Survey-Based Assessment of the Preferences in Residential Demand Response on the Island of Mayotte
Abstract
:1. Introduction
1.1. Background and Motivation
- Balance between loss of control and gain of comfort in direct load control (DLC) schemes: DLC refers to a DR scheme, in which electrical household appliances/devices—popular examples being water heaters, air conditioners (ACs), and electric heaters—are remotely controlled by the respective scheme provider in direction of the desired load shift, rewarded with a predefined remuneration [14]. DLC programs have gained greater attention due to their advantages of accurateness of estimate in flexible load and ease of reducing peak loads [14]. However, as participants in DLC programs give up some control over a household appliance or device, a common barrier towards participation in such schemes is the sense of losing control, even though gaining comfort through avoided actions [15]. Dütschke et al. [16] validate findings from a survey in a real laboratory test, finding participants to prefer preferred automatic DR to manual changes of electricity consumption [16]. Paetz et al. [17] come to the same conclusion, striking out the value of intelligent control systems to save time and maintain comfort [17]. Fell et al. [15] take up the link of such technologies to ease of use. Users frequently being absent from their homes might be attracted by automatic control schemes [18]. However, evidence on perceived drawbacks is also abundant. The installation of new technologies may deter from signing up for a DLC program [19,20], as may associated costs [21], space requirements [22], or installation itself [22,23]. Many of the abovementioned work points back to the popular information deficit model [24], which implies that lacking visibility of the current electricity price may lead to a loss of awareness over personal energy consumption behavior—and vice versa.
- Devices/appliances applicable for DR schemes: The acceptance of DLC may vary with the type of device/appliance included in the scheme [25]. A prominent assumption states that such devices/appliances are preferably shifted, to which the least routines are bound to [13]. The assumption can be confirmed by evidence found in literature. Yilmaz et al. found from a survey amongst 622 households in Switzerland, that participants most likely agree with heat pumps, boilers battery and PV to be controlled remotely, while dishwasher and washing machine shows low acceptance [26]. Ghanem et al. present evidence from a similar survey on the islands of La Graciosa (Spain), San Pietro (Italy), Aran Islands (Ireland), which indicate the washing machine, PV and battery to be largely accepted for DLC programs, while responses to EV were strikingly heterogeneous [4]. Shifting demand from wet goods, however, in some case studies raise concerns regarding noise, quality of laundry, and safety [21,27,28]. However, as with associated routines the acceptance of DLC for certain devices/appliances may vary according to the socio-demographic background of the respondents [26,28]. Particularly important in the considered setting of the present study, Xu et al. distinguish between DLC programs for AC to be remotely curtailed or switched-on (switch program), and AC to be controlled in a temperature range. Noticeably, the automatic switch program was significantly more preferred in a survey conducted in California [14]. The option to override the contract was indicated as more convincing to participate in the scheme than monetary compensation [14]. The idea of temperature range control is supported by Alimohammadisagvand for the northern hemisphere, who suggests controlled heat pumps to adjust the temperature range of residential heating in Finland [29] to minimize electricity costs [30].
- The issue of trust: Issues of trust can arise from technical issues in the associated technologies [31], lack of transparency in the DR scheme [27,31], the function of the overall energy market [32], or concerns about the entity providing the scheme [17,25]. Noticeably, this issue may be difficult to transfer to island systems, considering the often vertically integrated structure of utilities and small scale of the system.
- Tariff design: As a bounding bridge between technology, economics, and acceptance of DR schemes, designing attractive tariffs is crucial for the uptake of DR schemes [33]. Previous work has assessed the preference for different tariffs. An extensive overview of studies analyzing the acceptance of time-of-use tariffs can be found in Nicolson et al. [33]. Dynamic tariffs—mostly due to the high perceived involvement of the user—turn out to be less favored [15,26,34]. In addition, power tariffs experience low support [26,33]. Bonus tariffs in contrast are shown to be more interesting to survey participants in Yilmaz et al. [26]. The interest in tariffs, however, might be influenced by the socio-demographic background of the sample population [26]. Even though anticipated interest in tariffs may be high in most analyses, the actual change of consumer behavior and consumption in response to price signals varies across previous studies. The authors of [35,36,37,38] show evidence that demonstrates a permanent change in consumption patterns of users. However, many researchers argue DLC programs allow for a more reliable shift in consumption patterns, reducing uncertainty for the grid operator [25,39,40].
- Consumer motivations for demand response: Analysis addressing why residential electricity customers might choose to participate in DR schemes has identified numerous motivations, with financial and environmental benefits being the most prominent ones [14,19,27,32]. The actual purpose behind it—that is to increase electricity system reliability—has been found to be additional motivation [22], however, with high heterogeneity [4]. Noticeably, [41] find social benefits as another dimension of motivation, i.e., the pride of discussing participation with neighbors or being a role model for children. The major motivation might be closely linked to the question of preferred remuneration. While monetary remuneration is common practice, alternative remuneration schemes such as coupons have been proposed by researchers [42].
1.2. Research Contribution and Ambition
- To evaluate the overall interest in residential DR participation;
- To identify key drivers/main motivation for the participation in residential DR schemes;
- To discover how socio-demographics influence the key drivers for participation and preferences in compensation/remuneration;
- To identify distinct DR preferences (acceptance of DLC of individual electrical devices and appliances, interest in tariffs);
- To identify socio-demographic predictors for preferences in DLC and electricity tariffs;
- To explore the effect of overriding DR contracts on the willingness to participate.
2. Materials and Methods
2.1. Case Study of Mayotte
2.2. Survey
2.2.1. Independent Variables
2.2.2. Dependent Variables
- Acceptance of DLC: The respondents were asked to indicate with “yes”, “no”, or “maybe” for each device/appliance included in Table 2 whether they would allow the device to be controlled remotely by a third party. For AC, the question distinguished between controlling the AC in a temperature range of three degrees only and a total curtailment or start-up.
- Interest in tariffs: The respondents were asked to indicate their level of interest in different tariff types based on a five-point Likert scale. The respective tariffs were explained in an exemplary sentence listed in Table 3 and explicitly phrased close to the wording of Yilmaz et al. [26] to allow for later comparison.
- Main motivation to participating in a DR scheme: Asking “What is your main motivation for participating in such a program” the respondents were confronted to choose between monetary savings, the motivation to promote the energy transition, to be a pioneer in the neighborhood or to have a community project within the neighborhood as the main driver for their participation. The different options at first had to be evaluated on a 5-point Likert scale ranking before validating the answers in a comprehending question on the most important motivation of the aforementioned.
- Desired remuneration: Asking for the desired type of remuneration respondents could indicate monetary compensation, vouchers for leisure events such as movie tickets or home entertainment subscriptions, or the possibility of a third party beautifying the local neighborhood.
3. Results
3.1. Acceptance of Direct Load Control
3.1.1. Descriptive Statistics of DLC Acceptance
3.1.2. Socio-Demographics and DLC Acceptance
3.2. Interest in Tariffs
3.2.1. Descriptive Statistics of Interest in Tariffs
3.2.2. Socio-Demographics and Interests in Electricity Tariffs
3.3. Clusters of Demand Response Preference
3.3.1. Cluster Analysis
3.3.2. Predicting Clusters Based on Socio-Demographic Characters
3.4. Main Motivation for Participation in Residential Demand Response
3.4.1. Descriptive Statistics of Main Motivation to Participate in Residential Demand Response
3.4.2. Socio-Demographics and Main Motivation
3.5. Preferences in Remuneration
3.5.1. Descriptive Statistics of Preferences in Remuneration
3.5.2. Socio-Demographics and Interest in Remuneration
3.6. Timing of Notification
3.6.1. Descriptive Statistics of Preferred Timing of Notification
3.6.2. Socio-Demographics and Time of Notification
4. Discussion
5. Conclusions
- Explore the contemporary level of awareness and knowledge on DR, electricity supply, and climate change within the community, respecting potential differences across age groups;
- Assess the ability and willingness to pay for DR schemes, to exclude non-affordable (as cost-intensive for the user) DR schemes from further consideration;
- Explore the possibilities for alternative remunerations than monetary compensation on Mayotte.
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- European Union. 2050 Long-Term Strategy. European Union. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/strategies/2050_en (accessed on 7 September 2021).
- Scandurra, G.; Romano, A.A.; Ronghi, M.; Carfora, A. On the vulnerability of Small Island Developing States: A dynamic analysis. Ecol. Indic. 2018, 84, 382–392. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kotzebue, J.R.; Weissenbacher, M. The EU’s Clean Energy strategy for islands: A policy perspective on Malta’s spatial governance in energy transition. Energy Policy 2020, 139, 111361. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ghanem, D.A.; Crosbie, T. The Transition to Clean Energy: Are People Living in Island Communities Ready for Smart Grids and Demand Response? Energies 2021, 14, 6218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ioannidis, A.; Chalvatzis, K.J.; Li, X.; Notton, G.; Stephanides, P. The case for islands’ energy vulnerability: Electricity supply diversity in 44 global islands. Renew. Energy 2019, 143, 440–452. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gils, H.C.; Simon, S. Carbon neutral archipelago—100% renewable energy supply for the Canary Islands. Appl. Energ. 2017, 188, 342–355. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kuang, Y.; Zhang, Y.; Zhou, B.; Li, C.; Cao, Y.; Li, L.; Zeng, L. A review of renewable energy utilization in islands. Renew. Sust. Energ. Rev. 2016, 59, 504–513. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zafirakis, D.; Chalvatzis, K.J. Wind energy and natural gas-based energy storage to promote energy security and lower emissions in island regions. Fuel 2014, 115, 203–219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- IRENA. Power System Flexibility for the Energy Transition—Part 1: Overview for Policy Makers; IRENA: Bonn, Germany, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- IRGC. Demand Side Flexibility for Energy Transitions—Ensuring the Competitive Development of Demand Response Options; International Risk Governance Council: Lausanne, Switzerland, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Albadi, M.H.; El-Saadany, E.F. A summary of demand response in electricity markets. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2008, 78, 1989–1996. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schot, J.; Kanger, L.; Verbing, G. The roles of users in shaping transitions to new energy systems. Nat. Energy 2016, 1, 16054. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Christensen, T.H.; Friis, F.; Bettin, S.; Throndsen, W.; Ornetzeder, M.; Skjølsvold, T.M.; Ryghaug, M. The role of competences, engagement, and devices in configuring the impact of prices in energy demand response: Findings from three smart energy pilots with households. Energy Policy 2019, 137, 111142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xu, X.; Chen, C.; Zhu, X.; Hu, Q. Promoting acceptance of direct load control programs in the United States: Financial incentive versus control option. Energy 2018, 147, 1278–1287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fell, M.J.; Shipworth, D.; Huebner, G.M.; Elwell, C.A. Public acceptability of domestic demand-side response in Great Britain: The role of automation and direct load control. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2015, 9, 72–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dütschke, E.; Paetz, A.G. Dynamic electricity pricing—Which programs do consumers prefer? Energy Policy 2013, 59, 226–234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Paetz, A.G.; Dütschke, E.; Fichtner, W. Smart Homes as a Means to Sustainable Energy Consumption: A Study of Consumer Perceptions. J. Consum. Policy 2012, 35, 23–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lebosse, C. Grid4EU DEMO6—dD6.8-1 Assessment of the Social Behaviour of the Residential Customers after on Site Tests; Grid4EU: Paris, France, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- AECOM. Energy Demand Research Project: Final Analysis; AECOM for Ofgem: Herfordshire, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Parrish, B.; Heptonstall, P.; Gross, R.; Sovacoo, B.K. A systematic review of motivations, enablers and barriers for consumer engagement with residential demand response. Energy Policy 2020, 138, 111221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Belmans, R.; Beusen, B.; Boesmans, B.; Cardinaels, W.; Claessens, B.; Claessens, S.; Coomans, P.; D’hulst, R.; De Meyer, W.; Degraeve, J.; et al. Linear—The Report; The Linear Consortium: Genk, Belgium, 2014.
- Bird, J. Developing the Smarter Grid: The Role of Domestic and Small and Medium Enterprise Customers; Customer-Led Network Revolution: Newcastle, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Hall, N.L.; Jeanneret, T.D.; Rai, A. Cost-reflective electricity pricing: Consumer preferences and perceptions. Energy Policy 2016, 95, 62–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hargreaves, T.; Nye, M.; Burgess, J. Making energy visible: A qualitative field study of how householders interact with feedback from smart energy monitors. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 6111–6119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stenner, K.; Frederiks, E.R.; Hobman, E.V.; Cook, S. Willingness to participate in direct load control: The role of consumer distrust. Appl. Energ. 2018, 189, 76–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yilmaz, S.; Xu, X.; Cabrera, D.; Chanez, C.; Cuony, P.; Patel, M.K. Analysis of demand-side response preferences regarding electricity tariffs and direct load control: Key findings from a Swiss survey. Energy 2020, 212, 118217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Carmichael, R.; Schofield, J.; Woolf, M.; Bilton, M.; Ozaki, R.; Strbac, G. Residential Consumer Attitudes to Time-Varying Pricing; Imperial College London: London, UK, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Friis, F.; Haunstrup Christensen, T. The challenge of time shifting energy demand practices: Insights from Denmark. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2016, 19, 124–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alimohammadisagvand, B. Influence of Demand Response Actions on Thermal Comfort and Electricity Cost for Residential Houses. Ph.D. Thesis, Department of Mechanical Engineeering, Aalto University, Espoo, Finland, 2018. Available online: https://aaltodoc.aalto.fi/handle/123456789/33143 (accessed on 2 February 2022).
- Alimohammadisagvand, B.; Jokisalo, J.; Sirén, K. The potential of predictive control in minimizing the electricity cost in a heat-pump heated residential house. In Proceedings of the 3rd IBPSA-England Conference, BSO 2016, Newcastle, UK, 12–14 September 2016; Available online: http://www.ibpsa.org/proceedings/BSO2016/p1049.pdf (accessed on 2 February 2022).
- Wiekens, C.J.; van-Grootel, M.; Steinmeijer, S. Experiences and Behaviours of End-Users in a Smart Grid: The Influence of Values, Attitudes, Trust, and Several Types of Demand Side Management. In Proceedings of the BEHAVE2014—Behavior and Energy Efficiency Conference, Oxford, UK, 3–4 September 2014; Available online: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/270586399_EXPERIENCES_AND_BEHAVIORS_OF_END-USERS_IN_A_SMART_GRID_THE_INFLUENCE_OF_VALUES_ATTITUDES_TRUST_AND_SEVERAL_TYPES_OF_DEMAND_SIDE_MANAGEMENT (accessed on 2 February 2022).
- Torstensson, D.; Wallin, F. Potential and barriers for demand response at household customers. Energy Procedia 2015, 75, 1189–1196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Nicolson, M.L.; Fell, M.J.; Huebner, G.M. Consumer demand for time of use electricity tariffs: A systematized review of the empirical evidence. Renew. Sust. Energ. Rev. 2018, 97, 276–289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Todd, A.; Cappers, P.; Goldman, C.A. Residential Customer Enrollment in Time-Based Rate and Enabling Technology Programs: Smart Grid Investment Grant Consumer Behavior Study Analysis; Ernest Orlando Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory: Berkely, CA, USA, 2013.
- Faruqui, A.; Sergici, S. Arcturus: International Evidence on Dynamic Pricing. Electr. J. 2013, 26, 55–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Newsham, G.R.; Bowker, B.G. The effect of utility time-varying pricing and load control strategies on residential summer peak electricity use: A review. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 3289–3296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Voulis, N.; van Etten, M.; Chappin, E.; Warnier, M.; Brazier, F. Rethinking European energy taxation to incentivise consumer demand response participation. Energy Policy 2019, 124, 156–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yilmaz, S.; Weber, S.; Patel, M.K. Who is sensitive to DSM? Understanding the determinants of the shape of electricity load curves and demand shifting: Socio-demographic characteristics, appliance use and attitudes. Energy Policy 2019, 133, 110909. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ericson, T. Direct load control of residential water heaters. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 3502–3512. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- He, X.; Keyaerts, N.; Azevedoa, I.; Meeus, L.; Hancher, L.; Glachant, J.M. How to engage consumers in demand response: A contract perspective. Util. Policy 2013, 27, 108–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Western Power Distribution. SoLa Bristol SDRC 9.8 Final Report; Western Power Distribution: Bristol, UK, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Zhong, H.; Xie, L.; Xia, Q. Coupon Incentive-Based Demand Response: Theory and Case Study. IEEE Transactions on Power Systems 2013, 28, 1266–1276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Darby, S.; Mckenna, E. Social implications of residential demand response in cool temperate climates. Energy Policy 2012, 49, 759–769. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Global Solar Atlas. Mayotte. Available online: https://globalsolaratlas.info/map?s=-12.823048,45.152076&m=site&c=-12.823048,45.152076,11 (accessed on 4 January 2022).
- Farré, M.; Genest, O.; González Cuadrado, L.; Heylen, E.; Andolšek, A.; Gutschi, C.; Peiffer, N.; Sonvilla, P.; Varo López, J.; González Reed, P.; et al. MAESHA-D1.1 Use-Cases Requirements and KPIs Definition; Trialog: Paris, France, 2021. [Google Scholar]
Topic | Research Question | Survey Questions | Answer Options |
---|---|---|---|
DLC | How is the acceptance of DLC? | How likely would you be to participate in a demand response program? | Answers based on a Likert scale of 1 to 5 (1 = “Not at all likely”… 5 = “Very likely”) |
Which kind of devices/appliances are preferred for DLC? | Which devices/appliances would you be willing to control remotely? | Answer possibilities as indicated in Table 2. | |
Does the option to override the contract influence the acceptance of DLC? | To what extent do you think your answers would change to ‘yes’ if you had a weekly option to pause the contract? | Answers based on a Likert scale of 1 to 5 (1 = “Not at all likely” … 5 = “Very likely”) | |
Tariffs | How interested are you in the following tariffs? | Options presented in Table 3. | Answers based on a Likert scale of 1 to 5 (1 = “Not interested at all”… 5 = “Very interested”) |
What is the desired time-ahead of notification for price signals? | How many hours in advance would you like to receive a notification ahead to any price signals? | 2 h, 4 h, 6 h, 8 h | |
Major motivation | What is the major motivation to participate in DR schemes? | To what extent can you identify with the following statements:
| Answers based on a Likert scale of 1 to 5 (1 = “Completely disagree”… 5 = “Highly agree”) |
What is your main motivation for participating in a DR program? |
| ||
What kind of remuneration is desired? | To what extent can you identify with the following statements:
| Answers based on a Likert scale of 1 to 5 (1 = “Completely disagree”… 5 = “Highly agree”) |
Variable | Frequency (%) |
---|---|
Socio-demographic variables | |
Age | |
13–24 | 22.6 |
25–34 | 14.4 |
35–44 | 23.3 |
45–54 | 15.1 |
55–64 | 13.7 |
65+ | 11 |
Gender | |
Male | 44.5 |
Female | 55.5 |
Other | 0 |
Employment status | |
Employed | 37.7 |
Entrepreneur | 2.7 |
Not employed (unemployed and housewife/-man) | 25.3 |
Student | 18.5 |
Retired | 12.3 |
Other | 3.4 |
Area of residence | |
Mamoudzou | 30.1 |
Dembeni | 38.4 |
Kani-Keli | 19.2 |
Other | 12.3 |
Household size | |
1 person | 4.1 |
2 persons | 34.9 |
3–4 persons | 45.9 |
5 and more persons | 15.1 |
Presence of children in the household | |
Yes | 61.6 |
No | 38.4 |
Average monthly household electricity bill | |
<EUR 80 | 19.2 |
EUR 80–150 | 71.9 |
EUR 150–250 | 7.5 |
>EUR 250 | 1.4 |
Average monthly household income | |
<EUR 1.000 | 54.8 |
EUR 1.000–2.400 | 20.5 |
EUR 2.400–3.800 | 20.5 |
EUR 3.800–5.500 | 4.1 |
>EUR 5.500 | 0 |
Dwelling characteristics | |
Tenure type | |
Rent | 54.1 |
Own | 45.9 |
Dwelling type | |
Apartment | 4.1 |
House | 95.9 |
Appliance ownership | |
Solar panel | 3.4 |
Battery storage | 0 |
Electric vehicle | 0 |
Air conditioning | 76.7 |
Electric boiler | 6.8 |
Dishwasher | 24.7 |
Washing machine | 95.9 |
Tumble dryer | 3.4 |
Number of valid responses | 146 |
Tariff Title | Explanation |
---|---|
Bonus tariff | The price per kWh is fixed at X ct/kWh throughout the year. However, if you use electricity when the supply is high and consumption is low (e.g., in the afternoon or in winter), the DR supplier pays you a bonus of X ct/kWh. |
Malus tariff | The price per kWh is fixed at X ct/kWh throughout the year. However, if you consume when the electricity supply is low and consumption is high (e.g., in the evening or in the summer), the DR system supplier charges you a penalty of X ct/kWh. |
Dynamic tariff | The price of your consumption is dynamic and therefore varies from hour to hour and from day to day. For example, the price is different between 8 and 9 a.m., between 10 and 11 a.m., etc. |
Power tariff | Your bill depends on the maximum power demand during the year, instead of on your consumption. For example, if in December you use your air conditioner, charge your electric car, and use other devices at the same time, your total electricity demand will be 20 kW and you will be charged 20 €. If you only demanded 10 kW, you would be charged 10 €. |
Progressive tariff | The first kWh consumed are cheaper than those above a certain threshold. For example, you pay 7 ct/kWh for the first 100 kWh and 12 ct/kWh above this threshold. |
Fixed tariff | Each customer chooses a tariff category and pays a fixed price. For example, the “average consumer with a fixed price” which corresponds to an average consumption of 4,500 kWh pays 900 € per year. In case of a higher consumption, he/she will be charged according to a higher category. |
Question Number | Purpose | Variables | Method |
---|---|---|---|
1. Clusters of DR interests | Identify and segment various DSR preferences | Overall interest in DR; interest in different DLC options; interest in six tariffs | k-means cluster analysis with Tukey’s post hoc test |
2. Predicting clusters | Investigate the determinants of the DSR preference patterns reflected in cluster membership |
| Multinomial logistic regression |
3. Socio-demographics and DLC? | Investigate how acceptance of DLC differs across socio-demographic groups |
| Chi-square |
4. Socio-demographics and interests in tariffs? | Investigate how interest in tariffs differs across socio-demographic groups |
| ANOVA |
5. Socio-demographics and key driver? | Investigate how the key driver/motivation differs across socio-demographic groups |
| ANOVA |
6. Desired remuneration and socio-demographic/dwelling characteristics | Detect patterns along socio-demographic and dwelling characteristics and desired remuneration |
| ANOVA |
7. Timing of notification and socio-demographics | Detect patterns along socio-demographic and dwelling characteristics and the desired timing of notification |
| Chi-square |
AC Switch-On/Curtailment | Water Boiler | Dishwasher | Dryer | |||||||||||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Professional situation | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | ||||||||
21.953 | 10 | 0.015 | 0.274 | |||||||||||||||||||||
No | Maybe | Yes | ||||||||||||||||||||||
C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | |||||||||||||||||||
Employed | 13 | 13.6 | 11 | 16.2 | 55 | 55 | ||||||||||||||||||
Business owner | 0 | 1 | 0 | 1.2 | 4 | 1.8 | ||||||||||||||||||
Unemployed | 10 | 9.1 | 11 | 10.9 | 16 | 17 | ||||||||||||||||||
Student | 11 | 6.7 | 10 | 8 | 6 | 12.4 | ||||||||||||||||||
Retired | 1 | 4.4 | 10 | 5.3 | 7 | 8.3 | ||||||||||||||||||
Other | 1 | 1.2 | 1 | 1.5 | 3 | 2.3 | ||||||||||||||||||
Area | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | ||||||||||||||||
17.423 | 6 | 0.008 | 0.244 | 18.922 | 6 | 0.004 | 0.255 | |||||||||||||||||
No | Maybe | Yes | No | Maybe | Yes | |||||||||||||||||||
C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | |||||||||||||
Mamoudzou | 13 | 10.8 | 20 | 13 | 11 | 20.2 | 19 | 15.1 | 4 | 7.5 | 21 | 21.4 | ||||||||||||
Dembeni | 12 | 13.8 | 13 | 16.5 | 31 | 25.7 | 17 | 19.2 | 17 | 9.6 | 22 | 27.2 | ||||||||||||
Kani-Keli | 5 | 6.9 | 4 | 8.2 | 19 | 12.8 | 6 | 9.6 | 1 | 4.8 | 21 | 13.6 | ||||||||||||
Other | 6 | 4.4 | 6 | 5.3 | 6 | 8.3 | 8 | 6.2 | 3 | 3.1 | 7 | 8.8 | ||||||||||||
Owner vs. tenant | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | ||||||||||||||||
6.853 | 2 | 0.033 | 0.217 | 6.217 | 2 | 0.045 | 0.206 | |||||||||||||||||
No | Maybe | Yes | No | Maybe | Yes | |||||||||||||||||||
C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | |||||||||||||
Tenant | 25 | 19.5 | 25 | 23.3 | 29 | 36.3 | 7 | 12.4 | 5 | 4.3 | 67 | 62.2 | ||||||||||||
Owner | 11 | 16.5 | 18 | 19.7 | 38 | 30.7 | 16 | 10.6 | 3 | 3.7 | 48 | 52.8 | ||||||||||||
Presence of children | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | ||||||||||||||||||||
6.155 | 2 | 0.046 | 0.205 | |||||||||||||||||||||
No | Maybe | Yes | ||||||||||||||||||||||
C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | |||||||||||||||||||
Yes | 19 | 14.2 | 6 | 4.9 | 65 | 70.9 | ||||||||||||||||||
No | 14.2 | 8.8 | 2 | 3.1 | 50 | 44.1 | ||||||||||||||||||
Housing type | χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | ||||||||||||||||||||
6.598 | 2 | 0.037 | 0.213 | |||||||||||||||||||||
No | Maybe | Yes | ||||||||||||||||||||||
C | EC | C | EC | C | EC | |||||||||||||||||||
Apartment | 1 | 2.5 | 0 | 1.4 | 5 | 2.1 | ||||||||||||||||||
House | 60 | 58.5 | 34 | 32.6 | 46 | 48.9 |
Tariff | Indicator | Age | Professional Status | Children | Apartment vs. House | Income | Household Size |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Bonus | ANOVA F, Sig. | / | 6.634, <0.001 | ||||
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | / | Other vs. employed −1.372, <0.001 Other vs. business owner −1.350, 0.006 Other vs. unemployed −1.519, <0.001 Other vs. student −1.304, <0.001 Other vs. retired −1.433, <0.001 | |||||
Means, SD | / | Employed 4.73, 0.525 Business owner 4.75, 0.5 Unemployed 4.92, 0.277 Student 4.7, 0.609 Retired 4.83, 0.707 Other 3.4, 1.342 | |||||
Malus | ANOVA F, Sig. | 2.291, 0.049 | 7.078, <0.001 | 4.383, 0.038 | 15.811, <0.001 | / | |
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | / | Employed vs. business owner 1.295, <0.01 Employed vs. other 1.145, <0.012 Business owner vs. unemployed −1.507, 0.002 Business owner vs. retired 1.694, <0.001 Unemployed vs. other 1.357, 0.002 Retired vs. other 1.544, <0.001 | / | / | 2400–3800 vs. 1000–2400 0.567, 0.026 2400–3800 vs. 3800–5500 1.033, 0.017 | / | |
Mean, SD | 13–24: 4.24, 0.83 25–34: 4.33, 1.155 35–44: 4.59, 0.701 45–54: 4.73, 0.550 55–65: 4.88, 0.342 65+: 4.54, 0.798 | Employed 4.55, 0.741 Business owner 3.25, 2.062 Unemployed 4.76, 0.548 Student 4.37, 0.742 Retired 4.94, 0.236 Other 3.4, 1.140 | Yes 4.43, 0.862 No 4.71, 0.653 | Apartment 3.33, 1.633 House 4.59, 0.709 | <1000: 4.56, 0.709 1000–2400: 4.3, 1.088 2400–3800: 4.87, 0.346 3800–5500: 3.83, 1.169 | / | |
Dynamic | ANOVA F, Sig. | 3.709, 0.003 | 8.334, <0.001 | 5.850, 0.17 | 13.086, <0.001 | ||
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | 13–14 vs. 55–65: −0.839, Sig. 0.006 13–24 vs. 65+: −0.814, Sig. 0.19 | Employed vs. other 1.691, Sig. <0.001Business owner vs. other: 1.7, Sig. = 0.016 Unemployed vs. student: 0.643, Sig. = 0.016 Unemployed vs. other: 2.065, Sig. <0.001 Retired vs. student: 0.722, Sig. = 0.030 Retired vs. other: 2.144, Sig. <0.001 | / | / | |||
Means, SD | 13–24 M = 4.06, SD = 1.197 25–34 M = 4.67, SD = 0.577 35–44 M = 4.47, SD = 0.961 45–54 M = 4.64, SD = 0.658 55–65 M = 4.9, SD = 0.308 65+ M = 4.88, SD = 0.864 | Employed M = 4.49, SD = 0.814 Business owner M = 4.5, SD = 1 Unemployed M = 4.86, SD = 0.347 Student M = 4.22, SD = 1.121 Retired M = 4.94, SD =0.236 Other M = 2.8, SD = 1.304 | Yes M = 4.4, SD = 0.946, No M = 4.75, SD = 0.667 | Apartment M = 3.33, SD = 1.366 House M = 4.59, SD = 0.805 | |||
Capacity | ANOVA F, Sig. | 3.361, 0.007 | 3.361, 0.004 | 3.684, 0.057 * | |||
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | 13–24 vs. 45–54: −0.561, Sig. 0.033 13–24 vs. 55–65: −0.597, Sig. 0.025 13–24 vs. 65+: −0.634, Sig. 0.027 | Student vs. unemployed −0.532, Sig. 0.024 Student vs. retired: −0.611, Sig. = 0.036 | / | ||||
Means, SD | 13–24 M = 4.3, SD = 1.045 25–34 M = 4.67, SD = 0.483 35–44 M = 4.62, SD = 0.739 45–54 M = 4.86, SD = 0.351 55–65 M = 4.94, SD = 0.250 65+ M = 4.66, SD = 0.698 | Employed M = 4.862, SD = 0.615 Business owner M = 4.75, SD = 0.5 Unemployed M = 4.86, SD = 0.347 Student M = 4.33, SD = 1.074 Retired M = 4.94, SD = 0.236 Other M = 4.0, SD = 1.225 | Yes M = 4.58, SD = 0.779, No M = 4.8, SD = 0.698 | ||||
Fixed | ANOVA F, Sig. | 2.447, 0.037 | 12.791, <0.001 | 3.616, 0.015 | |||
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | / | / | 2 people compared to 5 people or more: 0.473, 0.034 | ||||
Means, SD | 13–24 M = 4.48, SD = 0.972 25–34 M = 4.25, SD = 0.750 35–44 M = 4.56, SD = 0.746 45–54 M = 4.86, SD = 0.351 55–65 M = 4.90, SD = 0.308 65+ M = 5.00, SD = 0.000 | Yes M = 4.52 SD = 0.824 No M = 4.93 SD = 0.260 | 1 person M = 5 SD = 0 2 people M = 4.88 SD = 0.51 3–4 people M = 4,58, SD = 0.67 5 people or more M = 4.41 SD = 0.02 | ||||
Progressive | ANOVA F, Sig. | 2.849, 0.018 | 6.230, <0.001 | 6.126, 0.014 | |||
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | 13–24 compared to 55–65 0.0617 and 0.033 and vice versa | Employed compared to other 1.055 and 0.014 and vice versa Unemployed compared to student 0.623 and 0.005 and vice versa Unemployed compared to other 0.319 and 0.001 and vice versa Student compared to retired −0.704 and 0.011 | / | ||||
Means, SD | 13–24 M = 4.33, SD = 0.99 25–34 M = 4.57, SD = 0.68 35–44 M = 4.59, SD = 0.89 45–54 M = 4.82, SD = 0.39 55–65 M = 4.95, SD = 0.22 65+ M = 4.94, SD = 0.25 | Employed M = 4.65 SD = 0.62 Business owner M = 4.25 SD = 0.96 Unemployed M = 4.92 SD = 0.36 Student M = 4.30 SD = 1.03 Retired M = 5.00 SD = 0.00 Other M = 3.60 SD = 1.52 | Yes M = 4.53 SD = 0.851 No M = 4.84 SD = 0.458 |
Feature | Cluster 1 | Cluster 2 | Cluster 3 | Cluster 4 |
---|---|---|---|---|
Percent of sample | 8.2 | 39 | 38.4 | 14.4 |
Name | moderate DLC, low tariff | Innovators | low DLC, high tariff | low DLC, moderate tariff |
Overall mean | 0.6 | 0.9 | 0.7 | 0.6 |
Interest in DLC | ||||
Interest in DLC mean | 0.62 | 0.86 | 0.55 | 0.44 |
PV | 0.958 | 0.877 | 0.688 | 0.643 |
Battery | 0.292 | 0.877 | 0.634 | 0.429 |
EV | 0.833 | 0.833 | 0.482 | 0.214 |
AC switch | 0.33 | 0.842 | 0.375 | 0.738 |
AC range | 1 | 0.78 | 0.661 | 0.714 |
Water boiler | 0.292 | 0.939 | 0.339 | 0.357 |
Dishwasher | 0.917 | 0.921 | 0.973 | 0.048 |
Dryer | 0.33 | 0.772 | 0.223 | 0.357 |
Interest in tariffs | ||||
Interest in tariffs mean | 0.59 | 0.93 | 0.97 | 0.86 |
Bonus | 0.792 | 0.936 | 0.982 | 0.881 |
Malus | 0.625 | 0.895 | 0.946 | 0.845 |
Dynamic | 0.458 | 0.908 | 0.978 | 0.81 |
Capacity | 0.563 | 0.947 | 0.969 | 0.893 |
Progressive | 0.479 | 0.952 | 0.982 | 0.869 |
Fix | 0.625 | 0.947 | 0.978 | 0.857 |
Parameter Estimation * | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Cluster Number of the Case * | Independent Variable | Std. Error | B | Significance (at alpha = 5%) | Odds Ratio |
1 | Intercept | 7.054 | 18.928 | 0.007 | |
Age | 0.450 | −1.572 | <0.001 | 0.208 | |
Gender | 0.866 | −0.861 | 0.32 | 0.423 | |
Professional situation | 0.330 | −0.339 | 0.305 | 0.713 | |
Area | 0.307 | 0.012 | 0.968 | 1.012 | |
Household size | 0.894 | −1.581 | 0.077 | 0.206 | |
Children | 1.459 | −2.953 | 0.043 | 0.052 | |
Tenant vs. Owner | 1.272 | 3.383 | 0.008 | 29.466 | |
Housing type Apartment vs. House | 2.077 | −5.335 | 0.01 | 0.005 | |
Electricity expenditure | 0.776 | 1.833 | 0.018 | 6.25 | |
Income | 0.925 | −2.536 | 0.006 | 0.079 | |
2 | Intercept | 3.610 | 1.307 | 0.717 | |
Age | 0.165 | −0.243 | 0.141 | 0.784 | |
Gender | 0.419 | 0.168 | 0.689 | 1.183 | |
Professional situation | 0.175 | −0.149 | 0.395 | 0.862 | |
Area | 0.172 | −0.383 | 0.026 | 0.682 | |
Household size | 0.355 | −0.379 | 0.286 | 0.684 | |
Children | 0.597 | −0.503 | 0.4 | 0.605 | |
Tenant vs. Owner | 0.541 | −0.46 | 0.395 | 0.631 | |
Housing type Apartment vs. House | 1.327 | 1.6 | 0.228 | 4.953 | |
Electricity expenditure | 0.448 | −0.051 | 0.909 | 0.95 | |
Income | 0.349 | −0.204 | 0.559 | 0.815 | |
3 | Intercept | 3.506 | −24.985 | <0.001 | |
Age | 0.278 | −0.752 | 0.007 | 0.471 | |
Gender | 0.633 | 0.57 | 0.368 | 1.768 | |
Professional situation | 0.304 | −0.517 | 0.089 | 0.596 | |
Area | 0.252 | −0.11 | 0.661 | 0.896 | |
Household size | 0.586 | −0.181 | 0.757 | 0.834 | |
Children | 1.047 | −1.738 | 0.097 | 0.176 | |
Tenant vs. Owner | 0.885 | 2.786 | 0.002 | 16.214 | |
Housing type Apartment vs. House | 0.000 | 13.904 | 1,092,175.375 | ||
Electricity expenditure | 0.609 | −0.432 | 0.478 | 0.649 | |
Income | 0.607 | −0.94 | 0.121 | 0.391 |
Motive | Indicator | Professional Status | Electricity Expenditure |
---|---|---|---|
Financial motive | ANOVA F, Sig. | 2.293, 0.049 | |
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | Student vs. retired −0.704, 0.031 | ||
Means, SD | Employed 4.67, 0.668 Business owner 4.5, 1 Unemployed 4.65, 0.824 Student 4.3, 0.912 Retired 5, 0 Other 4.2, 1.3 | ||
Motive energy transition | ANOVA F, Sig. | 4.217, 0.007 | |
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | <80 EUR/m vs. 80–150 EUR/m −0.379, 0.005 <80 EUR/m vs. 150–250EUR/m −0.464, 0.067 <80 EUR/m vs. >250 EUR/m −0.464, 0.623 | ||
Means, SD | <80 EUR/m 4.54, 0.999 80–150 EUR/m 4.91, = 0.343 150–250 EUR/m 5, 0 >250 EUR/m 4.85, 0.543 | ||
Motive neighborhood project | ANOVA F, Sig. | 3.537, 0.016 | |
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | < 80 EUR/m vs. 80–150 EUR/m −0.376, 0.015 | ||
Means, SD | <80 EUR/m 4.5, 1.106 80–150 EUR/m 4.88, 0.385 150–250 EUR/m 5, 0 >250 EUR/m 5, 0 | ||
Motive pioneer | ANOVA F, Sig. | 4.512, 0.005 | |
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | <80 EUR/m vs. 80–150 EUR/m −0.605, 0.003 | ||
Means, SD | <80 EUR/m 4.21, 1.424 80–150 EUR/m 4.82, 0.515 150–250 EUR/m 4.45, 1.036 >250 EUR/m 5, 0 |
Remuneration | Indicator | Professional Status | Household Size | Children | Electricity Expenditure | Age |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Voucher | ANOVA F, Sig. | 2.374, 0.042 | 4.663, 0.004 | 7.676, 0.006 | 5.966, <0.001 | |
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | Employed vs. other 0.982, 0.08 Retired vs. other 1.2, 0.031 | 2 vs. 5 0.694, 0.003 | <80 EUR/m vs. 80–150 EUR/m −0.517, 0.009 80–150 EUR/m vs. 150–250 EUR/m 0.747, 0.012 | |||
Means, SD | Employed 4.78, 0.712 Business owner 4.5, 1 Unemployed 4.65, 0.889 Student 4.52, 0.849 Retired 5, 0 Other 3.8, 1.304 | 1 4.33, 1.633 2 4.92, 0.440 3–4 4.69, 0.656 >5 4.23, 1.232 | Yes 4.54, 0.889 No 4.91, 0.549 | <80 EUR/m 4.32, 1.124 80–150 EUR/m 4.84, 0.502 150–250 EUR/m 4.09, 1.446 >250 EUR/m 5, 0 | ||
Neighborhood beautification | ANOVA F, Sig. | 4.495, 0.005 | 2.957, 0.014 | |||
Tukey’s HSD Mean I-J, Sig. | <80 EUR/m vs. 80–150 EUR/m −0,567, 0.002 | 13.24 vs. 35–44 −0.492, 0.077 13–24 vs. 55–56 −0.727, 0.009 | ||||
Means, SD | <80 EUR/m 4.21, 1.258 80–150 EUR/m 4.78, 0.537 150–250 EUR/m 4.64, 0.674 >250 EUR/m 5, 0 | 13–24 4.27, 1.069 25–34 4.62, 0.740 35–44 4.76, 0.496 45–54 4.77, 0.528 55–65 5, 0 65+ 4.66, 0.764 |
Timing of Notification Ahead | Housing Type | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
χ2 | df | p | Cramer’s V | |
9.281 | 3 | 0.026 | 0.252 | |
Apartment | House | |||
C | EC | C | EC | |
2 h | 0 | 0.9 | 21 | 20.1 |
4 h | 2 | 2.7 | 64 | 63.3 |
6 h | 0 | 1.2 | 30 | 28.8 |
8 h | 4 | 1.2 | 25 | 27.8 |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Schöne, N.; Greilmeier, K.; Heinz, B. Survey-Based Assessment of the Preferences in Residential Demand Response on the Island of Mayotte. Energies 2022, 15, 1338. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15041338
Schöne N, Greilmeier K, Heinz B. Survey-Based Assessment of the Preferences in Residential Demand Response on the Island of Mayotte. Energies. 2022; 15(4):1338. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15041338
Chicago/Turabian StyleSchöne, Nikolas, Kathrin Greilmeier, and Boris Heinz. 2022. "Survey-Based Assessment of the Preferences in Residential Demand Response on the Island of Mayotte" Energies 15, no. 4: 1338. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15041338
APA StyleSchöne, N., Greilmeier, K., & Heinz, B. (2022). Survey-Based Assessment of the Preferences in Residential Demand Response on the Island of Mayotte. Energies, 15(4), 1338. https://doi.org/10.3390/en15041338