Next Article in Journal
Efficiency Assessment of Five Types of Photovoltaic Modules Installed on a Fixed and on a Dual-Axis Solar-Tracked Platform
Next Article in Special Issue
A Review of the Energy Policy and Energy Transition Objectives for 2040 in the Canary Islands (Spain)
Previous Article in Journal
Statistical Analysis of Breakdown Voltage of Insulating Liquid Dopped with Surfactants
Previous Article in Special Issue
Allocative Efficiency towards Energy Transition: The Cases of Natural Gas and Electricity Markets
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Energy Taxation Reform with an Environmental Focus in Portugal

by
Alfredo Marvão Pereira
* and
Rui Marvão Pereira
Department of Economics, William & Mary, Williamsburg, VA 23187, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2023, 16(3), 1232; https://doi.org/10.3390/en16031232
Submission received: 1 December 2022 / Revised: 14 January 2023 / Accepted: 17 January 2023 / Published: 23 January 2023

Abstract

:
Climate change has made the decarbonization of the different domestic economies a widely accepted and urgent priority. Yet, this is a very challenging task in a largely uncharted territory. In this context, in this paper, we address the issue of energy taxation reform with an environmental focus in Portugal. We do so using a multi-sector and multi-household dynamic computable general equilibrium model of the Portuguese economy. We analyze the environmental, macroeconomic, and distributional effects of different policies replacing current energy taxation with carbon taxation and, then, extend the carbon taxation to the levels necessary to achieve the IPCC 2018 emissions reduction targets. Our analysis indicates a clear path in the quest for decarbonization. First, replace energy taxes with a carbon tax; second, adopt the levels of carbon taxation necessary to achieve the emissions goals; third, use extra tax revenues from the carbon tax to reverse any potential adverse macroeconomic and distributional effects of carbon taxation. In the process, this would be a way around the pervasive problem of perverse fossil fuel subsidies, which would effectively disappear and, as such, would improve the efficiency of the tax system.

1. Introduction

Recently, a report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [1] indicated that limiting global warming to 1.5 °C would require “rapid and far-reaching” transitions in land, energy, industry, buildings, transport, and cities. Global emissions of CO2 would need to fall by about 45% from 2010 levels by 2030, reaching “net zero” around 2050, and neutrality of the remaining greenhouse gases would need to be achieved soon thereafter. In turn, the European Union legislative package “Clean Energy for All Europeans” [2] includes, among other measures, requirements for each Member State to draw up National Integrated Energy and Climate Plans, setting out the objectives, targets, and contributions of each Member State by 2030.
There is a wide gap between intentions and actions when it comes to environmental policies. This is mostly due to the difficulty in obtaining “fossil fuel prices right”, i.e., having fossil fuel prices also reflect the environmental externalities they generate (see, for example, [3,4,5]).
In the path toward obtaining “fossil fuel prices right”, there are two issues of critical importance. The first is the inadequacy of current energy taxation systems to do this job due to the focus on energy content and not emissions, and even more so the widespread existence of environmentally perverse fossil fuel subsidies that actually make fossil fuels even cheaper than the market mechanisms would dictate. (See, for example, [6,7,8,9,10]).
The second is the mechanisms to obtain “fossil fuel prices right” by environmental standards, in particular, through carbon taxation. (See, for example, [11,12,13,14]). In this context, there is strong evidence that carbon taxation without countervailing measures would lead to macroeconomic losses, loss of international competitiveness, and would have adverse distributional effects. (See, for example, [15,16,17,18,19]). These adverse effects bring to the forefront the issue of recycling carbon tax revenues as a mechanism to mitigate such adverse effects while at the same time maintaining tax revenue neutrality, i.e., avoiding an increase in the overall tax burden for the domestic economy. [See, for example, [20,21,22,23,24,25]).
In Portugal, the main energy taxation exists under the so-called “Imposto sobre Productos Petroliferos e Energéticos”, ISP hereafter. This is a broad tax on petroleum and other energy products with tax revenues, which represents about 1.8% of the GDP. This tax has three main components: a basic unit tax, a road contribution component, and an add-on based on the carbon content of the products; more on which below. For the most part, the current energy tax system is designed mostly to reflect the energy content of fuels—rather than their emissions content—and is based on the need to raise funds for the public budget. In addition, it provides a large number of exemptions and subsidies on the use of different fossil fuels in transportation, agriculture, industrial processes, electricity generation, etc. In 2018, such exemptions and subsidies amounted to EUR 430 million or about 0.22% of the GDP or 12% of the ISP revenues. Accordingly, such environmentally perverse subsidies are substantial and pervasive.
In turn, in 2015, a carbon tax indexed to the carbon price in the EU-ETS was introduced as an add-on to the ISP tax. As such, this carbon tax has several serious shortcomings that make it a rather ineffective tool in desperate need of reform. In a nutshell, the existing carbon tax is hopelessly too low, it is far from universal, as it inherited all of the exemptions under energy taxation in Portugal, and contemplates no recycling mechanisms which would make it rather harmful to the economy and social justice should it be of a significant magnitude.
Faced with the IPCC 2018 targets and the EU 2019 directives, Portugal has recently approved the roadmap for carbon neutrality “Roteiro para a Neutralidade Carbónica” [26], RNC2050, hereafter. In the RNC2050, these different environmental and decarbonization targets are duly incorporated and specific decarbonization pathways are presented to achieve such targets. The RNC2050, however, is not intended to provide the specific public policy mechanisms necessary to get the country started in such pathways and to ultimately reach such targets. In this paper, we suggest a first strong step in the direction of decarbonization in the form of energy taxation reform.
The reality of energy and carbon taxation coupled with the need to achieve specific environmental goals fully justifies the need in Portugal for energy taxation reform. In this research, we focus on energy taxation reform with an environmental focus with the objective of getting fossil fuel prices right—allowing these prices to reflect the full costs of fossil fuel combustion activities. First, we analyze the effects of replacing the current tax on energy products with a carbon tax directly linked to the different environmental damages associated with fossil fuel combustion. Second, we extend the carbon taxation beyond what would be strictly necessary to replace the energy taxes, to the levels necessary to reach the international targets toward decarbonization. Third, we discuss a broader revenue-neutral fiscal reform that goes beyond the energy and carbon taxation margins, which would improve economic performance in the country while at the same time achieving the international targets toward decarbonization.
In these policy exercises, there are two important procedural aspects. First, we confine the analysis to the use of a tax on CO2 emissions and not on overall emissions of greenhouse gases, GHG hereafter. Second, although we consider and report the effects of the different policies on the emissions of other GHG and air pollutants, these are not the focus of the current article. Our focus is exclusively on CO2 emissions. This approach is consistent with the way carbon emissions are currently taxed in Portugal, as well as the terms of the current policy debate on the matter.
This paper uses a multi-sector, multi-household dynamic computable general equilibrium model of the Portuguese. Previous versions of this model are documented in [27,28] and were used to address several energy and climate policy issues (see [29,30,31,32,33,34]). The current version of the model has a detailed description of the tax system including energy taxation. It features a fine differentiation of consumer and producer goods, particularly energy products. It captures the heterogeneity in income and consumption patterns by considering five differentiated household groups.
General equilibrium models have been used extensively in energy and environmental studies. Our approach follows the tradition of the early models developed in [35,36]. This means considering a highly disaggregated modeling of the economy in which the economic behavior of individual agents responds to prices and other market incentives and in which equilibrium outcomes are the result of their market interactions. In addition, such an approach considers a rather detailed specification of the tax system and government accounts. In its specifics, however, it is more directly linked to the contributions in, for example, [37,38,39,40,41]). In turn, thematically, this research is closer to [9,13,22,25]. This means a much greater detailed specification of the energy and environmental sectors, coupled with the consideration of individual and market intertemporal dynamics.
This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present in very general terms the DGEP model and discuss some implementation issues. In Section 3, we highlight some of the areas that were upgraded in this version of the model with direct relevance for this research. Section 4 presents the simulation results for a simple replacement of the ISP with a CO2 tax. Section 5 does the same but includes the extra CO2 taxation necessary to achieve IPCC goals. Finally, Section 6 offers a summary of the results, policy recommendations, and some thoughts about future research.

2. The Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model

What follows is a very brief description of the general features and implementation of the dynamic computable general equilibrium model of the Portuguese economy, DGEP hereafter (see [25] for further details). In addition, and in order to provide a better understanding of the main features of the model, we provide some basic information about the model structure and parametrization of an aggregate version of the model in Appendix A.

2.1. The General Features

The dynamic multi-sector general equilibrium model of the Portuguese economy incorporates fully dynamic optimization behavior, detailed household accounts, detailed industry accounts, a comprehensive modeling of the public sector activities, and an elaborate description of the energy sectors. We consider a decentralized economy. There are four types of agents in the economy: households, firms, the public sector, and the foreign sector. All agents face financial constraints that frame their choices. All agents are price takers and have perfect foresight. See Figure 1 for a depiction of the general structure of the model and Figure 2 for the structure of its energy module.
Households and firms implement optimal choices, as appropriate, to maximize their objective functions. Households maximize their intertemporal utilities subject to an equation of motion for financial wealth, thereby generating optimal consumption, labor supply, and savings behaviors. We consider five household income groups per quintile. While the general structure of household behavior is the same for all household groups, preferences, income, wealth, and taxes are household-specific, as are consumption demands, savings, and labor supply. [See [41] for an alternative multi-criteria approach.]
Firms maximize the net present value of their cash flow, subject to the equation of motion for capital stock to yield optimal output, labor demand, and investment demand. We consider twenty-four production sectors covering the whole spectrum of economic activity in the country. These include energy-producing sectors, such as electricity and petroleum refining, other EU-ETS sectors, such as transportation, textiles, wood pulp and paper, chemicals and pharmaceuticals, rubber, plastic and ceramics, and primary metals, as well as sectors not in the EU-ETS, such as agriculture, basic manufacturing, and construction. While the general structure of production behavior is the same for all sectors, technologies, capital endowments, and taxes are sector-specific, as are output supply, labor demand, energy demand, and investment demand. The public sector and the foreign sector evolve in a way that is determined by the economic conditions and their respective financial constraints.
All economic agents interact in different markets. The general market equilibrium is defined by market clearing in product markets, labor markets, financial markets, and the market for investment goods. The equilibrium of the product market reflects the national income accounting identity and the different expenditure allocations of the output by sector of economic activity. The total amount of a commodity supplied to the economy, be it produced domestically, or imported from abroad, must equal the total end-user demand for the product, including the demand by households, by the public sector, its use as an intermediate demand, and its application as an investment good. See Figure 1 for a stylized presentation of the model.
The total labor supplied by the different households, adjusted by an exogenous and constant unemployment rate, is endogenously determined. It must equal the total labor demanded by the different sectors of economic activity. There is only one equilibrium wage rate, although this translates into different household-specific effective wage rates, based on household-specific levels of human capital which obviously differ by quartile of income. Different firms buy shares of the same aggregate labor supply. Implicitly, this means that we do not consider differences in the composition of labor demand among the different sectors of economic activity, in terms of the incorporated human capital levels. Saving by households and the foreign sector equals the value of domestic investment plus the budget deficit.
The evolution of the economy is described by the optimal change in the stock variables—household-specific financial wealth and sector-specific private capital stock, as well as their respective shadow prices. The evolution of the stocks of public debt and foreign debt act as resource constraints in the overall economy. The endogenous and optimal changes in these stock variables—investment, saving, budget deficit, and current account deficit—provide the link between subsequent periods. The model can be conceptualized as a large set of nonlinear difference equations, where flow variables are determined through optimal control rules.
The intertemporal path for the economy is described by the behavioral equations, the equations of motion for the stock and shadow price variables, and the market equilibrium conditions. We define the steady-state growth path as an intertemporal equilibrium trajectory in which all the flow and stock variables grow at the same rate while market and shadow prices are constant.

2.2. Calibration

The model is calibrated with data for the period 2005–2014 and stock values for 2015. The calibration of the model is designed to allow the model to replicate as its most fundamental base case, a stylized steady state of the economy, as defined by the trends and information contained in the data set. In the absence of any policy changes, or any other exogenous changes, the model’s implementation will just replicate into the future such stylized economic trends. Counterfactual simulations thus allow us to identify the marginal effects of any policy or exogenous change as deviations from the base case. The use of data for a long period in the calibration process, specifically a ten-year window covering a full business cycle, allows us to capture the long-term economic trends for the economy without undue contamination by business cycle effects. The period under consideration represents the most recent period for which at the time of the model development it was possible to gather comprehensive and consistent data and parameter calibration sets, due to the high demands of the model.
The existence of a steady state imposes three types of calibration restrictions. First, it determines the value of critical production parameters, such as adjustment costs and depreciation rates, given the initial capital stocks. These stocks, in turn, are determined by assuming that the observed levels of investment are such that the ratios of capital to GDP do not change in the steady state. Second, the need for constant public debt and foreign debt to GDP ratios implies that the steady-state budget deficit and the current account deficit are a fraction of the respective stocks of debt equal to the steady-state growth rate. Finally, the exogenous variables, such as public or international transfers, have to grow at the steady-state growth rate. As an indication, for calibration purposes, the steady-state growth rate considered, i.e., the average GDP growth rate for the calibration period was 0.1%.

2.3. Numerical Implementation

The dynamic general equilibrium model is fully described by the behavioral equations and accounting definitions, and thus constitutes a system of nonlinear equations and nonlinear first-order difference equations. No objective function is explicitly specified, on account that each of the individual problems (the household, firm, and public sector) are set as first order and Hamiltonian conditions. These are implemented and solved using the GAMS (general algebraic modeling system) software and the MINOS nonlinear programming solver.
MINOS uses a reduced gradient algorithm generalized by means of a projected Lagrangian approach to solve mathematical programs with nonlinear constraints. The projected Lagrangian approach employs linear approximations for the nonlinear constraints and adds a Lagrangian and penalty term to the objective to compensate for approximation error. This series of sub-problems is then solved using a quasi-Newton algorithm to select a search direction and step length.

2.4. The Reference Scenario and the Identification of the Effects of Policies

The reference scenario provides a trajectory for the economy through 2050. The reference scenario embodies several assumptions regarding climate policy, which are superimposed on the steady-state trajectory used in the calibration of the model. The main assumptions in our reference scenario are as follows. First, we assume that the current levels of carbon taxation persist through 2050. Second, we recognize that the major coal-fired power plants ceased operations at the end of their life span, and no additional coal generation capacity is scheduled for installation. As such, coal is exclusively used outside the electricity generation sector. Third, we assume that fossil fuel prices follow forecasts given by the International Energy Agency [42]. Although fossil fuel price forecasts are notoriously imprecise and volatile, the effects of assuming different price scenarios would not change the main message of the paper, although it would necessarily change some of the actual figures presented.
The effects of the different policy experiments are obtained by comparing the results of the counterfactual simulations against the results under the reference scenario. Specifically, for any given year, effects are presented as percentage deviations of the counterfactual results from the base case results for the same year. Accordingly, say for 2030, the effects of a given policy are measured as the deviation of the outcome of such policy in 2030 from the base case outcome in 2030. This provides a measure of the effects of policies that is independent of the actual reference scenario.
Now, by their very nature general equilibrium results are generated simultaneously considering all possible interactions and feedback among the different variables in the model. For the sake of clarity of presentation, however, we present the effects of the different policies in a sequential manner. We start by considering the effects of the different policies on energy prices. This is the point of the initial impact of the different policies. Then, we consider the effects on the different energy markets. We consider changes in the levels and composition of energy demand and energy generation. Ultimately, this also allows us to measure the environmental impacts of the policies. Then, we consider how the changes in energy prices affect the economy both at the macroeconomic level and at the industry levels. Finally, we consider the effects on households and, specifically, the welfare effects of the policies on different income groups.

3. Some Extensions to the DGEP Model

In this section, we provide more detailed information about some of the new features of the DGEP model, which are directly relevant to this research.

3.1. A Detailed Disaggregation of Production Sectors and Energy Inputs

We consider 24 sectors of economic activity encompassing all areas of economic activity. See Table 1 for the list of sectors as well as for some basic descriptive statistics.
This disaggregation allows us to identify the sectors of economic activity that produce goods that are internationally traded and those that do not. The sectors engaged in significant international trade include petroleum refining, food, textiles, wood, chemicals, rubber, basic metals, equipment, and transportation. These sectors account for 90% of exports. Yet, they represent just 28.5% of total output and 17.9% of total employment. Equally important, they are very high energy-intensive sectors, which are responsible for 45.7% of total energy expenditures.
In turn, we consider eleven types of energy inputs: crude oil; coal; natural gas; butane; propane; LPG; fuel oil; gasoline; diesel; electricity; and biomass.

3.2. A Detailed Specification of the Energy Taxation

The tax on petroleum products raised EUR 3.086 billion in 2015, approximately 1.8% of GDP and 5% of total public sector receipts, including tax revenues and social contributions.
The final sale price of energy products includes the following components: the base price per physical unit; the tax on petroleum products; and an additional value tax that is levied as a fraction of the base price plus the unit tax. Specifically, the tax on petroleum products, the ISP, includes a basic unit tax; the contribution for road service design to finance maintenance of the national road network; and an add-on tax on emissions of CO2. Table 2 includes details about these three components for a whole variety of fuels.

3.3. A Detailed Specification of GHG Emissions and other Air Pollutants

We incorporate in the model GHG emissions considered within the common reporting framework of the IPCC framework (see, for example, [1]). which represent the whole universe of GHG pollutants in Portugal: carbon dioxide (CO2); methane (CH4); nitrous oxide (N2O); hydrofluorocarbons (HFC); [perfluorocarbons (PFC); and sulfur hexafluoride (SF6) (See Figure 3).
Of the GHG considered, carbon dioxide, and in a small part methane, are directly related to the combustion of fossil fuels. In turn, the bulk of emissions from methane and remaining GHG derive mostly from agriculture and a variety of industrial processes.
In turn, we incorporate in the model the air pollutants considered within the National Emission Ceiling Directive of the European Energy Agency [43]: nitrogen oxide (NOx); sulfur dioxide (SO2); particulate matter (PM) 10 μm in diameter and 2.5 μm in diameter; volatile organic compounds (VOCs); carbon monoxide (CO); and ammonia (NH3) (See Figure 4).
These air pollutants are induced by the combustion of fossil fuels, either directly as is the case of nitrogen oxide and sulfur dioxide, or indirectly by road transportation activities such as particulate matter, volatile organic matter, and carbon monoxide. These are the relevant co-pollutants when we consider policies designed to reduce carbon dioxide emissions.
We model emissions of the different GHG and air pollutants in two different ways. For emissions that are generated by fossil fuel combustion, i.e., the co-pollutants with carbon dioxide, we model emissions as a direct function of the amount of the fossil fuel used in the corresponding activities. For emissions that are induced by agriculture and industrial processes, we modeled them as a fixed function of the output of each of the different production sectors or activities.
From a conceptual perspective, for fossil fuel-based emissions, carbon dioxide, and its co-pollutants, we capture the following three effects: effects due to fossil fuel switching; effects due to changes in the level of economic activity; and effects due to changes in the composition of economic activity. For process-based emissions, we capture only the last two effects.

4. Energy Taxation Reform with an Environmental Focus

To establish the effects of replacing the ISP with an equivalent CO2 tax we start by analyzing the effects, in isolation, of a CO2 tax of the magnitude necessary to replace the current ISP energy taxation. In this case, the CO2 tax is levied in addition to the current ISP taxation. We refer to this scenario henceforth as CF1. Then, we compare this scenario with a revenue-neutral experiment, in which the CO2 tax replaces the ISP taxation. We refer to this scenario as CF2. We present summary simulation results in Table 3, Table 4, Table 5, Table 6, Table 7 and Table 8.

4.1. On the Effects of a CO2 Tax under the Current Energy Taxation Framework

The CF1 scenario corresponds to the implementation of a CO2 tax of the magnitude necessary to replace the ISP, without actually replacing the ISP. The magnitude of the carbon tax necessary for this purpose is endogenously determined. Simulation results determined that the magnitude of the carbon tax is EUR 114 per ton of CO2, yielding additional tax revenues that are approximately 1.85% of the GDP.

4.1.1. Effects on the Energy Markets and Emissions

The introduction of this CO2 tax leads to an increase in energy prices of 13.91%, which leads to a decrease in energy demand by 12.40%. The price of domestic electricity generation increases by 12.59%, which leads to a 10.17% decrease in domestic production and a 12.81% increase in imports. Overall electricity demand declines by 9.80%. Accordingly, the share of electricity in final energy demand increases by 2.97%.
The introduction of this CO2 tax leads to a reduction in CO2 emissions of 36.02%, which represents 53.8% of the 2010 levels. Significant reductions are also induced in other GHG emissions, in particular, CH4 and N2O emissions, with smaller reductions in emissions observed for HP, PF, and SF6. In turn, the emissions of air pollutants are reduced greatly as well. This is true, particularly, for NOx, SO2, and VOC emissions, and less so for CO and PM emissions.

4.1.2. Macroeconomic and Distributional Effects

The macroeconomic effects of the CO2 tax are naturally adverse. GDP declines by 5.21% linked directly on the supply side to the reduction in investment by 1.33% and employment by 2.71%, and on the demand side by a reduction in private consumption of 1.21%. The consumer price index, CPI hereafter, increases by 2.32%. In turn, foreign debt increases by 3.70%, with greater reliance on relatively cheaper foreign goods. Finally, there is, by construction, a reduction of 12.66% in public debt.
The industries that are the most adversely affected in terms of their output are petroleum refining and electricity generation, as expected, as well as rubber, plastic and ceramics, basic metals, equipment, and transportation, as well as textiles, wood, and chemicals. These are all energy-intensive sectors that produce internationally traded goods.
Overall, there is an aggregate household welfare loss of 1.34%. Across the different household income groups, this loss is felt in a regressive manner. Indeed, the lowest income group suffers a loss of 1.85% while the highest income group loses just 1.02%. Accordingly, the factor of regressivity is 1.8.

4.2. On the Effects of Replacing the ISP with a CO2 Tax

In a CF2 simulation, we use the proceeds of the EUR 114 per ton of CO2 tax discussed above to replace the ISP in a revenue-neutral manner. Effectively, this experiment consists in transforming the ISP from a tax based on the energy content of the different fuels into an environmental tax based on CO2 emissions content.

4.2.1. Effects on Energy Markets and Emissions

Energy prices increase marginally by 0.55% and energy demand declines by just 4.36%. The price of electricity generation increases by 7.31%, which leads to a reduction of 5.37% in production. The production from renewables increases by 7.83%, while imports increase by 9.20%. Overall, the share of electricity in final energy demand declines by 0.80%. Compared to CF1, all results under CF2 are smaller. The most important differences in CF2 are the increase in electricity production from renewable sources and the relative decline in the share of electricity in final demand.
Under CF2, CO2 emissions declined by 28.26%. This means that emissions by 2030 represent 60.2% of emissions in 2010. The remaining emissions of both GHG and air pollution are also less pronounced but maintain the patterns observed before. The lower reductions compared to CF1 are due to the replacement of the energy taxes as opposed to the mere addition of a CO2 tax.

4.2.2. Macroeconomic and Distributional Effects

The substitution of the energy taxes with a CO2 tax leads to a decline in GDP of 1.19% with private investment remaining essentially unchanged and employment declining by just 0.56%. The CPI shows a small increase of 0.38% and for private consumption, a marginal decline of 0.12%. Foreign debt increases but just by 2.26% while, naturally, the public debt by definition is just marginally affected. Overall, compared to CF1, we observe smaller adverse macroeconomic effects.
The reduction in economic activity observed at the aggregate level hides some interesting industry effects. While electricity generation declines, the production of the refining sector increases, albeit only marginally. This reflects the switch in the focus of taxation of the sector but not a meaningful net increase in the tax burden on the sector. Along the same lines, transportation services also show increased production. The remaining industries that are adversely affected are the same as under CF1 but with greatly reduced effects under CF2, in particular the cases of chemicals, basic metals, and equipment.
The adverse household welfare effects are now much smaller, a loss of just 0.10%. Yet, the same patterns of regressivity can be observed, as the lowest household income group sees a loss of 0.22% and the highest income group of less than 0.08%. The factor of regressivity is 2.7.

5. On the Effects of Energy Taxation Reform while Reaching IPCC Targets

Having reached this point, it is clear that there are benefits to energy taxation reform. It is also clear that there are adverse efficiency and distributional effects. More fundamentally, this reform does not generate the reductions in CO2 emissions necessary to reach the IPCC 2018 targets.
In this new set of experiments, we consider the effects of energy tax reform while at the same time increasing CO2 taxation to the levels necessary to reach IPCC emissions targets. The new levels of CO2 taxation are, naturally, much larger than what would be strictly necessary to replace the ISP. In terms of the experiments considered, we look first to a case in which the revenues from the CO2 taxation in excess of what is necessary to finance the energy taxation reform reverts to the general public budget, i.e., a non-recycling case. We refer to this scenario henceforth as CF3. Second, we consider the recycling of these extra CO2 revenues in ways conducive to improving the economic and distributional outcomes. We refer to this scenario henceforth as CF4. We present the simulation results in Table 3, Table 4, Table 5, Table 6, Table 7 and Table 8, as before.

5.1. Effects of Energy Taxation Reform without Revenue Recycling

To reach a reduction in CO2 emissions by 2030 of 45% relative to 2010 levels, we need a CO2 tax rate that increases from EUR 114 to 190 per ton of CO2. As before, these levels are endogenously determined in the model simulations. We consider an increasing level of taxation reflecting the increasing marginal costs of emissions abating.

5.1.1. Effects on Energy Markets and Emissions

Under CF3, energy prices increase by 8.52% and energy demand decreases by 10.58%. The price of electricity generation increases by 12.66%, which leads to a 9.54% reduction in production. Production of electricity from renewable energy resources increases by 5.89% while imports increase by 14.15%. Overall, the share of electricity in final energy demand increases by 1.59%.
Compared to CF2, results in CF3 are of a much greater magnitude, in some cases almost doubling the effect, which suggests rapidly increasing marginal abatement costs. Qualitatively, the most important difference is the increase in the relative role of electricity in final energy demand directly induced by a change in the relative prices of electricity to fossil fuels.
Under CF3, CO2 emissions decrease by 37.64%. As such, emissions by 2030 will represent 52.7% of emissions in 2010, which marginally exceeds what is required under the IPCC target. GHG and air pollution emissions are much reduced compared to CF2 due to higher levels of CO2 taxation.
Reductions in emissions across the board are similar to the ones observed under CF1—a case in which a CO2 tax of EUR 114 per ton is imposed on top of the existing energy tax system. This suggests that from an environmental perspective, a carbon tax of EUR 114 per ton of CO2 added to the status quo has the same environmental effects as a tax starting at EUR 114 and increases to EUR 190 by 2030, which includes the replacement of current energy taxes.

5.1.2. Macroeconomic and Distributional Effects

Under CF3, there is a decrease in GDP of 3.97%, with private investment decreasing by 0.61% and employment decreasing by 2.03%. The CPI increases by 1.65% and private consumption decreases by 0.78%. Foreign debt increases by 3.59% while public debt decreases by 1.53% due to the added CO2 tax revenues and despite a decreasing tax base.
Overall, compared to CF2, we observe significantly larger negative macroeconomic effects. This reinforces the evidence supporting sharply increasing marginal abatement costs for CO2 emissions. More importantly, compared to CF1—a case with similar environmental effects—the adverse macroeconomic effects are now clearly smaller, although still sizeable.
Under CF3, the industries most affected include electricity production, petroleum refining, agriculture, mining, textiles, wood, chemicals, rubber, basic metals, equipment, trade, and transportation. These are essentially the same industries that are most affected under CF2, although the adverse effects are now larger. In particular, the adverse effects on petroleum refining, trade, and transportation are significantly larger. In turn, compared to CF1, all of these adverse effects are smaller, in particular for sectors such as refining and transportation, sectors that are directly affected by the current energy taxation.
The adverse household welfare effects under CF3 are a loss of 0.86%. Yet, the same patterns of regressivity can be observed, as the lowest income group sees a welfare loss of over 1.25% and the highest income group is 0.65%. The factor of regressivity is 1.9. Overall, the adverse distributional effects are also significantly larger under CF3 than under CF2. More importantly, again, the adverse distributional effects under CF3 compare favorably to the ones observed under CF1 while displaying a similar pattern of regressivity.

5.2. Effects of Energy Tax Reform on Revenue Recycling

In CF4, the extra tax revenues generated by the additional CO2 taxation over what is needed to finance the energy tax reform are recycled in the economy through lower taxation at other tax margins. This means that this case, CF4 is strictly revenue neutral. Specifically, the recycling of additional revenue is conducted as follows: 50% for an investment tax credit, ITC hereafter, applicable to the traded goods sectors and 50% to reductions in personal income tax, IRS hereafter, divided into equal amounts across the different income groups; both mechanisms associated with broad energy efficiency gains.

5.2.1. Effects on Energy Markets and Emissions

Under CF4, energy prices increase by 3.72% and energy demand decreases by 4.47%. The price of electricity generation increases by 3.65%, which leads to a reduction of 1.75% in production. The production of electricity from renewable energy increases by 9.50%, while electricity imports increase by 6.06%. Overall, the share of electricity in final energy demand increases by 2.99%. Compared to CF3, the adverse effects on energy prices and demand are much smaller under CF4. This is particularly true for electricity prices and demand, which contributes to a much larger increase in the share of electricity in final energy demand.
Under CF4, CO2 emissions decrease by 34.76%. This means that emissions by 2030 represent 55.1% of emissions in 2010, which is on target to meet the IPCC goal of 55% of 2010 levels. Emissions of the other GHG also decline substantially, except for HF and PF, which actually increase. Air pollutant emissions also fall significantly with the exception of NH3. Compared with CF3, under CF4, we see less favorable emission reductions across the board. This is normal and it is a manifestation of the rebound effect. We allowed for a greater than necessary reduction in CO2 emissions in CF3 to account for the rebound effect under recycling.

5.2.2. Macroeconomic and Distributional Effects

Under CF4, there is a 1.46% increase in GDP, with private investment increasing by 1.63% and employment by 0.90%. The CPI increases by 0.53% and private consumption increases by 1.18%. Foreign debt decreases by 0.90%, while public debt decreases by 3.59% due to the increase in economic activity. Compared to CF3, as desired, we observe a reversal of the adverse macroeconomic effects. Under CF4, there is an increase in production for most sectors. Electricity, mining, and rubber, however, are still affected adversely in a significant manner. This implies that while the recycling mechanisms have led to a reversion of the bulk of the adverse macroeconomic effects, there are still specific industries that need further consideration in terms of cost mitigation strategies.
Under CF4, household welfare gains are 1.09%. Furthermore, these effects are progressive in nature as the lower income group gains 2.51% while the highest income group gains just 0.53%. This means that under CF4, the adverse distributional effects both at the aggregate level and in terms of the regressive pattern that we observed under CF3 have been reversed.

5.2.3. On the Effects of Different Recycling Mechanisms

We now consider the decomposition of the CF4 scenario into its personal income tax and investment tax credit components in order to identify the mechanisms behind the overall CF4 results. Scenario CF4A considers carbon tax revenue recycling exclusively at the personal income tax level, while CF4B considers carbon tax revenue recycling exclusively through investment tax credits.
Recycling the additional CO2 tax revenues after replacing the ISP at only the IRS level leads to the reversal of the negative distributional and regressive effects of the policy without reversing the adverse economic effects. Indeed, comparable emissions reductions leads to much greater welfare gains and much greater output losses. In turn, recycling the additional CO2 tax revenues with a corporate income tax credit for private investment leads to the reversal of the negative economic impact of the policy without eliminating the negative and regressive distributional effects of the policy. Overall, these results indicate the need for a multifaceted recycling approach if the adverse economic and distributive effects of decarbonization are to be reversed.

6. Conclusions and Policy Implications

In this paper, we address the issue of energy taxation reform with an environmental focus in Portugal. We address this issue in the context of a dynamic disaggregated computable general equilibrium model of the Portuguese economy. We analyze the environmental, macroeconomic, and distributional effects of different policies allowing for current energy taxes to be replaced with a carbon tax while at the same time reaching the IPCC 2018 emissions reduction targets.
Our simulation results show, first, that a carbon tax of EUR 114 per ton imposed on top of the current energy taxation is enough to achieve the IPCC 2030 targets. It does so, however, at a high macroeconomic and distributional cost. In turn, replacing energy taxes with such a carbon tax would lead to smaller, although still significant, environmental effects and much smaller adverse macroeconomic and distributional effects.
This suggests that just replacing energy taxation with a carbon tax may be a good second-best alternative compared to the status quo. This is particularly so if political constraints do not allow for the implementation of a well-designed carbon tax with the proper recycling mechanisms. Just replacing the current energy taxes with a carbon tax would greatly mitigate the adverse economic and distributional effects of a stand-alone carbon tax, while still achieving important environmental goals in a context of strict tax revenue neutrality. In addition, this second-best alternative would improve the efficiency of the tax system by implicitly eliminating the myriad of perverse fossil fuel subsidies consigned in the current energy taxation system. Replacing the current energy taxation with a carbon tax completely sidesteps the politically charged issue of reducing or eliminating fossil fuel subsidies.
Our simulation results show, second, that to achieve the IPCC 2030 targets while replacing the current energy taxes ISP requires a carbon tax increasing to EUR 190 by 2030. The marginal burden of the additional tax in terms of the economic and distributional impact sharply increases compared to the previous cases. This suggests a pattern of sharply increasing marginal abatement costs.
Significantly, the case of achieving the IPCC targets while replacing the ISP with carbon taxation has similar CO2 emissions effects compared to the case of adding carbon taxation to the ISP burden, as in this case. Yet, the economic and distributional effects are less adverse when the current energy taxes are replaced. This means that from a policy perspective, the strategy of replacing the current energy taxation with a carbon tax while at the same time reaching IPCC levels clearly dominates a strategy in which the IPCC levels are achieved by carbon taxation while maintaining the current patterns of energy taxation.
Finally, our simulation results show that proper recycling of revenues in excess of what is needed to replace current energy taxes allows for positive economic and distributional outcomes while keeping the environmental benefits, thereby reverting the adverse effect observed. It is important to note that the recycling strategy presented in this paper is illustrative only. It is not the only way of achieving multiple dividends or the most desirable way to do so.
In this vein, we also show that the recycling of revenues through the demand side and personal income tax reductions are fundamental to achieving the desirable distributional effects of these policies, while the recycling of revenues through the supply side and investment tax credits are fundamental to achieving desirable macroeconomic outcomes.
Overall, our analysis indicates a clear specific path in the quest for decarbonization. First, replace current energy taxation with a carbon tax; second, target the carbon taxation levels necessary to achieve the relevant emissions goals; and third, use extra tax revenues to reverse any potential adverse macroeconomic and distributional effects of carbon taxation. In the process, this would be a way around the fossil fuel subsidies, which would effectively disappear.
Furthermore, our analysis indicates a clear framework for decarbonization efforts. There is no way to reach decarbonization without duly considering the potential adverse macroeconomic, budgetary, international competitiveness, and distributional effects of such policies. These adverse effects, if not addressed, would likely make it impossible to reach a political consensus on such policies. In this context, revenue neutrality—with its reduction in other tax distortions and the achievement of desirable economic and welfare outcomes—has to be the central piece of any decarbonization policies. As a corollary, addressing the issue of decarbonization in a comprehensive manner is of paramount importance. This is so because only with comprehensive reform will it be possible to neutralize such adverse effects. Piecewise measures are bound to lead to undesirable economic and welfare effects.
Naturally, there are several important extensions of the analysis in this paper. First, from a policy perspective, it would be important to develop a closer analysis of the effects of taxing all GHG emissions and not just CO2 emissions in light of our evidence that the taxation of CO2 emissions in and of itself affects other GHG emissions. In the same vein, and in the direction of a unified and comprehensive approach, it would be important to consider a comprehensive reform of all current environmental taxation including taxation of air pollutants and other environmental externalities, and not just of energy taxation. Second, it would relevant to analyze the robustness of the magnitude of the effects of the different policies on different fossil fuel price scenarios. Different fossil fuel prices would differently affect emission projections, as well as the ability of the domestic economy, to counteract the adverse effects of decarbonization policies. Third, it would be informative to compare the effects on energy markets implied by these economic policies with the projections of decarbonization scenarios based on technological or engineering approaches that often inform actual energy policies. Fourth, it would be decisive from a policy perspective to model and analyze the interaction between the tax-based decarbonization strategies consider in this paper and other related policies, such as incentives for private investment in clean technologies or the development of new technologies based on the use of hydrogen.
Finally, although this is an energy policy paper applied to the Portuguese economy and its policy implications are directly relevant to the Portuguese case, its interest is far from parochial. The quest for decarbonization is universal. The existence of inefficient energy taxation mechanisms incorporating fossil fuel subsidies is widespread. The concerns over the macroeconomic and distributional effects of renewable energy finance and environmental policies, in general, are unavoidable if there is some hope of meaningful policies ever being adopted.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, A.M.P. and R.M.P.; methodology, A.M.P. and R.M.P.; software, R.M.P.; validation, R.M.P.; formal analysis, A.M.P.; writing—original draft preparation, A.M.P.; writing—review and editing, A.M.P. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

Not available.

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank four anonymous referees for their very perceptive comments and suggestions. An early version of this paper was circulated as a working paper by the Research Department of the Portuguese Ministry of the Economy.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. The dynamic general equilibrium model—the model structure.
Table A1. The dynamic general equilibrium model—the model structure.
The Production Sector
Y t = A t ( γ v a   V A t ρ v a + ( 1 γ v a )   A G G _ E t ρ v a ) 1 ρ v a (A1)
V A t = A v a , t ( L t d H K t ) θ L K t θ K K G t 1 θ L θ K (A2)
K p , t + 1 = ( 1 δ k ) K p , t + I p , t μ k I p , t 2 K p , t (A3)
N C F t = Y t ( 1 + τ f s s c ) w t ( L t d H K t ) I p , t I W , t ( 1 ρ I ) τ v a t , I I p , t p e , t E t τ c i t ( Y t ( 1 + τ f s s c ) w t ( L t d H K t ) α I p , t α I w , t p e , t E t ) + τ i t c , I I p , t + τ i t c , R I I w , t (A4)
α = [ 1 ( 1 + g ) N D E P ] / N D E P [ 1 ( 1 + g ) 1 ] (A5)
θ L γ V A A t ( γ v a   V A t ρ v a + ( 1 γ v a ) A G G _ E t ρ v a ) 1 ρ v a 1   V A t ρ V A = ( 1 + τ F S S C ) w t L t d H K t (A6)
I t K t = 1 2 μ I [ 1 + ( 1 ρ I ) τ V A T , I α τ C I T τ I T C ] ( 2 μ I q t + 1 K ) 1 ( 1 + r t + 1 ) (A7)
q t K = ( 1 τ C I T ) θ K Y t K t + q t + 1 K 1 + r t + 1 [ 1 δ K + μ I ( I t K t ) 2 ] (A8)
The Energy Sector
A G G _ E t = A E , t ( γ E   C r u d e   O i l t ρ e + ( 1 γ E )   N T F t ρ e ) 1 ρ e (A9)
p e , t E t = p f e , t F E t + ( p c r u d e   o i l , t + e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r o i l τ c a r b o n )   C r u d e   O i l t (A10)
p f e , t F E t = i = 1 n ( p f , i , t + e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r f τ c a r b o n ) F i , t (A11)
( p f , i , t + e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r f τ c a r b o n ) θ f , j F i , t ( p f , j , t + e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r f τ c a r b o n ) θ f , i F j , t = 0 (A12)
θ E A G G _ E t F E t A t ( γ v a   V A t ρ v a + ( 1 γ v a ) A G G _ E t ρ v a ) 1 ρ v a 1 ( 1 γ E   )   A E , t ( γ E   C r u d e   O i l t ρ e + ( 1 γ E )   N T F t ρ e ) 1 ρ e 1 N T F t ρ e p f e , t = 0 (A13)
A G G _ E t C r u d e   O i l t ( 1 γ V A   ) A t ( γ v a   V A t ρ v a + ( 1 γ v a ) A G G _ E t ρ v a ) 1 ρ v a 1 γ E   A E , t ( γ E   C r u d e   O i l t ρ e + ( 1 γ E )   N T F t ρ e ) 1 ρ e 1 C r u d e   O i l t ρ e p c r u d e   o i l , t = 0 (A14)
N T F t = A E 2 , t ( φ c f R K ) t θ R K i = 1 n F i , t θ f , i (A15)
R K t + 1 = ( 1 δ r k ) R K t + I w , t μ r k I w , t 2 R K t (A16)
I w , t R K t = 1 2 μ r k ( 1 + ( 1 ρ I ) τ v a t , R I α   τ c i t τ i t c r ) ( 2 μ r k q t + 1 R K ) 1 ( 1 + r t + 1 ) (A17)
q t R K = π t R K t = ( 1 τ c i t ) θ R K Y t R K t + q t + 1 R K ( 1 + r ) ( ( 1 δ r k ) + μ r k ( I w , t R K t ) 2 ) (A18)
C a r b o n E m i s s i o n s t = f N e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r f F i , t + e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r o i l C r u d e   O i l t (A19)
The Household Sector
U a , t = σ σ 1 υ = 0 γ υ β υ [ c a + υ , t + υ σ 1 σ + B a + υ , t + υ σ 1 σ ] (A20)
υ = 0 γ υ [ 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t + v ] v ( 1 + τ V A T , C ) C a + v , t + v = T W a , t (A21)
T W a , t H W a , t + F W a , t + P V F t (A22)
H W a , t = m = 0 ( γ 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t + m ) m ( ( 1 τ p i t ) ( ( 1 τ w s s c ) w t + m ( L ¯ a + m , t + m ) H K t + m + T R t + m ) + R t + m L S T t + m ) (A23)
F W a , t = ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t 1 p d ) P D t 1 + ( 1 τ π ) N C F t 1 ( 1 + r t 1 f d ) F D t 1 + ( 1 τ p i t ) ( ( 1 τ w s s c ) w t 1 ( L ¯ a 1 , t 1 ) H K t 1 + T R t 1 ) + R t 1 L S T t 1     ( 1 + τ v a t ) C a 1 , t 1 (A24)
( 1 + τ v a t ) C t = [ 1 ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t 1 ) σ 1 γ β σ ] ( H W t + ( P D t F D t ) + P V F t ) (A25)
t = ( B ( 1 + τ v a t ) ( 1 τ w s s c ) ( 1 τ p i t ) w t ( 1 U R t ) H K t ) σ C t (A26)
The Public Sector
U p u b l i c = t [ ( C t t p 1 ) α C C G t 1 α C ]   ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t P D ) t (A27)
P D t + 1 = ( 1 + r t P D ) P D t + ( 1 + τ v a t , c g ) C G t + ( 1 + τ v a t , i g ) I G t + ( 1 + τ v a t , i h ) I H t + T R t T t (A28)
T t = P I T t + C I T t + V A T t + F S S C t + W S S C t + L S T t (A29)
K G t + 1 = ( 1 δ k g ) K G t + I G t μ k g I G t 2 K G t (A30)
H K t + 1 = ( 1 δ h k ) H K t + I H t μ h k I H t 2 H K t (A31)
q t + 1 P D ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t + 1 P D ) = q t P D ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t P D ) (A32)
q t + 1 P D = ( 1 α c ) ( C t p 1 C G t ) α C ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t P D ) (A33)
q t + 1 P D = q t + 1 k g ( 2 μ k g I G t K G t ) (A34)
q t K G = q t + 1 P D ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t P D ) ( ( τ π ( 1 τ c i t ) + τ c i t ) Y t K G t ) + q t + 1 k g ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t + 1 P D ) ( ( 1 δ k g ) + μ k g ( I G t K G t ) 2 ) (A35)
q t + 1 P D = q t + 1 h k ( 2 μ h k I H t H K t ) (A36)
q t H K = q t + 1 P D ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t P D ) ( ( τ p i t ( 1 τ f s s c ) ( 1 τ π ) ( 1 + τ c i t ) τ f s s c + τ w s s c ) Y t H K t ) + q t + 1 h k ( 1 + ( 1 τ r ) r t + 1 P D ) ( ( 1 δ h k ) + μ h k ( I H t H K t ) 2 ) (A37)
Market Equilibrium
( 1 U R t ) L S t = L t d (A38)
Y t = i = 1 n p f , i , t F i , t + p c r u d e   o i l , t C r u d e   O i l t + C t + I p , t + I w , t + C G t + I G t + I H t N X t (A39)
F D t + 1 = ( 1 + r t f d ) F D t + N X t R t (A40)
F W t = P D t F D t (A41)
Table A2. The dynamic general equilibrium model—the basic data set.
Table A2. The dynamic general equilibrium model—the basic data set.
Domestic spending data (% of Y 0 )
Y 0 GDP (billion Euros)166.2279
g 0 Long-term growth rate (%)0.01763
V A 0 Value added83.743
A G G _ E 0 Primary energy consumption expenditure2.557
C 0 Private consumption62.263
I p , 0 Private investment20.312
I w , 0 Private wind investment0.064
C G 0 Public consumption14.652
I G 0 Public capital investment3.411
I H 0 Public investment in education6.996
Primary energy demand (GJ as a % of Y 0 )
E 0 Primary fossil energy spending2.472
N T F 0 Non-transportation fuels0.584
F E 0 Fossil fuels (excluding crude oil)0.160
C r u d e O i l 0 Quantity of crude oil imports0.321
F Coal , 0 Quantity of coal imports0.082
F Natural   Gas , 0 Quantity natural gas imports0.077
Energy prices (€ per GJ)
p C r u d e   O i l , 0 Import price of crude oil6.14
p f , C o a l , 0 Import price of coal1.89
p f , N a t u r a l   G a s , 0 Import price of natural gas4.45
Foreign account data (% of Y 0 )
N X 0 Trade deficit7.697
r 0 F D F D 0 Interest payments of foreign debt3.157
R 0 Unilateral transfers11.413
C A D 0 Current account deficit1.913
F D 0 Foreign debt108.500
Public sector data (% of Y 0 )
T 0 Total tax revenue41.958
P I T 0 Personal income tax revenue5.710
C I T 0 Corporate income tax revenue3.110
V A T 0 Value-added tax revenue13.700
V A T c On private consumption expenditure10.669
V A T I On private investment expenditure1.902
V A T c g On public consumption expenditure0.649
V A T i g On public capital investment expenditure0.379
V A T i h On public investment in human capital0.101
W S S C 0 Social security tax revenues11.700
W S S C 1 , 0 Employers’ contributions5.600
W S S C 2 , 0 Workers’ contributions6.100
C a r b o n   T a x 0 CO2 tax0.000
L S T 0 Lump sum tax revenue7.738
T R t Social transfers15.915
r 0 P D P D 0 Interest payments of public debt2.497
D E F 0 Public deficit0.015
P D 0 Public debt85.800
Population and Employment Data (% of P O P 0 )
P O P 0 Population (in thousands)10.586
L 0 Active population5.587
U R 0 Unemployment rate0.058
Private wealth (% of Y 0 )
H W 0 Human wealth2574.498
F W 0 Financial wealth−22.700
P V F 0 Present value of the firm1429.101
N C F 0 Distributed profits17.930
Prices
w 0 Wage rate0.031
q 0 P D Shadow price of public debt−0.883
q 0 k Shadow price of private capital1.291
q 0 r k Shadow price of wind energy capital1.291
q 0 k g Shadow price of public capital1.104
q 0 h k Shadow price of human capital5.521
Capital stocks (% of Y 0 )
K 0 Private capital215.321
R K 0 Wind energy capital stock1.142
K G 0 Public capital stock73.415
H K 0 Human capital stock226.899
Table A3. The dynamic general equilibrium model—the structural parameters.
Table A3. The dynamic general equilibrium model—the structural parameters.
Household Parameters
βDiscount rate0.003
γ Probability of survival0.987
g P O P Population growth rate0.000
σ Elasticity of substitution 1.000
p 1 Leisure share parameter—C0.331
Production parameters
θ L Labor share in value-added aggregate—C0.506
θ K P Capital share in value-added aggregate—C 0.294
θ K G Public capital share in value-added aggregate—C0.200
σ V A Elasticity of substitution between value-added and energy0.400
σ Crude Elasticity of substitution between oil and other energy0.400
θ K R wind energy share in non-transportation fuels—C 0.146
θ E fossil energy share in non-transportation fuels—C 0.854
φ c f Wind energy price: quantity capacity utilization factor—C0.074
θ C o a l coal share in non-transportation fuels—C0.313
θ g a s natural gas share in non-transportation fuels—C0.687
γ V A CES scaling share between value-added and energy—C1.000
γ E CES scaling share between oil and other energy—C0.580
δ k Depreciation rate—private capital—C 0.060
μ k Adjustment costs coefficient—private capital—C 1.159
δ R k Depreciation rate—wind energy capital—C 0.028
μ R k Adjustment costs coefficient—wind energy capital—C1.952
A ˙ i / A i Exogenous rate of technological progress0.000
Emission factor
e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r o i l Emission factor for oil (tCO2 per TJ)72.600
e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r c o a l Emission factor for oil (tCO2 per TJ)90.200
e m i s s i o n _ f a c t o r g a s Emission factor for oil (tCO2 per TJ)55.800
Public Sector Parameters—Tax Parameters
τ p i t Effective personal income tax rate0.104
τ π Effective personal income tax rate on distributed profits0.112
τ r Effective personal income tax rate on interest income0.200
τ c i t Effective corporate income tax rate0.116
N D E P Time for fiscal depreciation of investment16.000
α Depreciation allowances for tax purposes0.735
ρ I Fraction of private investment that is tax exempt0.680
τ i t c , I Investment tax credit rate—private capital0.005
τ i t c , R I Investment tax credit rate—wind energy capital0.005
τ V A T , C Value-added tax rate on consumption0.212
τ v a t , I Value-added tax rate on investment0.094
τ v a t , c g Value-added tax rate on public consumption0.044
τ v a t , i g Value-added tax rate on public capital investment0.111
τ v a t , i h Value-added tax rate for public investment in human capital0.014
τ f s s c Firms’ social security contribution rate0.152
τ w s s c Workers’ social security contribution rate0.166
Public Sector Parameters—Outlay Parameters
1 α C Public consumption share0.215
δ k g Public infrastructure depreciation rate—C 0.020
μ k g Adjustment cost coefficient—C 2.392
δ h k Human capital depreciation rate—C0.000
μ h k Adjustment cost coefficient—C 13.817
Real interest rates
r , r F D , r P D Interest rate0.0291
C indicates the calibrated parameter.
Table A4. The dynamic general equilibrium model—model variables.
Table A4. The dynamic general equilibrium model—model variables.
Stock Variables
K t Private Capital
R K t Wind Energy Capital
K G t Public Capital
H K t Human Capital
P D t Public Debt
F D t Foreign Debt
F W a , t Financial Wealth
H W a , t Human Wealth
Shadow Prices
q t K Shadow Price of Private Capital
q t R K Shadow Price of Wind Energy Capital
q t K G Shadow Price of Public Capital
q t H K Shadow Price of Human Capital
q t P D Shadow Price of Public Debt
Production Variables
Y t Gross Domestic Product
V A t Value Added
L t d Labor Demand
I p , t Private Investment
P V F t Present Value of the Firm
N C F t Net Cash Flow
Energy Variables
A G G _ E t Aggregate Energy
N T F t Primary Demand for Non-transportation Fuels
E t Fossil Fuel Demand
F E t Fossil Fuels Composite (Excluding Crude Oil)
C r u d e   O i l t Primary Demand for Crude Oil
F i , t Fossil Fuels (Excluding Crude Oil), where i = c o a l ,   n a t u r a l   g a s
I W , t Private Investment in Wind Energy
Household Variables
C t Private Consumption
t Leisure
L S t Labor Supply
T W a , t Total Wealth
Public Sector Variables
C G t Public Consumption
I H t Human Capital Investment
I G t Public Capital Investment
T t Total Tax Revenue
P I T t Personal Income Tax Revenue
C I T t Corporate Income Tax Revenue
V A T t Value-Added Tax Revenue
F S S C t Firms’ Social Security Contributions
W S S C t Workers’ Social Security Contributions
L S T t Lump Sum Tax Revenue

References

  1. Masson-Delmotte, V.; Zhai, P.; Pörtner, H.-O.; Roberts, D.; Skea, J.; Shukla, P.; Pirani, A.; Moufouma-Okia, W.; Péan, C.; Pidcock, R.; et al. IPCC, 2018: Global Warming of 1.5 °C. An IPCC Special Report on the Impacts of Global Warming of 1.5 °C above Pre-Industrial Levels and Related Global Greenhouse Gas Emission Pathways, in the Context of Strengthening the Global Response to the Threat of Climate Change, Sustainable Development, and Efforts to Eradicate Poverty; IPCC: Geneva, Switzerland, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  2. European Commission. Clean Energy for All Europeans; Publication Office of the European Union: Luxembourg, Luxembourg, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  3. Parry, I. The Right Price. Financ. Dev. 2015, 52, 10–13. [Google Scholar]
  4. Parry, I.; Heine, D.; Lis, E.; Li, S. Getting Energy Prices Right: From Principle to Practice; International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  5. Coady, D.; Parry, I.; Shang, B. Energy Price Reform: Lessons for Policy Makers. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2018, 12, 197–219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Sovacool, B. Reviewing, Reforming and Rethinking Global Energy Subsidies: Toward a Political Economy Research Agenda. Ecol. Econ. 2017, 135, 150–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Rentschler, J.; Bazilian, M. Principles for Designing Effective Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reforms. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2017, 11, 138–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Coady, D.; Parry, I.; Sears, L.; Shang, B. How Large are Global Fossil Fuel Subsidies? World Dev. 2017, 91, 11–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Gelan, A. Kuwait’s Energy Subsidy Reduction: Examining Economic and CO2 Emissions Effects with or Without Compensation. Energy Econ. 2018, 71, 186–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Monasterolo, I.; Raberto, M. The Impact of Phasing out Fossil Fuel Subsidies on the Low Carbon Transition. Energy Policy 2019, 124, 355–370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. OECD. Environmental Taxation: A Guide for Policy Makers; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development: Paris, France, 2011. Available online: https://www.oecd.org/ (accessed on 2 January 2019).
  12. Marron, D.; Toder, E. Tax Policy Issues in Designing a Carbon Tax. Am. Econ. Rev. Pap. Proc. 2014, 104, 563–568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Williams, R., III. Environmental Taxation. Natl. Bur. Econ. Res. Work. Pap. 2016, 22303. Available online: https://www.nber.org/papers/w22303.84782 (accessed on 2 January 2019).
  14. High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices. Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices; Carbon Price Leadership Coalition, World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  15. Carbone, J.; Rivers, N. The Impacts of Unilateral Climate Policy on Competitiveness: Evidence from Computable General Equilibrium Models. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2017, 11, 24–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Renner, S.; Lay, J.; Greve, H. Household Welfare and CO2 Emission Impacts of Energy and Carbon Taxes in Mexico. Energy Economics 2018, 72, 222–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Zachman, G.; Fredriksson, G.; Claeys, G. The Distributional Effects of Climate Policies; Bruegel’s Weekly Newsletter: Bruxelles, Brussel, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  18. Fremstad, A.; Paul, M. The Impact of a Carbon Tax on Inequality. Energy Econ. 2019, 163, 88–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Pizer, W.; Sexton, S. Distributional Impacts of Energy Taxes. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2019, 13, 104–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Carbone, J.; Morgenstern, R.; Williams, R., III; Burtraw, D. Getting to an Efficient Carbon Tax: How the Revenue is Used Matters. Resour. Future 2014, 185, 33–37. [Google Scholar]
  21. Jorgenson, D. Time to Tax Carbon: Enhancing Environmental Quality and Economic Growth. Harv. Mag. 2014, 117, 53–79. [Google Scholar]
  22. Jorgenson, D.; Goettle, R.; Ho, M.; Wilcoxen, P. Carbon Taxes and Fiscal Reform in the United States. Natl. Tax J. 2015, 68, 121–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Marron, D.; Morris, A. How to Use Carbon Tax Revenues; Tax Policy Center, Urban Institute and Brookings Institution: Washington, DC, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  24. Metcalf, G. Paying for Pollution: Why a Carbon Tax is Good for America; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  25. Kirchner, M.; Sommer, M.; Krantena, K.; Kletzzan-Slamanig, D.; Kettner-Marx, C. CO2 Taxes, Equity and the double Dividend–Macroeconomic Model Simulation for Austria. Energy Policy 2019, 126, 294–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. RNC2050. Roteiro para a Neutralidade Carbónica (RNC2050). Estratégia de Longo Prazo para a Neutralidade Carbónica da Economia Portuguesa em 2050. R262/2019; Portuguese Ministry of the Environment and Energy Transition: Lisbon, Portugal, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  27. Pereira, A.; Pereira, R. On the environmental, economic and budgetary impacts of fossil fuel prices: A dynamic general equilibrium analysis of the Portuguese case. Energy Econ. 2014, 42, 248–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Pereira, A.; Pereira, R. DGEP—A Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of the Portuguese Economy: Model Documentation; Department of Economics, College of William and Mary: Williamsburg, WM, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  29. Pereira, A.; Pereira, R. Environmental fiscal reform and fiscal consolidation: The quest for the third dividend in Portugal. Public Financ. Rev. 2014, 42, 222–253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Pereira, A.; Pereira, R. The Role of Electricity for the Decarbonization of the Portuguese Economy—DGEP Technical Report. 2017. Available online: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/84782 (accessed on 2 January 2019).
  31. Pereira, R. The economic and budgetary impact of climate policy in Portugal: Carbon taxation in a dynamic general equilibrium model with endogenous public sector behavior. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2017, 67, 231–259. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Pereira, A.; Pereira, R. Achieving the triple dividend in Portugal: A dynamic general-equilibrium evaluation of a carbon tax indexed to emissions trading. J. Econ. Policy Reform 2019, 22, 148–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Pereira, A.; Pereira, R. On the relative roles of fossil fuel prices, energy efficiency, and carbon taxation in reducing carbon dioxide emissions. J. Environ. Plan. Manag. 2017, 60, 1825–1852. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Pereira, A.; Pereira, R.; Rodrigues, P. A new carbon tax in Portugal: A missed opportunity to achieve the triple dividend? Energy Policy 2016, 93, 110–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Borges, A.M.; Goulder, L.H. Decomposing the impact of higher energy prices on long-term growth, Chapter 8. In Applied General Equilibrium Analysis; Scarf, H.E., Shoven, J.B., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1984. [Google Scholar]
  36. Fullerton, D.; Shoven, J.; Whalley, J. A General Equilibrium Model for Tax Policy Evaluation; NBER, University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  37. Goulder, L.H.; Hafstead, M.A. A Numerical General Equilibrium Model for Evaluating U.S. Energy and Environmental Policies. In Working Paper; Stanford University: Stanford, CA, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  38. Bhattarai, K.; Haughton, J.; Tuerck, D. The economic effects of the fair tax: Analysis of results of a dynamic CGE model of the US economy. Int. Econ. Econ. Policy 2016, 13, 451–466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Chung, T.; Wende, S. On the Marginal Excess Burden of Taxation in an Overlapping Generations Model. ANU Work. Pap. Econ. Econom. 2017, 2017, 652. [Google Scholar]
  40. Annicchiarico, B.; Battles, S.; Di Dio, F.; Molina, P.; Zoppoli, P. GHG mitigation schemes and energy policies: A model-based assessment for the Italian economy. Econ. Model. 2017, 61, 495–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Nesticò, A.; Passaro, R.; Maselli, G.; Somma, P. Multi-criteria methods for the optimal localization of urban green areas. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 374, 133690. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. International Energy Agency. World Energy Outlook 2018. Available online: https://www.iea.org/reports/world-energy-outlook-2018 (accessed on 2 January 2019).
  43. European Environmental Energy. National Emissions Ceilings Directive. 2016. Available online: https://.eea.europa.eu/data-and-maps/data/national-emission-ceilings-nec-directive-inventory-16 (accessed on 2 January 2019).
Figure 1. The DGEP Model.
Figure 1. The DGEP Model.
Energies 16 01232 g001
Figure 2. The Energy Module.
Figure 2. The Energy Module.
Energies 16 01232 g002
Figure 3. Greenhouse gas emissions.
Figure 3. Greenhouse gas emissions.
Energies 16 01232 g003
Figure 4. Air pollutant emissions.
Figure 4. Air pollutant emissions.
Energies 16 01232 g004
Table 1. Sectors of economic activity: definition and basic information.
Table 1. Sectors of economic activity: definition and basic information.
OutputEmploymentExportsEnergyCO2
Emissions
Total100.0100.0100.0100.0100.0
Petroleum refining3.90.05.324.48.6
Electricity4.20.20.228.935.5
Biomass0.30.0-0.0
Agriculture3.610.21.81.82.7
Mining0.90.21.10.70.9
Food products, beverages, and tobacco5.62.27.82.02.2
Textiles2.84.311.31.32.3
Wood, and pulp and paper2.11.26.61.42.2
Chemicals and pharmaceuticals2.60.46.22.22.1
Rubber, plastics, and ceramics2.11.37.52.616.3
Basic metals and fabricated metal products2.11.88.21.01.1
Equipment manufacturing4.23.327.30.60.7
Water, sewage, and waste management1.20.80.70.71.0
Construction6.95.81.11.64.1
Wholesale and retail trade10.615.50.210.25.0
Transportation4.83.49.79.99.6
Accommodation and food services4.06.11.11.71.1
Information technology3.61.82.20.50.1
Finance and insurance4.81.81.10.50.2
Real estate7.21.0-0.40.1
Professional services6.613.00.71.41.0
Public administration5.35.9-2.61.4
Education3.76.9-0.70.3
Health4.78.7-1.91.3
Table 2. The ISP and its components.
Table 2. The ISP and its components.
UnitsTotal Tax Rate
(Euro per Unit)
Unit TaxRoad Contribution
(Euro per Unit)
CO2 Add-On
Butane/Propanekg0.024800.00799 0.01681
ElectricityMWh1.000001.00000
Fuel Oilkg0.036860.01565 0.02121
Natural GasGJ0.684290.30000 0.38429
Natural Gas (vehicular)GJ3.224292.84000 0.38429
Diesel (Colored and Marked)l0.094460.07751 0.01695
Diesel Heating Oill0.346950.33000 0.01695
Diesell0.406360.278410.111000.01695
Gasolinel0.621510.518950.087000.01556
LPG Autol0.270760.127880.123000.01988
Table 3. Long run [2030] effects: energy markets.
Table 3. Long run [2030] effects: energy markets.
CF1CF2CF3CF4CF4ACF4B
Carbon Tax114114120–190120–190120–190120–190
Energy Price13.910.558.523.729.033.47
Electricity Price12.597.3112.663.6513.593.30
Electricity Production−10.17−5.37−9.54−1.75−7.65−2.71
Thermal Generation−25.61−20.18−29.31−25.52−27.83−26.28
Renewable Energy Systems−2.187.835.899.507.858.48
Net Electricity Imports12.819.2014.156.0618.264.33
Energy Demand−12.40−4.36−10.58−4.47−8.62−5.36
Electricity Demand−9.80−5.13−9.16−1.62−7.23−2.59
% Electricity in Final Demand2.97−0.801.592.991.522.92
Percentage change from the corresponding year in the reference case.
Table 4. Long run [2030] effects: greenhouse gas and air pollutant emissions.
Table 4. Long run [2030] effects: greenhouse gas and air pollutant emissions.
CF1CF2CF3CF4CF4ACF4B
Greenhouse Gas Emissions
CO2 Emissions Relative to 201053.8%60.2%52.7%55.1%53.6%54.2%
Carbon Dioxide–CO2−36.02−28.26−37.64−34.76−36.16−35.34
Methane—CH4−25.29−16.57−26.75−23.39−25.01−24.04
Nitrous Oxide—N2O−30.73−22.39−32.16−29.03−30.56−29.66
Hydrofluorocarbons—HFC−5.66−0.94−4.072.56−3.803.56
Perfluorocarbons—PFC−4.96−0.96−3.692.02−3.312.60
Sulfur Hexafluoride—SF6−10.17−5.37−9.54−1.75−7.65−2.71
Air Pollutant Emissions
Nitrogen Oxide—NOx−37.22−29.01−37.90−34.97−36.44−35.57
Sulfur Dioxide—SO2−43.13−35.66−44.14−41.45−42.82−42.01
Volatile Org. Compounds—VOC−23.67−15.36−26.37−23.18−24.65−23.81
Carbon Monoxide—CO−51.08−45.62−54.54−52.74−53.39−53.20
Particulate Matter—PM−71.71−69.19−77.22−76.57−76.59−76.85
Ammonia—NH3−11.93−1.44−3.980.35−3.170.37
Percentage change from the corresponding year in the reference case.
Table 5. Long run [2030] effects: macroeconomic performance.
Table 5. Long run [2030] effects: macroeconomic performance.
CF1CF2CF3CF4CF4ACF4B
GDP−5.21−1.19−3.971.46−3.061.72
Private Consumption−1.21−0.12−0.781.182.34−0.85
Investment−1.330.02−0.611.630.371.63
Employment−2.71−0.56−2.030.90−1.000.88
Foreign Debt−12.660.64−1.53−3.59−3.38−0.79
Public Debt3.702.263.59−0.907.20−2.98
CPI2.320.381.650.532.490.03
Percentage change from the corresponding year in the reference case.
Table 6. Long run [2030] effects: energy taxes.
Table 6. Long run [2030] effects: energy taxes.
ReferenceCF1CF2CF3CF4CF4ACF4A
Unit Tax2.283.902.303.223.373.303.34
CSR0.220.210.230.220.220.220.22
ISP1.901.840.000.000.000.000.00
CO20.161.852.073.013.153.083.12
Percent of GDP.
Table 7. Long run [2030] effects: output by industry.
Table 7. Long run [2030] effects: output by industry.
CF1CF2CF3CF4CF4ACF4B
Total−5.21−1.19−1.53−3.59−3.38−0.79
Petroleum refining−11.160.64−0.18−0.21−0.18−0.07
Electricity−10.17−5.371.431.571.480.62
Biomass2.042.29−1.34−3.63−11.052.57
Agriculture−4.39−1.50−1.40−20.391.66−44.25
Mining−9.07−0.96−2.020.90−1.010.88
Manufacture of food products, etc.−3.05−0.280.591.534.60−1.00
Textiles−8.13−5.0440.2146.5043.6545.05
Wood, and pulp and paper−7.81−4.66−1.53−3.59−3.38−0.79
Chemicals and pharmaceuticals−8.12−2.67−0.18−0.21−0.18−0.07
Rubber, plastics, and ceramics−13.49−9.091.431.571.480.62
Basic metals and metal products−10.35−4.12−1.34−3.63−11.052.57
Equipment manufacturing−16.91−1.62−1.40−20.391.66−44.25
Water, sewage, and waste management−2.02−0.71−2.020.90−1.010.88
Construction−1.80−0.210.591.534.60−1.00
Wholesale and retail trade−5.86−0.2540.2146.5043.6545.05
Transportation−9.500.75−1.53−3.59−3.38−0.79
Accommodation and food services−2.37−0.41−0.18−0.21−0.18−0.07
Information technology−1.95−0.421.431.571.480.62
Finance and insurance−2.61−0.45−1.34−3.63−11.052.57
Real estate−0.82−0.12−1.40−20.391.66−44.25
Professional services−3.48−0.57−2.020.90−1.010.88
Public administration−0.94−0.420.591.534.60−1.00
Education−0.58−0.1840.2146.5043.6545.05
Health−1.32−0.37−1.53−3.59−3.38−0.79
Other−2.68−0.43−0.18−0.21−0.18−0.07
Percentage change from the corresponding year in the reference case.
Table 8. Long run [2030] effects: welfare effects.
Table 8. Long run [2030] effects: welfare effects.
CF1CF2CF3CF4CF4ACF4B
Equivalent Variation in Income
All Households−1.34−0.10−0.861.092.26−0.94
First Quintile (lowest income)−1.85−0.22−1.252.514.84−1.08
Second Quintile−1.64−0.12−1.041.713.35−0.99
Third Quintile−1.45−0.09−0.921.252.56−0.96
Fourth Quintile−1.33−0.09−0.850.851.82−0.94
Fifth Quintile (highest income)−1.02−0.08−0.650.531.24−0.86
Percentage change from the corresponding year in the reference case.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Pereira, A.M.; Pereira, R.M. Energy Taxation Reform with an Environmental Focus in Portugal. Energies 2023, 16, 1232. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16031232

AMA Style

Pereira AM, Pereira RM. Energy Taxation Reform with an Environmental Focus in Portugal. Energies. 2023; 16(3):1232. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16031232

Chicago/Turabian Style

Pereira, Alfredo Marvão, and Rui Marvão Pereira. 2023. "Energy Taxation Reform with an Environmental Focus in Portugal" Energies 16, no. 3: 1232. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16031232

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop