal
Assessment of the Brittle–Ductile State of Major Injection and Confining Formations in the Alberta Basin
Next Article in Special Issue
Exploring the Relationship between Crude Oil Prices and Renewable Energy Production: Evidence from the USA
Previous Article in Journal
A Multi-Fluid Model for Water and Methanol Transport in a Direct Methanol Fuel Cell
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A Supply and Use Model for Estimating the Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices

by
Nikolaos Rodousakis
1,
George Soklis
2,* and
Theodore Tsekeris
1
1
Centre of Planning and Economic Research, 106 72 Athens, Greece
2
Department of Public Administration, Panteion University, 176 71 Athens, Greece
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2022, 15(19), 6878; https://doi.org/10.3390/en15196878
Submission received: 19 August 2022 / Revised: 15 September 2022 / Accepted: 16 September 2022 / Published: 20 September 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Energy and Economic Systems: National Accounting Perspectives)

Abstract

:
This paper develops a supply and uses a model to estimate the direct and indirect contribution of costs to the formation of energy prices. The model is implemented into the Greek economy based on data from the supply and use tables. The findings of the analysis indicate that the main component of energy prices are profits, mainly distributed to the energy sector itself, and imports, which mostly concern Mining and quarrying products and Coke and refined petroleum products imported from non-EU countries. As far as the contribution of the energy sector to the price formation of the other industries of the Greek economy is concerned, it is found that the energy sector mainly contributes to the price formation of industrial sectors. The results imply that the containment of energy prices should be principally based on an income policy that would limit excessive profits within the energy sector and an import substitution policy towards the exploitation of domestic mining and quarrying products as well as coke and refined petroleum products.

1. Introduction

The rise of energy prices has become a crucial problem in most national economies during the last months. The increased energy costs have an immediate adverse effect on a household’s energy expenditure. Moreover, they affect the other industries of the economy that are using energy as an intermediate input in their production process. Thus, it is important to study the intersectoral relationships of the energy sector in order to assess the impact of the increased energy prices on individual industries and the total economic system.
By and large, the price of a product can be decomposed to the cost of the factors of production that have been used in the production process. For instance, if we assume the existence of two primary inputs in the production process, i.e., labor and capital, then the price of a product can be decomposed into the cost of labor and the cost of capital involved in its production. Furthermore, in the more realistic case of multisectoral economic systems and produced means of production, the reduction of prices to the costs of primary inputs should take into account two types of requirements. First, the cost of the direct requirements in the production process and, second, the indirect requirements, i.e., the cost of those primary inputs that are used for the production of intermediate inputs in the production process. The present research problem refers to the proper quantification of the contribution of both direct and indirect cost requirements to energy prices. The contribution of the energy sector to the price formation of the other industries of the economy is also considered in the current analytical framework. The main objective of this study is to demonstrate the use of a novel approach for more updated analysis and concise estimation of the contribution of the various costs to the formation of energy prices in a national economy. For this purpose, we adopt appropriate methods of input-output analysis, by constructing a supply and use model and employing data originating from the Supply and Use Tables (SUT’s). The suggested approach is indicatively implemented here for the case of the Greek economy.
Input-output analysis is an analytical tool originally developed by the Nobel Prize winner in economics Wassily Leontief, which analyzed the interdependencies between the different sectors/industries of the economic system (see, e.g., [1,2]); this kind of analysis has been used in the past to estimate the contribution of primary inputs costs to prices by making use of data from the Symmetric Input-Output Tables (SIOT) (see, e.g., [3,4] for the case of the Greek economy). Input-output tables are extensive data matrices that depict the linkages among economic sectors, households and the government, and, hence, the structure of domestic production. In the current context, they are used to analyze the intersectoral flows, from one economic entity to the others, and, hence, the interdependencies within and among the energy sector and all the other sectors of the economy. In turn, they can manifest the role of energy in the current structure of production and the assessment of the potential effects of structural changes across the economy and energy-related activities over a medium to long-term time horizon [5,6,7,8,9].
However, the SIOT is derived from the SUT’s on the basis of some restrictive and debatable assumptions (see, e.g., [10,11,12,13]). Specifically, in the SUT’s, which constitute the core of the modern systems of national accounts, there are industries that produce more than one commodity and commodities that are produced by more than one industry. The SUT’s consist of a pair of tables, the Supply Table, and the Use Table. The Supply Table provides intersectoral information on the production of the products by the various industries of the economy as well as information about the imported goods and services. The part of the Supply Table that describes domestic production is called the Make Matrix of the economy. The Use Table provides information about the usage of intermediate inputs by the various industries as well as the value-added per industry and final demand. The part of the Use Table that describes the intermediate inputs of the various industries is called the Use Matrix of the economy. Therefore, the SUT’s allow, by construction, the consideration of joint production of commodities; it has long been argued that joint production activities constitute the rule in the real world (see, e.g., [14,15]). The joint production phenomenon and its importance were also known to classical and early neoclassical economists (see, e.g., [16]).
In this study, we depart from previous works in the field, since the use of SUT’s allows us to adopt and implement a supply and use model. Based on this model and the economic structure described by SUT’s, for the first time −to the best of our knowledge− we decompose energy prices to the costs for primary inputs. Thus, the proposed analytical framework offers a more realistic picture of the actual economic system and of the formation and impact of energy prices, compared to the traditional approach and the limitations related to the SIOT. Another novelty of the paper is that, in a similar way, using the supply and use model, we decompose the contribution of the energy sector in the price formation of the products of the other industries of the economy.
In this paper, we make use of the supply and use model and exploit data from the SUT’s of the Greek economy for the year 2018 (the latest data available during the conduct of this research), instead of using the traditional input-output model and employing older (as they are published every 5 years) data from the SIOT for the year 2015. Therefore, the present model provides more timely and concise information about the sectoral origin of each particular cost that forms energy prices. Based on the relationships underlying the SUT’s, we implement the supply and use model to decompose the energy prices into the costs of the primary inputs used both directly and indirectly in energy production in the Greek economy.
It is stressed here that the intersectoral input-output analysis focuses on and relies on the current structure of production and assesses the potential effects of structural changes incurred on and resulting from energy prices during the medium and the long term. In turn, the findings of the analysis can be incorporated into a strategic development plan and formulate policy recommendations. In particular, the knowledge about the sectoral origin of each particular cost shaping energy prices enables the economic policy makers to implement more comprehensive and well-targeted strategies in their effort to contain energy prices; these strategies can harness the key role of energy in changing cost requirements and supporting the sustainable growth of individual sectors and the total economy. Nevertheless, in addition to the commodity attribute of energy, wherein the pricing mechanism depends on cost pricing, the energy price also has a financial attribute.
In terms of the energy financial attribute, the pricing mechanism depends on capitalization pricing. According to this financial attribute, energy prices are shaped by a multitude of factors involved in processes that are dynamic and take place over short periods of time. For this reason, the investigation of these factors falls out of the scope of the current research; it is mentioned that these factors may encompass the behavior of the energy market subjects [17,18,19,20], the energy market and the overall economic environment [21,22,23,24], and the pricing mechanism of the energy itself [25].
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 describes the materials and methods used in the analysis. Section 3 presents the results of the empirical analysis. Finally, Section 4 discusses the findings of the paper and concludes, including how the limitations of this study can be addressed in future research.

2. Materials and Methods

The price side of typical SUT’s can be described by the following Equation (see, e.g., [11,12])
e T M = e T U + v T
where M [ M i j ] is the n × n Make Matrix of the economy, M i j denotes the amount (in money terms) of product i produced by industry j , U [ U i j ] is the Use Matrix of the economy, U i j denotes the amount (in money terms) of product i used as intermediate consumption by industry j , v [ v j ] is the n × 1 vector of valued added (or, equivalently, costs for primary inputs), v j denotes the value added generated in industry j , e [ 1 , 1 , . , 1 ] denotes the summation vector, and T is the sign of the transpose of matrix entity. The Make and Use Matrices can be written as M = p ^ B y ^ and U = p ^ A y ^ , respectively, where p [ p i ] is the vector of market prices, p i denotes the market price of product i , B [ B i j ] is the output matrix of the economy, B i j denotes the amount (in physical terms) of product i produced by industry j per unit of activity level, A [ A i j ] is the input matrix of the economy, A i j denotes the amount (in physical terms) of product i used as an intermediate input by industry j per unit of activity level, y [ y j ] is the vector of activity levels, y j denotes the activity level of industry j , and x ^ is a diagonal matrix that is formed by the elements of the vector x .
Thus, Equation (1) can be re-written as
e T p ^ B y ^ = e T p ^ A y ^ + v T
or
p T M ˜ = p T U ˜ + v T
where M ˜ B y ^ and U ˜ A y ^ are the Make and Use Matrices, respectively, of the economy expressed in physical terms. Now, if we assume that the physical unit of measurement of each product is worth of a monetary unit (see, e.g., [26]), i.e., it holds p = e , then Equation (2) becomes
e T M ˜ = e T U ˜ + v T
Provided that the matrix [ M ˜ U ˜ ] is nonsingular, the solution of Equation (3) is given by
e T = v T [ M ˜ U ˜ ]   1
The right-hand side of Equation (4) gives the direct and indirect requirements in primary inputs necessary to produce the net output of each industry. The matrix [ M ˜ U ˜ ]   1 is the so-called “generalized inverse Leontief matrix” (see, e.g., [27]), as opposed to the well-known “inverse Leontief matrix” derived from the usual input-output tables. Thus, Equation (4) reduces the price of the net product of each industry to the costs for primary inputs (wages, profits, taxes, consumption of fixed capital, etc.) involved in its production process. Moreover, Equation (4) captures not only the direct costs of primary inputs of an industry, but also the indirect costs. The latter refers to the costs of primary inputs necessary to produce the products of the other industries that are used as intermediate inputs in the production of each product.
Now, we define the k × n matrix C [ C i j ] , where k is the number of the different categories of primary inputs, n the number of the industries in the economy, and C i j denotes the direct requirements in i -th primary input necessary to produce the output of industry j . Thus, it obviously holds e T C = v T . By post-multiplying the matrix C with the “generalized inverse Leontief matrix”, we get a k × n matrix, say D [ D i j ] , defined as D = C [ M ˜ U ˜ ]   1 , where D i j gives the direct and indirect contribution of the i -th primary input to the price formation of the net product of industry j . Thus, it also holds e T D = e T . Therefore, the matrix D gives the contribution of the different categories of primary inputs to the price formation of the net outputs of the different industries in the economy.
We can further decompose the contribution of costs to price formation per industry of origin of the primary inputs costs, by defining a new matrix, say E [ E i j ] , as E = v ^ [ M ˜ U ˜ ]   1 , where E i j gives the direct and indirect contribution of the primary inputs of industry i to the price formation of the net output of industry j . In a similar way, we can decompose the contribution of costs to price formation per primary input cost and industry of origin, by defining the matrix E k [ E i j k ] as E k = e k ^ [ M ˜ U ˜ ]   1 , where e k is the vector of the k -th primary input used per industry. Therefore, E i j k gives the contribution of the k -th primary input of industry i to the price formation of the net output of industry j .
The above formulation provides a supply and use framework for estimating the contribution of primary costs to the price formation of the various industries of the economy. Since we are interested in the formation of energy prices, we focus on the industry that is related to energy production. Our empirical analysis is based on data from the SUT’s of the Greek economy for the year 2018, i.e., the year with the most recent data at the time of this research. The SUT’s of the Greek economy (for the year 2018) were retrieved from the website of the Hellenic Statistical Authority (ELSTAT), www.statistics.gr (accessed on 10 June 2022), and they describe the production of 64 products by 64 industries. The industry of interest in our analysis is the 24th in order in the SUT’s named “Electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning supply” (“Energy” hereafter). Moreover, from the value-added sector in the SUT’s, we can identify four categories of primary inputs, i.e., “Consumption of fixed capital”, “Net taxes”, “Profits”, and “Wages”. In order to capture the contribution of imports in price formation, we consider the imports of the economy as a primary input. Hence, imports are also included as part of the total supply of each industry. Since the SUT’s of the Greek economy provides detailed information about the imports from the EU countries as well as imports from the non-EU countries, we add these two new categories of primary inputs in our analysis as “EU Imports” and “Extra EU Imports”. Thus, the present analysis is based on Make and Use matrices of dimensions 64 × 64 and six categories of primary inputs.

3. Results

In what follows, we present the results derived from the application of the methods mentioned before to the Energy sector of the Greek economy. First, we construct the generalized inverse Leontief matrix of the Greek economy and we find that it is nonsingular. Thus, the generalized inverse Leontief matrix exists and we may proceed further to our analysis as it was outlined in the previous section.

3.1. The Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices

We begin with the construction of the matrix of direct requirements in primary inputs and, then, we estimate the matrix of the contribution of the different categories of primary inputs to the price formation of the net output of the energy sector. The 24th column of this matrix of the Greek economy gives the contribution of costs to the formation of Energy prices. Our results are reported in Table 1. For reasons of comparison, we also report the average contribution of costs to price formation in the Greek economy.
From the results reported in Table 1, it follows that Profits have the highest contribution in the formation of energy prices, while Profits and total Imports form almost 70% of energy prices. In comparison with the price formation in the rest of the Greek economy, we notice the relatively higher importance of Profits and Extra EU imports and the relatively lower contribution of Wages, Net taxes and EU imports in the formation of energy prices.

3.2. The Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices per Industry of Origin

Next, we estimate the contribution of costs to price formation per industry of origin of the primary inputs. Our estimations are based on the calculation of the matrix of the direct and indirect contribution of the primary inputs of each industry to the price formation of the net output of the energy sector and we focus on the column of the matrix that corresponds to the energy sector. Our results are reported in Figure 1.
From the results reported in Figure 1, it follows that the primary inputs of the energy sector form about 55.6% of the energy prices, while the rest of the costs come from primary inputs of the rest of the industries of the Greek economy. The other industries that contribute substantially to the formation of energy prices are “Mining and quarrying” (16.4%), “Coke and refined petroleum products” (9.7%), “Real estate activities” (7.1%), and “Financial service activities” (1.9%).

3.3. The Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices per Primary Input Cost and Industry of Origin

Next, we estimate the contribution of costs to energy price formation per primary input cost and industry of origin, by estimating the matrices of the contribution of costs to price formation per primary input cost and industry of origin in the Greek economy. We focus on the primary inputs costs found to mostly contribute to the formation of energy prices, i.e., Wages, Profits, Consumption of fixed capital, and Extra EU imports. The findings of our estimations are reported in Figure 2.
From the results reported in Figure 2, it follows that, on the one hand, the costs for Wages, Profits and Consumption of fixed capital that form the energy prices mainly come from the energy sector itself. On the other hand, the costs for Extra EU imports that form energy prices mainly concern “Mining and quarrying” (65.9%), “Coke and refined petroleum products” (17.4%), while direct energy imports from non-EU countries have a share of only 7.3% in the costs of Extra EU imports that form energy prices. Another noticeable industry in the formation of energy prices is the “Real estate activities”, which contribute about 8.0% of the profits and about 22.2% of the consumption of fixed capital that forms energy prices.

3.4. The Contribution of the Energy Sector to the Price Formation of the Other Industries Products

As the various industries of the economy contribute to the formation of energy prices, the energy sector also contributes to the formation of the prices of the other industries. Thus, for reasons of completeness, it is important to additionally estimate how the primary inputs costs of the energy sector affect the price formation of the other industries; this estimation can be based on the calculation of the matrix of the direct and indirect contribution of the primary inputs of each industry to the price formation of the net output of a particular industry. Instead of focusing on the 24th column of this matrix, we now concentrate on its 24th row which gives the direct and indirect contribution of the primary inputs of the energy sector to the price formation of the net output of the other industries of the Greek economy. Our estimations reveal that the energy sector contributes on average about 2.1% in the price formation of the other industries of the Greek economy. In Table 2, we report the industries in which the energy sector contributes more than its average contribution.
From the results reported in Table 2, it follows that the highest contribution of the energy sector in the price formation of the products of other industries refers to the “Sewerage; waste collection, treatment and disposal activities; materials recovery; remediation activities and other waste management services” (9.4%), “Water collection, treatment and supply” (8.1%) and “Manufacture of basic metals” (8.0%). Thus, we notice that the most significant contribution of the energy sector to the price formation of other industries mainly concerns industrial sectors of the Greek economy.
In a nutshell, the results of the supply and use model highlight the intricate nature of the interrelationships which shape the energy prices. In particular, it is verified that the influence of the input costs reflects the net outcome of the sell and purchase transactions among several different sectors of the economy with varying degrees of contribution to the prices of the energy sector. Besides, there is a varying impact of energy on the input cost requirements of the other industries of the economy. Therefore, the findings underline the need to employ SUT’s to analyze more esoteric issues and obtain insights into the suitability of policies to manage the green transition, energy cost and its impact on other industries and the total economy.

4. Discussion and Conclusions

In this paper, we developed a method to estimate the contribution of primary inputs costs to the net outputs of the various industries of a national economy through a supply and use model; this method captures the direct and indirect contribution of each primary input to the price formation in all industries of the economy. Furthermore, the usage of data from the Supply and Use Tables, instead of the traditional input-output tables, allows us to avoid the restrictive assumptions involved in the conversion methods that transform the Supply and Use Tables into Symmetric Input-Output Tables. On the empirical side, we used more recent (compared to the Symmetric Input-Output Tables) data from the Supply and Use Tables of the Greek economy for the year 2018 (the latest available data at the time of this research). The analysis was principally focused on the estimation of the contribution of primary inputs costs in the formation of energy prices.
Our empirical results revealed that the energy prices in the Greek economy are mostly formed by Profits and Imports. The Profits that form energy prices are mainly distributed to the energy sector itself (about 86.4%). The Imports largely concern Extra EU imports of “Mining and quarrying products” and “Coke and refined petroleum products”. Another industry of the Greek economy that has a noticeable contribution to the formation of energy prices is “Real estate activities”, which contributes to about 8.0% of the profits and about 22.2% of the consumption of fixed capital that form energy prices. As far as the contribution of the energy sector to the price formation of the other industries of the Greek economy is concerned, the energy sector mainly contributes to the price formation of industrial sectors. The highest contribution is identified in the industries “Sewerage; waste collection, treatment and disposal activities; materials recovery; remediation activities and other waste management services” (9.4%), “Water collection, treatment and supply” (8.1%) and “Manufacture of basic metals” (8.0%).
These results are in line with the findings of Lychnaras et al. [28] and Rodousakis and Soklis [29] regarding the intersectoral linkages of the Greek energy sector. More specifically, based on an extended version of the hypothetical extraction method proposed by Dietzenbacher and van der Linden [30] and data originating from the Symmetric Input-Output Tables of the Greek economy for the year 2015, Lychnaras et al. [28] found that the Greek energy sector mostly relies on buying inputs from the industries “Mining and quarrying products” and “Coke and refined petroleum products”. Besides, Rodousakis and Soklis [29] found that the industry that mostly depends on the energy sector for the purchase of inputs is the industry “Sewerage; waste collection, treatment and disposal activities; materials recovery; remediation activities and other waste management services”.
Since energy prices have risen dramatically during the previous months and policy authorities struggle to take sufficient measures to contain energy prices, the proposed methodology and empirical results in this study could be relevant and important. More specifically, our results for the formation of energy prices in the Greek economy indicate that a policy to contain them could be mainly based on the implementation of income and import substitution policies.
On the short run, the relatively high share of profits distributed to the energy sector that form energy prices indicates that an income policy which would limit excessive profits could have significant positive effects on the containment of energy prices; this policy would be particularly beneficial for the competitiveness of the industries in which the energy sector has a relatively high contribution in the price formation of their products, i.e., “Sewerage; waste collection, treatment and disposal activities; materials recovery; remediation activities and other waste management services”, “Water collection, treatment and supply” and “Manufacture of basic metals”; it is worth noting that the implementation of such a policy has recently been proposed by the UN Secretary-General, who declared that “The combined profits of the largest energy companies in the first quarter of this year are close to $100 billion. I urge governments to tax these excessive profits, and use the funds to support the most vulnerable people through these difficult times” [31]. On the long run, an import substitution policy towards the exploitation of domestic mining and quarrying products as well as the coke and refined petroleum products could have a significantly positive impact, not only on the retainment of energy prices, but also on the increase in the energy security of the country.
Finally, it should be noted that, similar to all the traditional input-output analyses, the proposed model assumes fixed structures in the inter-industry relationships. Moreover, since the data about the structure of the Greek economy are derived from the Supply and Use Tables for the year 2018, the analysis does not capture possible changes due to structural reforms that occurred in the latest years through the implementation of decarbonatization policies in the Greek energy sector. Thus, future research efforts could employ more recent (when available) datasets and possible extensions of the proposed methodological framework to consider the dynamics of energy price formation mechanisms, including various types of investment/financial flows and exogenous shocks. Given the availability of more refined data at the sectoral level, the analysis could also focus on the prices of different types of activities and sources of energy, such as those related to lignite, natural gas and renewable energy sources. Additionally, the inclusion of information about different countries by use of inter-country input-output data [32,33,34,35,36] could further contribute to the current knowledge, by providing insights not only into the inter-industry relationships, but also into the inter-country relationships among industries.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, N.R., G.S. and T.T.; methodology, N.R., G.S. and T.T; formal analysis, N.R., G.S. and T.T; writing—original draft preparation, N.R., G.S. and T.T; writing—review and editing, N.R., G.S. and T.T. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data for the Supply and Use Tables of the Greek economy were retrieved from the website of the Hellenic Statistical Authority (ELSTAT), www.statistics.gr.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Leontief, W. The Structure of the American Economy, 1919–1939; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 1951. [Google Scholar]
  2. Leontief, W. Input-Output Economics, 2nd ed.; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 1986. [Google Scholar]
  3. Garganas, N.; Momferatos, P. Intersectoral Analysis of the Contribution of Cost to Price Formation in Greece; Bank of Greece: Athens, Greece, 1979. (In Greek) [Google Scholar]
  4. Mariolis, T.; Soklis, G. The contribution of primary inputs to price formation: An input-output analysis of the Greek economy. Greek Econ. Outlook 2020, 41, 101–118. [Google Scholar]
  5. Wu, R.H.; Chen, C.Y. On the application of input-output analysis to energy issues. Energy Econ. 1990, 12, 71–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Hawdon, D.; Pearson, P. Input-output simulations of energy, environment, economy interactions in the UK. Energy Econ. 1995, 17, 73–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Llop, M.; Pié, L. Input–output analysis of alternative policies implemented on the energy activities: An application for Catalonia. Energy Policy 2008, 36, 1642–1648. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Cellura, M.; Longo, S.; Mistretta, M. The energy and environmental impacts of Italian households consumptions: An input–output approach. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2011, 15, 3897–3908. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Markaki, M.; Belegri-Roboli, A.; Michaelides, P.; Mirasgedis, S.; Lalas, D.P. The impact of clean energy investments on the Greek economy: An input–output analysis (2010–2020). Energy Policy 2013, 57, 263–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. United Nations. Handbook of Input-Output Table Compilation and Analysis. Studies in Methods. Handbook of National Accounting; Series F, No. 74; United Nations, Department for Economic and Social Affairs, Statistics Division: New York, NY, USA, 1999. [Google Scholar]
  11. Eurostat. Eurostat Manual of Supply, Use and Input-Output Tables; Office for the Official Publications of the European Communities: Luxembourg, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  12. Soklis, G. The conversion of the supply and use tables to symmetric input-output tables: A critical review. Bull. Political Econ. 2009, 3, 51–70. [Google Scholar]
  13. Mariolis, T.; Rodousakis, N.; Soklis, G. Empirical Input-Output Representations and Transmutations of Actual Economies. In Spectral Theory of Value and Actual Economies; Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science; Springer: Singapore, 2021; Volume 24, pp. 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Steedman, I. L’ importance empirique de la production jointe. In La Production Jointe: Nouveaux Débats; Bidard, C., Ed.; Economica: Paris, France, 1984. [Google Scholar]
  15. Faber, M.; Proops, J.L.R.; Baumgärtner, S. All production is joint production. A thermodynamic analysis. In Sustainability and Firms: Technological Change and the Changing regulatory Environment; Faucheux, S., Cowdy, J., Nikolaï, I., Eds.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 1998. [Google Scholar]
  16. Kurz, H.D. Classical and Early Neoclassical Economists on Joint Production. Metroeconomica 1986, 38, 1–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Huang, Z.; Liao, G.; Li, Z. Loaning scale and government subsidy for promoting green innovation. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2019, 144, 148–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Li, Z.; Zou, F.; Mo, B. Does mandatory CSR disclosure affect enterprise total factor productivity? Econ. Res. -Ekon. Istraživanja 2021, 35, 4902–4921. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Li, Z.; Huang, Z.; Failler, P. Dynamic correlation between crude oil price and investor sentiment in China: Heterogeneous and asymmetric effect. Energies 2022, 15, 687. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Hong, M.; Wang, X.; Li, Z. Will oil price volatility cause market panic? Energies 2022, 15, 4629. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Liu, Y.; Li, Z.; Xu, M. The influential factors of financial cycle spillover: Evidence from China. Emerg. Mark. Financ. Trade 2020, 56, 1336–1350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Liu, Y.; Liu, S.; Xu, X.; Failler, P. Does energy price induce China’s green energy innovation? Energies 2020, 13, 4034. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Liu, Y.; Failler, P.; Peng, J.; Zheng, Y. Time-varying relationship between crude oil price and exchange rate in the context of structural breaks. Energies 2020, 13, 2395. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Li, T.; Li, X.; Liao, G. Business cycles and energy intensity. Evidence from emerging economies. Borsa Istanb. Rev. 2022, 22, 560–570. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Huang, Z.; Dong, H.; Jia, S. Equilibrium pricing for carbon emission in response to the target of carbon emission peaking. Energy Econ. 2022, 112, 106160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Miller, R.; Blair, P. Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions; Prentice Hall: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 1985. [Google Scholar]
  27. Bidard, C. Prix, Reproduction, Rareté; Dunod: Paris, France, 1991. [Google Scholar]
  28. Lychnaras, V.; Rodousakis, N.; Soklis, G. The two Sides of the Energy Crisis in the Greek Economy: Part A (In Greek), Centre of Planning and Economic Research (KEPE), Current Analysis 6/2021. 2021. Available online: https://www.kepe.gr/images/Aναλύσεις_Επικαιρότητας_6-2021.pdf (accessed on 14 August 2022).
  29. Rodousakis, N.; Soklis, G. The Two Sides of the Energy Crisis in the Greek Economy: Part B (In Greek), Centre of Planning and Economic Research (KEPE), Current Analysis 1/2022. 2022. Available online: https://www.kepe.gr/images/Aναλύσεις_Επικαιρότητας_1-2022.pdf (accessed on 14 August 2022).
  30. Dietzenbacher, E.; van der Linden, J.A. Sectoral and spatial linkages in the EC production structure. J. Reg. Sci. 1997, 37, 235–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. United Nations. Available online: https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment/blog/2022/08/calling-record-profits-from-oil-and-gas-amid-global-energy-crisis-immoral-un-secretary-general-urges-support-to-most-vulnerable-and-transition-to-renewables/ (accessed on 14 August 2022).
  32. Moran, D.; Wood, R. Convergence between the Eora, WIOD, EXIOBASE, and OpenEU’s consumption-based carbon accounts. Econ. Syst. Res. 2014, 26, 245–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Akizu-Gardoki, O.; Bueno, G.; Wiedmann, T.; Lopez-Guede, J.M.; Arto, I.; Hernandez, P.; Moran, D. Decoupling between human development and energy consumption within footprint accounts. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 202, 1145–1157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Chen, G.Q.; Wu, X.D.; Guo, J.; Meng, J.; Li, C. Global overview for energy use of the world economy: Household-consumption-based accounting based on the world input-output database (WIOD). Energy Econ. 2019, 81, 835–847. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Yamano, N.; Guilhoto, J. CO2 Emissions Embodied in International Trade and Domestic Final Demand: Methodology and Results Using the OECD Inter-Country Input-Output Database. OECD Science; Technology and Industry Working Papers No. 2020/11; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  36. Li, W.; Wang, A.; Wang, X. Review on the input-output network and its application in energy and mineral industries. Front. Energy Res. 2022, 10, 1429. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The contribution of costs to energy prices per industry of origin.
Figure 1. The contribution of costs to energy prices per industry of origin.
Energies 15 06878 g001
Figure 2. The Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices per Primary Input Cost and Industry of Origin: (a) Wages; (b) Profits; (c) Consumption of fixed capital; (d) Extra EU imports.
Figure 2. The Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices per Primary Input Cost and Industry of Origin: (a) Wages; (b) Profits; (c) Consumption of fixed capital; (d) Extra EU imports.
Energies 15 06878 g002aEnergies 15 06878 g002b
Table 1. The contribution of costs to Energy prices.
Table 1. The contribution of costs to Energy prices.
Type of CostEnergyEconomy’s Average
Wages16.4%26.9%
Profits36.9%20.5%
Net taxes3.5%10.3%
Consumption of fixed capital10.8%9.6%
EU imports9.7%18.4%
Extra EU imports22.8%14.3%
Note: The percentages may not add up to 100% due to rounding.
Table 2. The contribution of the Energy sector to the price formation of the other industries.
Table 2. The contribution of the Energy sector to the price formation of the other industries.
IndustriesEnergy Sector Contribution
Sewerage; waste collection, treatment and disposal activities9.4%
Water collection, treatment and supply8.1%
Manufacture of basic metals8.0%
Sports activities and amusement and recreation activities4.1%
Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products3.0%
Warehousing and support activities for transportation2.9%
Social work activities2.8%
Manufacture of electrical equipment2.7%
Activities of membership organisations2.4%
Average2.1%
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Rodousakis, N.; Soklis, G.; Tsekeris, T. A Supply and Use Model for Estimating the Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices. Energies 2022, 15, 6878. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15196878

AMA Style

Rodousakis N, Soklis G, Tsekeris T. A Supply and Use Model for Estimating the Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices. Energies. 2022; 15(19):6878. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15196878

Chicago/Turabian Style

Rodousakis, Nikolaos, George Soklis, and Theodore Tsekeris. 2022. "A Supply and Use Model for Estimating the Contribution of Costs to Energy Prices" Energies 15, no. 19: 6878. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15196878

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop