Next Article in Journal
Broadband Power Line Communication in Railway Traction Lines: A Survey
Previous Article in Journal
From Lab to Fab: Development and Deployment of Direct Air Capture of CO2
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

Unlocking the Value of Aggregated Demand Response: A Survey of European Electricity Markets

by
Maja Božičević Vrhovčak
* and
Bruno Malbašić
Energy Institute Hrvoje Požar, 10000 Zagreb, Croatia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2023, 16(17), 6386; https://doi.org/10.3390/en16176386
Submission received: 1 August 2023 / Revised: 27 August 2023 / Accepted: 30 August 2023 / Published: 3 September 2023
(This article belongs to the Section F1: Electrical Power System)

Abstract

:
This paper focuses on the possible roles of aggregators in the European electricity markets and the challenges and opportunities they face in participating in different market segments. Demand response (DR) is becoming increasingly important with the growth of renewable energy, and aggregators can play a critical role in balancing supply and demand in real time. This paper provides an overview of prices in electricity markets in which DR aggregators can participate and provides recommendations for aggregators regarding which markets to focus on. However, the regulatory framework for aggregators is still evolving in Europe, creating challenges for them to navigate different market designs, regulatory frameworks, and pricing mechanisms. Through a combination of literature review and data analysis, this paper aims to provide insights for aggregators on how to maximize profits and minimize risks in the European electricity market. The article achieves this by conducting an extensive analysis of various markets, comparing their essential attributes relevant to the functioning of aggregators.

1. Introduction

Demand response (DR) is a mechanism that enables electricity customers to adjust their consumption in response to changes in the price of electricity or to signals from the electricity grid operator. The goal of this adjustment is to ensure the balance between supply and demand on the electricity grid, which can then help to reduce the need for expensive and polluting peaking power plants and improve the reliability and efficiency of the electricity system [1].
DR programs can be divided into two main categories: economic and reliability programs. Economic DR programs, in most cases, provide incentives to customers to reduce their electricity consumption during periods of high demand and high prices. Reliability DR programs, in most cases, provide incentives to customers to reduce their consumption or shift it to a different time to prevent blackouts [2]. In rare cases, there is a need to increase consumption to prevent frequency or voltage imbalance in low demand periods.
The importance of DR in the electricity market has increased with the growth of distributed energy resources such as solar and wind power, which can be highly variable and difficult to predict. The integration of these resources into the grid requires new methods of balancing supply and demand in real time, and DR can play a critical role in this process. Additionally, with the increasing focus on decarbonization, DR can be an important tool to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by reducing the need for fossil-fueled power plants.
DR can be implemented by electricity customers acting alone, but increasingly it is being implemented by aggregators. Aggregators can also provide value in terms of energy efficiency, energy storage, and renewable energy [3].
In this paper, we will focus on the possible roles of aggregators in the European electricity markets and analyze the most advanced countries in Europe and their markets/prices. The paper will provide an overview of prices in electricity markets in which DR aggregators can participate, and in the end, it will provide recommendations for aggregators in terms of which markets to focus on. Currently, aggregators cannot participate in all electricity market mechanisms due to technical or regulatory barriers.
The European electricity market is a complex and dynamic system that is undergoing significant changes, driven by factors such as the integration of renewable energy, the liberalization of the market, and the increasing need for balancing supply and demand. The market is composed of national and regional markets, each with its own regulatory framework, market design, and pricing mechanisms.
The liberalization of the European electricity market began in the late 1990s with the goal of creating a single market for electricity across the European Union. This process involved the separation of electricity generation, transmission, and distribution, and the introduction of competition in the generation and supply of electricity. The market is now composed of different market segments, such as the day-ahead, intraday, balancing, and capacity markets, each with its own rules, prices, and participants.
The role of aggregators in the European electricity market is to act as intermediaries between electricity customers and the market. They do this by aggregating the load of large industrial customers or many small customers, such as households and small businesses, which are the main focus of this paper, and participating in various market segments on their behalf. By doing so, aggregators can help customers reduce their electricity costs and increase their participation in the market [4,5]. They are expected to play an important role in the integration of renewable energy into the grid, by providing flexibility and balancing services, and in the decarbonization of the electricity sector.
From the renewable energy perspective, DR aggregators play an important role by helping to balance the supply and demand of electricity. As more renewable energy sources such as wind and solar are integrated into the grid, the variability of their output can make it difficult to maintain grid stability and meet demand. DR aggregators work by coordinating and incentivizing consumers to reduce their electricity consumption during periods of high demand or when the supply of renewable energy is low. By reducing consumption, they can help to reduce the strain on the grid and prevent the need for fossil fuel-based power plants to be brought online to meet demand [6,7].
However, the regulatory framework for aggregators is still evolving in Europe, and there are significant differences between countries in terms of the rules and incentives for aggregators. This can create challenges for aggregators, as they need to navigate different market designs, regulatory frameworks, and pricing mechanisms in order to provide services to their customers. This is certainly creating barriers for aggregators looking to become active in several member states [8].
Therefore, the main objective of this paper is to provide an overview of prices in markets in which aggregators can participate and to identify markets on which aggregators should focus. Specifically, the paper aims to:
(1)
Analyze different types of markets in which aggregators can participate in the European electricity market, including day-ahead, intraday, capacity, and balancing markets.
(2)
Survey market prices in European countries that are considered advanced in DR and the electricity market.
(3)
Evaluate the challenges and opportunities for aggregators in the European electricity market, considering the different regulatory frameworks, market designs, and pricing mechanisms.
(4)
Provide recommendations for aggregators on which markets to focus on in order to maximize profits and minimize risks.
In order to achieve these objectives, the paper will use a combination of literature review and data analysis. The end result of this paper is to provide a comprehensive review of the prices in markets in which aggregators can participate in the European market and recommendations for aggregators concerning which markets to focus on.

2. Methodology

The research design for this paper includes a combination of literature review and data analysis. The literature review provides an overview of existing research on DR and aggregator participation in electricity markets. A list of Q1 and Q2 open-access energy-related journals has been drafted, and the articles about aggregators and their market roles have been browsed and analyzed. The data analysis is based on the prices in different market segments in European countries with the most developed electricity markets. The data collection process is based on researching public information about each chosen country’s TSO and wholesale electricity market. TSO data provide information mostly about ancillary services (FCR, mFRR, aFRR), prices, and rules, and the wholesale electricity market contains information about the prices and rules of DAMs and IDMs. The results are shown in tables and graphs and discussed further in the text. The choice of the most developed countries in Europe in terms of DR is based on [9].

3. Literature Review of Types of Markets in Which Aggregators Can Participate

The so-called Electricity Directive [9] requires “the fair participation of aggregators in all electricity markets and that transmission and distribution system operators treat aggregators equally with other market participants”. Each of the electricity markets has its own rules, prices, and participants, and can offer different opportunities and challenges for aggregators.
The literature about aggregators is extensive and covers a broad area, from describing the value of aggregators for the electricity system [10,11] and consumers [12], to aggregator profit maximization through optimal scheduling [13,14], to aggregator behavior in the electricity markets [15,16,17,18,19,20,21]. The literature on DR and aggregator participation in electricity markets has shown that DR can be an effective tool for balancing supply and demand on the grid and that aggregators can play an important role in providing flexibility and balancing services [22,23,24,25,26]. Aggregators’ business models have been thoroughly researched [27,28,29,30,31,32]. However, there are still gaps in our understanding of the opportunities and challenges for aggregators in different European markets, and how these markets are behaving in terms of prices [33,34,35].
One gap in the literature is the lack of a comprehensive analysis of the prices in different market segments in which aggregators can participate. While some studies have examined the prices in specific markets, such as the day-ahead or balancing markets, there is a need for a more comprehensive analysis of the prices in different market segments, and how these prices are affecting the opportunities and challenges for aggregators. Another gap in the literature is the lack of a comprehensive analysis of different market segments from the aggregators’ perspective.

3.1. Day-Ahead Market

To participate in the day-ahead market, a demand-response aggregator would first analyze its end users’ energy usage patterns to identify periods of high and low demand when it is able to reduce or increase consumption without causing any negative impacts on operations. Based on this analysis, the aggregator would then determine how much energy it is able to curtail or shift during each hour of the following day. Next, the aggregator would submit bids to the market operator for each hour of the following day, indicating the amount of energy it is willing to reduce or increase consumption by and the price it is willing to accept for providing this service. The market operator evaluates all the bids it receives from all market participants, to determine the optimal mix of resources needed to meet expected demand for each hour of the following day [36].
Based on this evaluation, the market operator sets a clearing price for each hour of the following day. This is the price that all market participants will receive if their bids are accepted. If the aggregator’s bid is accepted, it is notified of the clearing price for each hour and the amount of energy it is expected to curtail or shift during each hour.
The aggregator then uses its resources in a way to activate the necessary energy adjustment measures. For example, it may temporarily adjust thermostats or turn off non-essential equipment during the designated time periods, taking the comfort factor into account.
At the end of the trading day, the aggregator reports back to the market operator on the actual amount of energy it was able to curtail or shift. If it meets its commitment, it receives payment at the clearing price for each hour.
Overall, participating in the day-ahead market allows demand-response aggregators to monetize the flexibility of their end users’ energy consumption while also helping to balance the overall electricity grid and prevent blackouts or other disruptions. By reducing the need for expensive peaking power plants, demand response can help to lower electricity prices and reduce greenhouse gas emissions.

3.2. Intraday Market

Intraday markets allow market participants, including demand-response aggregators, to adjust their energy commitments on a more short-term basis. For example, if unexpected changes in weather or other factors lead to higher-than-expected demand for electricity, the market operator may need to call upon additional resources to balance the grid.
To participate in the intraday market, a demand-response aggregator would first need to establish a connection to the market operator’s systems, typically through a third-party provider. This connection would allow the aggregator to receive real-time information about market conditions and submit bids to adjust its energy commitments accordingly.
When the aggregator identifies an opportunity to curtail, shift, or increase energy usage in response to changing market conditions, it would submit an offer to the market operator indicating the amount of energy it is willing to reduce or increase consumption by and the price it is willing to accept for providing this service. The market operator evaluates all of the offers it receives from demand-response aggregators and other market participants to determine the optimal mix of resources needed to balance the grid in real time [6].
If the aggregator’s offer is accepted, it is notified of the clearing price for the current hour and the amount of energy it is expected to curtail or shift during that hour. The aggregator then uses its resources in a way to activate the necessary energy adjustment measures.
At the end of the hour, the aggregator reports back to the market operator on the actual amount of energy it was able to curtail or shift. If it meets its commitment, it receives payment at the clearing price for that hour.
Overall, participating in the intraday market allows demand-response aggregators to adjust their energy commitments on a more short-term basis in response to changing market conditions and maximize their profit.

3.3. Balancing Market

The balancing market (BM) is a mechanism that the TSO uses to balance the supply and demand of electricity in real time. It provides a mechanism for the TSO to procure energy or capacity from market participants who have not been able to balance their generation and schedule in the IDM or have sudden outages. The balancing market is typically used as a last resort to maintain the balance of the system and avoid grid instability.
The main difference between providing balancing services to a grid operator through the IDM and the BM lies in the timing and duration of the service provision. In the IDM, balancing services are provided to the grid operator to help maintain the balance between electricity supply and demand in real time, as changes in electricity consumption and production can occur quickly and unexpectedly. These services are typically provided on a short-term basis, with the aim of addressing any imbalances that may arise in the electricity system.
On the other hand, the BM is a longer-term market where balancing services are procured by the grid operator for a longer duration, typically several days or weeks in advance. In the BM, the grid operator procures a portfolio of services to cover different types of imbalances that may occur over a longer period of time. In the BM, on the day of delivery, individual imbalances of Balance Responsible Parties (BRPs) are calculated. A BRP is a market participant that is responsible for ensuring that the energy it generates or consumes is in balance with its energy schedule. Participants in BRPs are aggregators, energy suppliers, generators, or large consumers, who have contracted to deliver or consume a certain amount of electricity within a given timeframe. Negative and positive individual imbalances occur when BRPs are over or under the contracted value. BRPs are financially responsible for their individual imbalances, and the imbalances are settled through the calculated imbalance prices. A price that is paid for negative imbalances is called a “negative imbalance price”, and a price that is paid for positive imbalances is called a “positive imbalance price”. The net sum of all individual imbalances of each BRP is called the system imbalance.
When it is not equal to zero, the system imbalance leads to a deviation from the nominal system frequency (50 Hz in Europe). The TSO is responsible for eliminating the imbalance in the system and restoring the system frequency to its nominal value. To do so, the TSO activates reserve power in cases of system imbalance. If there is a shortfall in the system (negative system imbalance), the up-reserve is activated, i.e., an increase in production or a decrease in consumption. Likewise, if there is a surplus in the system (positive system imbalance), the down-reserve is activated, i.e., a decrease in production or an increase in consumption.
Specifically, in most countries in Europe, there are three types of reserves that contribute to balancing frequency: frequency containment reserve, automatic frequency restoration reserve, and manual frequency restoration reserve.
  • The frequency containment reserve (FCR) is known as the primary reserve. It is the first type of reserve activated by the TSO. It is used to stabilize the system frequency and restrict greater frequency deviations.
  • The automatic frequency restoration reserve (aFRR) is known as the secondary reserve, automatically activated to bring the system frequency back to its nominal value.
  • The manual frequency restoration reserve (mFRR) is known as the tertiary reserve, used for significant imbalances that last for a long time and to take over the role of automated reserves in order to be ready for new imbalances. The TSO manually activates the mFRR if the available capacity of the aFRR drops below a certain threshold.
Balancing energy can be activated by increasing/decreasing production or consumption. Capacity and balancing energy markets in most European countries are separated. The capacity market results in a capacity reservation price (payment for reservation), while the balance energy market determines the balance energy price (payment for activation).
Aggregators can offer reserves of power to the transmission system operators (TSOs) to help eliminate imbalances in the system in exchange for payment for reservations and/or activation by the TSO. Aggregated portfolio management creates an opportunity to make offers in the FCR, aFRR, or mFRR markets. The activation of the reserves of power must be quite rapid, even as quickly as 30 s. The secondary reserve is usually activated within five minutes according to the table, while the tertiary must be activated within 15 min. The market is transparent, and its price sets the reference price for the calculation of imbalances that occur days after the delivery of energy.
In the case of DR, the aggregator offers the amount of energy/power that can be increased or reduced, and the TSO decides whether to accept the offer or not [37].

3.4. Capacity Market

Capacity markets are designed to provide incentives for market participants, including demand-response aggregators, to invest in new or existing resources that can provide capacity to the grid during periods of peak demand. In a capacity market, market participants are paid for their ability to provide a certain amount of capacity over a specified period of time.
To participate in a capacity market, a demand-response aggregator would first need to submit an offer indicating the amount of capacity it is able to provide over the specified period of time, typically in the form of a commitment to reduce or increase energy consumption during peak high or low demand periods. For example, the aggregator may commit to reducing energy consumption by 1 MW during the peak high demand period from 2–3 pm every weekday for the next three years. Based on these offers, the market operator determines the total amount of capacity needed to meet expected demand during the specified period of time and sets a clearing price for this capacity. If the aggregator’s offer is accepted, it is notified of the clearing price and the amount of capacity it is expected to provide over the specified period of time.
The aggregator should then communicate with its end-users to implement the necessary energy adjustment measures to provide the committed capacity during peak demand periods. At the end of the specified period of time, the aggregator reports back to the market operator on the actual amount of capacity it provided. If it meets its commitment, it receives payment at the clearing price for the capacity it provided.
Overall, participating in a capacity market provides DR aggregators with a long-term revenue stream and incentives to invest in new or existing resources that can provide capacity to the grid during periods of peak demand. However, some studies still show that the capacity remuneration schemes currently implemented provide inadequate incentives to DR operators—for example, [38].

4. Market Data Collection and Analysis

The following chapter contains tables and graphs showing various features of electricity markets in more advanced European countries in terms of DR and market mechanisms, namely Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, and the Netherlands [39,40,41,42,43,44,45,46,47,48,49]. The goal of the European electricity market is to have the lowest possible barrier to participation in the energy markets and to have the shortest possible trading and readout periods. The long-term EU goal is to establish the integrated market-oriented procurement of the mFRR, FRR, FCR, and RR reserve mechanisms [50,51]. As opposed to the balancing and reserve mechanisms, DAMs and IDMs across Europe are well-coupled [52,53]. In the following sections, market characteristics for each country have been analyzed and compared according to:
  • Service or market mechanism.
  • Type of contract.
  • Minimum offer of service (quantity of electricity).
  • Gate closure time.
  • Service activation time.
  • Frequency of activation.
  • Service price.
To decide whether to participate in DAMs, IDMs, or ancillary services, the demand-response aggregator should consider several factors. Firstly, the aggregator should analyze the price signals in the DAMs/IDMs and the ancillary services market to determine which market offers the best opportunities for their flexibility assets. Secondly, the aggregator should assess the flexibility of their assets, the size and duration of their bids, and the level of risk they are willing to take. Thirdly, the aggregator should consider operational and technical requirements for participating in each market segment, such as the minimum and maximum bid sizes, the time for submitting bids, and the ramp rate of their assets. Finally, the aggregator should evaluate the potential benefits and costs of participating in each market segment, such as the revenue earned from the market, the cost of balancing their assets, and any regulatory requirements for participating in each segment. By considering these factors, the aggregator can make an informed decision on which market segment to participate in and optimize their revenue streams.
In electricity markets, there are two types of prices: average and marginal prices. Average prices are calculated based on the total amount of energy traded in a given time period, divided by the total cost of that energy. These prices provide an overall picture of market trends and can be used for long-term planning purposes. On the other hand, marginal prices are calculated based on the cost of the last unit of energy traded in the market, which sets the price for all units of energy traded at that time. Marginal prices are crucial for short-term trading and balancing purposes, as they reflect the actual cost of supplying energy at a given moment. While both average and marginal prices provide valuable insights into electricity market mechanisms, it is important to consider both when making informed decisions about participating in the market. In this paper, average prices are mostly used in the analysis of ancillary services, and marginal prices are used for wholesale markets.
For the cross-country comparison of DAM and IDM prices, publicly available data have been used [39,40]. DAM and IDM prices on a regular day are shown in Figure 1 (for 26 March 2023).
The graph showing DAM prices in March 2023 for Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, and the Netherlands indicates that prices differed across countries. While Belgium and France had the highest prices at 124 EUR/MWh and 118 EUR/MWh, respectively, Finland had the lowest at 74 EUR/MWh. These differences can be attributed to various factors, such as differences in fuel prices, the availability of renewable energy sources, transmission constraints, and demand–supply imbalances. While removing cross-border constraints can help to reduce price differences between countries, there are still other remaining factors that affect electricity prices. It is unlikely that prices will be exactly the same in every country. However, despite these differences, the prices in the IDM are not significantly different from those in the DAM. This is because the IDM primarily serves as a balancing mechanism for the DAM, and any significant differences in the underlying fundamentals driving the prices are reflected in the DAM.
Figure 2 presents FCR capacity reservation marginal prices in the analyzed countries in March 2023. As countries trade on the power exchange, they also maintain yearly, weekly, and daily auctions/tenders for auxiliary services such as primary, secondary, and tertiary reserves.
The German TSOs procure all control reserves (balancing capacity and balancing energy) commonly across their control areas and partly in cooperation with neighboring countries (Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, France, the Netherlands, Slovenia, and Switzerland) [49].
The tendering is open, transparent, and free from discrimination, according to the guidelines of the Federal Cartel Office (Bundeskartellamt—BKartA), the national regulatory authority (Bundesnetzagentur), and EU Guidelines.
“Precondition for providing balancing services is the pre-qualification procedure of each balancing service provider (BSP) at the connecting TSO. The possibility of pooling/aggregation enables small technical units as well as loads to deliver balancing services. The terms and conditions for BSPs contain the market rules from qualification to settlement for all market participants” [54].
In order to secure FCRs for Finland, Fingrid procures them from various sources such as domestic yearly and hourly markets, as well as HVDC links with Estonia and other Nordic countries. Providers of reserves can offer capacity located in Finland that meets the reserve requirements for trading in the yearly and/or hourly market. Both markets have identical technical requirements and separately trade FCRs up and down [55].
Figure 3 and Figure 4 present the aFRR and mFRR average capacity reservation and activation prices on 26 March 2023.
The graphs show that the prices for different services such as the mFRR, aFRR, and FCR vary significantly between countries. For example, the prices for the aFRR and mFRR in Germany are generally higher than in Finland. The differences in the balancing energy marginal price between Germany and Finland can be attributed to several factors, including the countries’ energy mix, demand patterns, and market structure. One significant factor is the energy mix of the countries. Germany has a higher share of renewable energy sources, particularly wind and solar, which are subject to fluctuations due to weather conditions [56]. These fluctuations can cause imbalances between electricity supply and demand, leading to a higher demand for balancing energy. In contrast, Finland has a higher share of nuclear and hydroelectric power, which is generally more stable and less subject to fluctuations. Another factor is the demand pattern in the countries. Germany has a larger population and a more significant industrial sector, which creates a higher demand for electricity and increases the likelihood of imbalances that require balancing energy. Finland, on the other hand, has a smaller population and a less energy-intensive economy, which reduces the demand for total energy and for balancing energy. The market structure can also play a role in the differences in balancing energy prices. Germany has a more complex market structure with more energy exchanges, which can lead to more price volatility and higher balancing energy prices.
The up-regulating price is the price of the most expensive up-regulating energy bid used; however, it is at least the price in the Finnish price area in the Nord Pool. Everyone whom Fingrid has ordered to up-regulate during the hour receives payment for the energy agreed upon based on the up-regulating energy price. The down-regulating price is the price of the cheapest down-regulating energy bid used; however, it is no more than the price in the Finnish price area in the Nord Pool [57].
An analysis of market mechanisms across various countries has revealed notable differences in gate closure times. For instance, in France, the gate closure time for the FCR is 8:00 h in the day-ahead market, followed by 9:00 h for the aFRR in the day-ahead market, 10:00 h for the mFRR in the day-ahead market, and 12:00 h for the wholesale DAM. These variations in gate closure times among different market mechanisms and countries underscore the diverse approaches taken by market operators in managing electricity supply and demand. Understanding these differences is essential for ensuring effective grid management and promoting cross-border electricity trading.
Table 1 shows that the minimum offer on the wholesale market in selected countries ranges from 0.1 MW to 1 MW. Lower values are favorable for demand-response aggregators while higher values create market barriers for aggregators’ participation in the market.
Table 2 shows that the FCR and mFRR have standard unit activation periods (30 s FCR and 15 min mFRR) in contrast to the aFRR, which varies between countries (2–7.5 min). Austria, Belgium, Germany, and the Netherlands have implemented 15 min offers and readings in most of the market mechanisms, which significantly contributes to the portfolio and position optimization of every participant.

5. Discussion

The results of the data analysis show that the prices in the different market segments vary significantly between countries.
Many countries currently have a trading time resolution of one hour, which is considered too long for the aggregated resources of a large number of flexible small consumers. The implementation of shorter trading time resolutions allows for more accurate pricing signals and a more efficient matching of supply and demand, which can lead to improved market liquidity and reduced volatility in electricity prices.
For flexible resource aggregators, shorter trading time resolutions enable more precise forecasting and the management of aggregated resources, allowing them to adjust usage in real time to respond to price signals.
For producers and energy traders, shorter trading time resolutions enable more detailed forecasts about supply and demand imbalances, allowing for more accurate forecasting and improved risk management. This can lead to better portfolio and position optimization and improved efficiency in electricity trading.
Most countries have different prices in the electricity market, but these would otherwise be almost equal if there was no congestion in cross-border flows [58]. The prices of ancillary services differ for both the reservation and activated energy because the TSO is the only buyer and sets the rules for purchasing reserves.
Currently, the most common source of revenue for aggregators as market participants are ancillary services (primary, secondary, and tertiary reserves). The response from the consumer is usually quickly activated, thus making it suitable for the primary reserve, which has an activation time of less than 30 s. In this way, the aggregator gains a constant income as the TSO is obligated to reserve the capacity. When the reserved capacity is activated, the aggregator gains an additional income at a price higher than the electricity market price. The capacity reservation price tends to decrease over a long-term period. The main reason for the reservation price decrease is an increase in market liquidity. New platforms for the cross-border procurement of ancillary services are being developed, contributing to market liquidity, which tends to lower and, in the future, may possibly even remove the need for unit reservation [59].
Due to technical and regulatory challenges in each country combined with the nature of DAMs, aggregators find it challenging to participate in such markets. DR participation in DAMs is significant in the Netherlands (700 MW from industry) [60].

6. Conclusions and Further Work

DR programs have the potential to provide significant benefits to both customers and the electricity grid in Europe. However, there are several regulatory challenges and barriers that can make it difficult for DR providers to offer their services effectively. One of the most significant challenges is the lack of harmonized legislation across Europe. Each country has its own policies, programs, and by-laws for DR, which can make it challenging for providers to operate across borders. This inconsistency can limit the potential benefits of DR programs and make it difficult to achieve scale. Another barrier to DR adoption is the inconsistent incentives provided to DR programs in different countries. Some countries offer robust support and incentives for DR programs, while others do not. This lack of consistency can make it difficult for DR providers to offer their services effectively and maximize the benefits of DR. The complexity of electricity market design is another challenge for DR providers. Different market designs in each country can create barriers to entry for new DR providers and limit the potential benefits of DR. The lack of interoperability between different DR technologies is also a challenge for providers. Access to data is essential for DR providers to offer their services effectively. However, there are challenges related to data privacy, which can hinder the development of DR programs. Additionally, in some countries, a small number of large utilities dominate the market, making it difficult for new DR providers to enter the market and compete on a level playing field. Finally, regulatory uncertainty is a significant challenge for DR providers. The regulatory environment for DR is constantly changing, which can create uncertainty for providers and limit the potential benefits of DR programs. However, it should be noted that there are ongoing efforts to address these issues, such as the development of a more harmonized regulatory framework and the promotion of interoperability between different DR technologies [61].
DR aggregators face significant challenges when participating in electricity markets. One of the most significant challenges is the inherent uncertainty associated with aggregated DR resources, which cannot be scheduled with the same level of certainty as traditional generators. Instead, DR aggregators rely on the actions of end users, making it challenging to accurately forecast their output. Additionally, factors beyond the aggregator’s control, such as weather conditions or changes in consumer behavior, can impact their availability, making it difficult to provide firm commitments to deliver or consume energy. Consumer behavior becomes less of a problem as number of consumers increase over time.
Despite these challenges, DR aggregators can play a crucial role in balancing the grid, and their participation in ancillary services markets can be recommended based on the previous analysis. Ancillary services markets often have shorter activation times than DAMs, which can make it easier for DR aggregators to participate. Moreover, these markets usually offer higher prices, making them more financially attractive.
This paper offers an extensive exploration of the potential roles that aggregators can play within a variety of electricity markets. It also provides a comparative analysis of essential market characteristics within six EU nations, serving as a guide for those interested in participating in aggregation. Future work will investigate aggregators’ performance across multiple markets and pay further attention to the impacts of the chosen business model on the profitability of the aggregator’s operations by conducting a simulation with different price signals.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization and formal analysis: M.B.V.; Investigation, validation and writing: B.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by the European Commission, European Structural and Investments Funds 2014–2020, grant number KK.01.1.1.07.0038, by the research project of the Energy Institute Hrvoje Požar, “Development of an integrated solution for strategic long-term climate and energy policy planning and development of joint climate and energy plans”.

Data Availability Statement

No new data were created or analyzed in this study. Data sharing is not applicable to this article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest. The funders had no role in the design of the study; in the collection, analyses, or interpretation of data; in the writing of the manuscript; or in the decision to publish the results.

References

  1. Bruninx, K.; Pandžić, H.; Le Cadre, H.; Delarue, E. On the Interaction between Aggregators, Electricity Markets and Residential Demand Response Providers. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2020, 35, 840–853. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Zhu, B.; Xu, L.; Chen, Y. A Strategy for Demand Response of Households Based on Communities. In Proceedings of the 2020 Asia Energy and Electrical Engineering Symposium (AEEES), Chengdu, China, 29–31 May 2020; pp. 983–987. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Dranka, G.G.; Ferreira, P.; Vaz, A.I.F. Co-benefits between energy efficiency and demand-response on renewable-based energy systems. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2022, 169, 112936. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Holmberg, D.; Omar, F. Characterization of Residential Distributed Energy Resource Potential to Provide Ancillary Services; National Institute of Standards and Technology: Gaithersburg, MD, USA, 2023. [Google Scholar]
  5. Liu, B. Scheduling Strategies of Smart Community with Load Aggregator-Based Demand Response. In Proceedings of the 2018 2nd IEEE Conference on Energy Internet and Energy System Integration (EI2), Beijing, China, 20–22 October 2018; pp. 1–4. [Google Scholar]
  6. Bruninx, K.; Pandžić, H.; Le Cedre, H.; Delarue, E. On Controllability of Demand Response Resources & Aggregators’ Bidding Strategies. In Proceedings of the 2018 Power Systems Computation Conference (PSCC), Dublin, Ireland, 11–15 June 2018; pp. 1–7. [Google Scholar]
  7. European Smart Grids Task Force, Expert Group 3, Final Report on Demand Side Flexibility. 2019. Available online: https://energy.ec.europa.eu/ (accessed on 7 March 2023).
  8. FTI Consulting, Market Design for Demand Response. 2017. Available online: https://www.europarl.europa.eu/ (accessed on 7 March 2023).
  9. The European Parliament and The Council of the European Union. Directive (EU) 2019/944 of the European Parliament and of The Council of 5 June 2019 on Common Rules for The Internal Market for Electricity and Amending Directive 2012/27/EU. 2019. Available online: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=celex%3A32019L0944 (accessed on 10 March 2023).
  10. Burgera, S.; Chaves-Ávilab, J.P.; Batllec, C.; Pérez-Arriaga, I. The Value of Aggregators in Electricity Systems. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 77, 395–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Tantau, A.; Puskás-Tompos, A.; Fratila, L.; Stanciu, C. Acceptance of Demand Response and Aggregators as a Solution to Optimize the Relation between Energy Producers and Consumers in order to Increase the Amount of Renewable Energy in the Grid. Energies 2021, 14, 3441. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Marić, L.L.; Keko, H.; Delimar, M. The Role of Local Aggregator in Delivering Energy Savings to Household Consumers. Energies 2022, 15, 2793. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Hansen, T.M.; Roche, R.; Suryanarayanan, S.; Maciejewski, A.; Siegel, H.J. Heuristic optimization for an aggregator-based resource allocation in the Smart Grid. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2015, 6, 1785–1794. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Shewale, A.; Mokhade, A.; Funde, N.; Bokde, N. An Overview of Demand Response in Smart Grid and Optimization Techniques for Efficient Residential Appliance Scheduling Problem. Energies 2020, 13, 4266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Mahmoudi, N.; Forushani, E.H.; Shafie-khah, M.; Saha, T.K.; Golshan, M.E.H.; Siano, P. A bottom-up approach for demand response aggregators’ participation in electricity markets. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2017, 143, 121–129, ISSN 0378-7796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Iria, J.; Soares, F.; Matos, M. Optimal supply and demand bidding strategy for an aggregator of small prosumers. Appl. Energy 2018, 213, 658–669, ISSN 0306-2619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Wang, Z.; Dong, L.; Shi, M.; Qiao, J.; Jia, H.; Mu, Y.; Pu, T. Market power modeling and restraint of aggregated prosumers in peer-to-peer energy trading: A game-theoretic approach. Appl. Energy 2023, 348, 121550, ISSN 0306-2619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Xu, Z.; Hu, Z.; Song, Y.; Wang, J. Risk-averse optimal bidding strategy for demand-side resource aggregators in day-ahead electricity markets under uncertainty. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2015, 8, 96–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Kubli, M.; Canzi, P. Business strategies for flexibility aggregators to steer clear of being “too small to bid”. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2021, 143, 110908, ISSN 1364-0321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Pakere, I.; Gravelsins, A.; Bohvalovs, G.; Rozentale, L.; Blumberga, D. Will Aggregator Reduce Renewable Power Surpluses? A System Dynamics Approach for the Latvia Case Study. Energies 2021, 14, 7900. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Zoričić, D.; Knežević, G.; Miletić, M.; Dolinar, D.; Sprčić, D.M. Integrated Risk Analysis of Aggregators: Policy Implications for the Development of the Competitive Aggregator Industry. Energies 2022, 15, 5076. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Beus, M.; Pavic, I.; Pandzic, H.; Capuder, T.; Stritof, I.; Androcec, I. Evaluating Flexibility of Business Models for Distributed Energy Resource Aggregators. In Proceedings of the 2018 15th International Conference on the European Energy Market (EEM), Lodz, Poland, 27–29 June 2018; pp. 1–5. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Aro, M.; Evens, C.; Mäki, K.; Järventausta, P. Sub-aggregator business models for dr. Cired. In Proceedings of the 2021—The 26th International Conference and Exhibition on Electricity Distribution, 20–23 September 2021; pp. 3206–3210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Yang, D.; He, S.; Chen, Q.; Li, D.; Pandžić, H. Bidding strategy of a virtual power plant considering carbon-electricity trading. in CSEE J. Power Energy Syst. 2019, 5, 306–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Pressmair, G.; Leutgöb, K.; Amann, C.; Tzovaras, D.; Ioannidis, D. Business models for DR related to small- and medium-sized prosumers—New stakeholders and the role of DSOs. In Proceedings of the CIRED 2020 Berlin Workshop (CIRED 2020), 22–23 September 2020; pp. 661–664. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Lahti, A.; Heine, P.; Honkapuro, S. Analyzing the impact of the customers’ decision-making on the implementation of dr. In Proceedings of the CIRED 2021—The 26th International Conference and Exhibition on Electricity Distribution, 20–23 September 2021; pp. 3070–3074. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Moura, R.; Brito, M.C. Prosumer aggregation policies, country experience and business models. Energy Pol. 2019, 132, 820–830. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Iria, J.; Soares, F.; Matos, M. Optimal bidding strategy for an aggregator of prosumers in energy and secondary reserve markets. Appl. Energy 2019, 238, 1361–1372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Okur, Ö.; Heijnen, P.; Lukszo, Z. Aggregator’s business models in residential and service sectors: A review of operational and financial aspects. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2021, 139, 110702, ISSN 1364-0321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Iria, J.; Soares, F. An energy-as-a-service business model for aggregators of prosumers. Appl. Energy 2023, 347, 121487, ISSN 0306-2619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Bertolini, M.; Morosinotto, G. Business Models for Energy Community in the Aggregator Perspective: State of the Art and Research Gaps. Energies 2023, 16, 4487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Dong, J.; Dou, X.; Liu, D.; Bao, A.; Wang, D.; Zhang, Y. Energy Trading Strategy of Distributed Energy Resources Aggregator in Day-Ahead Market Considering Risk Preference Behaviors. Energies 2023, 16, 1629. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Gržanić, M.; Morales, J.M.; Pineda, S.; Capuder, T. Electricity Cost-Sharing in Energy Communities Under Dynamic Pricing and Uncertainty. IEEE Access 2021, 9, 30225–30241. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Pandžić, H.; Pavić, I.; Andročec, I. Optimal Battery Storage Participation in European Energy and Reserves Markets. Energies 2020, 13, 6629. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Verpoorten, K.; De Jonghe, C.; Belmans, R. Market barriers for harmonized demand-response in balancing reserves: Cross-country comparison. In Proceedings of the 2016 13th International Conference on the European Energy Market (EEM), Porto, Portugal, 6–9 June 2016; pp. 1–5. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Wang, F.; Xiang, B.; Li, K.; Ge, X.; Lu, H.; Lai, J.; Dehghanian, P. Smart Households’ Aggregated Capacity Forecasting for Load Aggregators Under Incentive-Based DR Programs. in IEEE Trans. Ind. Appl. 2020, 56, 1086–1097. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Khandelwal, M.; Mathuria, P.; Bhakar, R. State-of-Art on Flexibility Services in Electricity Markets. In Proceedings of the 2018 8th IEEE India International Conference on Power Electronics (IICPE), Jaipur, India, 13–15 December 2018; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Lambin, X. Integration of Demand Response in Electricity Market Capacity Mechanisms. Util. Policy 2020, 64, 101033, ISSN 0957-1787. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. NordPool. March 2023. Available online: https://www.nordpoolgroup.com/en/ (accessed on 27 March 2023).
  40. EPEX SPOT. March 2023. Available online: https://www.epexspot.com/en (accessed on 27 March 2023).
  41. RTE. March 2023. Available online: https://www.rte-france.com/en. (accessed on 28 March 2023).
  42. Ausgrid. March 2023. Available online: https://www.ausgrid.com.au/. (accessed on 28 March 2023).
  43. Fingrid. March 2023. Available online: https://www.fingrid.fi/en/ (accessed on 28 March 2023).
  44. Elia. March 2023. Available online: https://www.elia.be/ (accessed on 29 March 2023).
  45. 50hertz. March 2023. Available online: https://www.50hertz.com/en/ (accessed on 29 March 2023).
  46. TenneT. March 2023. Available online: https://www.tennet.eu/ (accessed on 29 March 2023).
  47. National Grid ESO. March 2023. Available online: https://www.nationalgrideso.com/ (accessed on 30 March 2023).
  48. ENTSO-E. March 2023. Available online: https://www.entsoe.eu/ (accessed on 30 March 2023).
  49. Regelleistung.net. March 2023. Available online: https://www.regelleistung.net/ext/?lang=en (accessed on 30 March 2023).
  50. The European Parliament and The Council of the European Union. Regulation (EU) 2019/943 of The European Parliament and of The Council of 5 June 2019 on the Internal Market for Electricity. 2019. Available online: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=CELEX%3A32019R0943 (accessed on 30 March 2023).
  51. The European Commission. Regulation (EU) 2017/2195 of 23 November 2017 Establishing a Guideline on Electricity Balancing. 2017. Available online: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/ (accessed on 30 March 2023).
  52. ENTSO-E. Single Day-Ahead Coupling (SDAC). Available online: https://www.entsoe.eu/network_codes/cacm/implementation/sdac/ (accessed on 31 March 2023).
  53. ENTSO-E. Single Intraday Coupling (SIDC). Available online: https://www.entsoe.eu/network_codes/cacm/implementation/sidc/ (accessed on 31 March 2023).
  54. Regelleistung.net. Balancing Market in Germany. Available online: https://www.regelleistung.net/en-us/Market-information/Modalities-Legal-Framework (accessed on 31 March 2023).
  55. Fingrid. Frequency Containment Reserves (FCR Products). Available online: https://www.fingrid.fi/en/electricity-market/reserves_and_balancing/frequency-containment-reserves/ (accessed on 31 March 2023).
  56. Abuzayed, A.; Hartmann, N. Triggering Germany’s ambitious dream of a completely renewable electricity sector by 2035. In Proceedings of the 2022 International Conference on Renewable Energies and Smart Technologies (REST), Tirana, Albania, 28–29 July 2022; pp. 1–4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Fingrid. Balancing Energy And Balancing Capacity Markets (mFRR). Available online: https://www.fingrid.fi/en/electricity-market/reserves_and_balancing/balancing-energy-and-balancing-capacity-markets/ (accessed on 31 March 2023).
  58. Liu, W.; Wu, Q.; Wen, F.; Østergaard, J. Day-Ahead Congestion Management in Distribution Systems Through Household DR and Distribution Congestion Prices. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2014, 5, 2739–2747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. ENTSO-E. Go-Live of PICASSO and MARI Platforms that Complete the Ambitious Electricity Balancing Regulation Target Implementation. Available online: https://www.entsoe.eu/news/ (accessed on 31 March 2023).
  60. IEA DR tracking report. Available online: https://www.iea.org/energy-system/energy-efficiency-and-demand/demand-response (accessed on 4 April 2023).
  61. ACER. Framework Guideline on DR. Available online: https://acer.europa.eu/Official_documents/Acts_of_the_Agency/Framework_Guidelines/Framework%20Guidelines/FG_DemandResponse.pdf (accessed on 4 April 2023).
Figure 1. Wholesale DAM price (left-hand side) and IDM price (right-hand side).
Figure 1. Wholesale DAM price (left-hand side) and IDM price (right-hand side).
Energies 16 06386 g001
Figure 2. FCR capacity reservation marginal price in March 2023.
Figure 2. FCR capacity reservation marginal price in March 2023.
Energies 16 06386 g002
Figure 3. Average aFRR capacity reservation price (left-hand side) and aFRR average up energy activation price (right-hand side) on 26 March 2023.
Figure 3. Average aFRR capacity reservation price (left-hand side) and aFRR average up energy activation price (right-hand side) on 26 March 2023.
Energies 16 06386 g003
Figure 4. Average mFRR capacity reservation price (left-hand side) and mFRR average up energy activation price (right-hand side) on 26 March 2023.
Figure 4. Average mFRR capacity reservation price (left-hand side) and mFRR average up energy activation price (right-hand side) on 26 March 2023.
Energies 16 06386 g004
Table 1. Minimal bid on different market segments in chosen countries in 2023 [MW].
Table 1. Minimal bid on different market segments in chosen countries in 2023 [MW].
AustriaBelgiumFinlandFranceGermanyNetherlands
DAM0.10.10.10.10.10.1
IDM0.10.10.10.10.10.1
FCR110.1111
aFRR111111
mFRR1151011
Table 2. Time in which units have to respond with activation on different ancillary services [min].
Table 2. Time in which units have to respond with activation on different ancillary services [min].
AustriaBelgiumFinlandFranceGermanyNetherlands
FCR0.50.50.50.50.50.5
aFRR57.526.6655
mFRR151515151515
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Božičević Vrhovčak, M.; Malbašić, B. Unlocking the Value of Aggregated Demand Response: A Survey of European Electricity Markets. Energies 2023, 16, 6386. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16176386

AMA Style

Božičević Vrhovčak M, Malbašić B. Unlocking the Value of Aggregated Demand Response: A Survey of European Electricity Markets. Energies. 2023; 16(17):6386. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16176386

Chicago/Turabian Style

Božičević Vrhovčak, Maja, and Bruno Malbašić. 2023. "Unlocking the Value of Aggregated Demand Response: A Survey of European Electricity Markets" Energies 16, no. 17: 6386. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16176386

APA Style

Božičević Vrhovčak, M., & Malbašić, B. (2023). Unlocking the Value of Aggregated Demand Response: A Survey of European Electricity Markets. Energies, 16(17), 6386. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16176386

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop