A Quantitative Analysis of the Optimal Energy Policy from the Perspective of China’s Supply-Side Reform
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature
3. Model
3.1. Final Goods
3.2. Intermediate Goods
3.3. Energy Producer
3.4. Energy Producer
3.5. Market Clearing
- Intermediate goods market.
- Energy market. In equilibrium, the energy demand for the two types of intermediate products should be equal to the energy output.
- Labor market. The supply of workers L is normalized to 1, which equals the number of workers employed by high and low energy-consuming firms.
4. Numerical Results
4.1. Calibration and Model Validation
4.2. Quantitative Results
4.3. Experiment
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. A Descriptive Diagram
Appendix B. Computation
Appendix C. Results
BGP | Experiment 1 | Experiment 2 | Experiment 3 | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Gross output:Y | 0.348 | 0.305 | 0.300 | 0.306 |
(−12.31%) | (−13.83%) | (−12.18%) | ||
Fossil energy:F | 0.391 | 0.417 | 0.420 | 0.403 |
(6.72%) | (7.56%) | (3.28%) | ||
Green energy:G | 0.424 | 0.534 | 0.513 | 0.557 |
(66.36%) | (53.67%) | (76.09%) | ||
Energy structure:G/(F+G) | 0.288 | 0.478 | 0.442 | 0.506 |
(26.02%) | (20.90%) | (31.26%) | ||
Energy:E | 0.495 | 0.472 | 0.431 | 0.462 |
(−4.75%) | (−13.00%) | (−6.78%) | ||
Scientists in industry F: | 0.006 | 0.004 | 0.004 | 0.005 |
(−28.23%) | (−28.71%) | (−18.89%) | ||
Scientists in industry G: | 0.004 | 0.005 | 0.006 | 0.005 |
(28.73%) | (39.41%) | (18.07%) | ||
Technology of industry F: | 2.212 | 2.378 | 2.377 | 2.394 |
(7.48%) | (7.44%) | (8.21%) | ||
Technology of industry G: | 1.818 | 2.054 | 2.065 | 2.038 |
(13.03%) | (13.63%) | (12.11%) | ||
Technology of industry G:A | 2.038 | 2.237 | 2.241 | 2.239 |
(9.76%) | (9.97%) | (9.85%) | ||
Price of industry M: | 0.522 | 0.578 | 0.572 | 0.577 |
(10.79%) | (9.54%) | (10.50%) | ||
Price of industry F: | 0.360 | 0.394 | 0.488 | 0.401 |
(9.45%) | (35.50%) | (11.33%) | ||
Price of industry G: | 0.423 | 0.371 | 0.472 | 0.356 |
(−12.12%) | (11.73%) | (−15.80%) | ||
Relative energy price:/ | 1.173 | 0.0.941 | 0.967 | 0.887 |
(−19.71%) | (−17.55%) | (−24.37%) |
References
- Zhang, Y.; Zhang, M.; Liu, Y.; Nie, R. Enterprise investment, local government intervention and coal overcapacity: The case of China. Energy Policy 2017, 101, 162–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boulter, J. China’s Supply-side Structural Reform. Reserve Bank-Aust. Bull. 2018, 12, 1–19. [Google Scholar]
- Gutowski, T.G.; Sahni, S.; Allwood, J.M.; Ashby, M.F.; Worrell, E. The energy required to produce materials: Constraints on energy-intensity improvements, parameters of demand. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. A 2013, 371, 001–003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Lin, J.Y.; Wu, H.-M.; Xing, Y. “Wave Phenomena” and Formation of Excess Capacity. Econ. Res. J. 2010, 10, 4–19. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, Y.; Luo, G.; Guo, Y. Why is there overcapacity in China’s PV industry in its early growth stage? Renew. Energy 2014, 72, 188–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feng, Y.; Wang, S.; Sha, Y.; Ding, Q.; Yuan, J.; Guo, X. Coal power overcapacity in China: Province-Level estimates and policy implications. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2018, 137, 89–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, D.; Wang, Y.; Song, X.; Liu, Y. Coal overcapacity in China: Multiscale analysis and prediction. Energy Econ. 2018, 70, 244–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, J.; Li, P.; Wang, Y.; Liu, Q.; Shen, X.; Zhang, K.; Dong, L. Coal power overcapacity and investment bubble in China during 2015–2020. Energy Policy 2016, 97, 136–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, Q.; Hou, X.; Han, J.; Zhang, L. The drivers of coal overcapacity in China: An empirical study based on the quantitative decomposition. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2019, 141, 123–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, D.; Wan, K.; Song, X.; Liu, Y. Provincial allocation of coal de-capacity targets in China in terms of cost, efficiency, and fairness. Energy Econ. 2019, 141, 109–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, W.; Lua, C.; Ding, Y.; Zhang, Y. The impacts of policy mix for resolving overcapacity in heavy chemical industry and operating national carbon emission trading market in China. Appl. Energy 2019, 204, 509–524. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Acemoglu, D. Directed technical change. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2002, 4, 781–809. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Smulders, S.; De Nooij, M. The impact of energy conservation on technology and economic growth. Resour. Energy Econ. 2003, 1, 59–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Acemoglu, D.; Akcigit, U.; Hanley, D.; Kerr, W. Transition to clean technology. J. Political Econ. 2016, 1, 53–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hart, R. Directed technological change: It’s all about knowledge. Swed. Univ. Agric. Sci. Dep. Econ. Work. Pap. Ser. 2012, 2, 1–18. [Google Scholar]
- Goulder, L.H.; Stephen, H.S. Induced technological change and the attractiveness of CO2 abatement policies. Resour. Energy Econ. 1999, 21, 211–253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Popp, D. ENTICE: Endogenous technological change in the DICE model of global warming. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2004, 48, 742–768. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gerlagh, R. A climate-change policy induced shift from innovation in carbon-energy production to carbon-energy savings. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 425–448. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Acemoglu, D.; Aghion, P.; Bursztyn, L.; Hémous, D. The Environment and Directed Technical Change. Am. Econ. Rev. 2012, 1, 131–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Fried, S. Climate policy and innovation: A quantitative macroeconomic analysis. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 2018, 1, 90–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Heutel, G. How should environmental policy respond to business cycles? Optimal policy under persistent productivity shocks. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 2012, 2, 244–264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fischer, C.; Springborn, M.R. Emissions targets and the real business cycle: Intensity targets versus caps or taxes. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2011, 3, 352–366. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Angelopoulos, K.; Economides, G.; Philippopoulos, A. What is the Best Environmental Policy? Taxes, Permits and Rules under Economic and Environmental Uncertainty. Athens Univ. Econ. Bus. DEOS Work. Pap. 2010, 3, 1–37. [Google Scholar]
- Dissou, Y.; Karnizova, L. Emissions cap or emissions tax? A multi-sector business cycle analysis. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2016, 79, 169–188. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Method of Moments | Data | Model |
---|---|---|
Ratio of energy consumption of industry M: /E | 0.73 | 0.73 |
Ratio of energy supply of industry F: F/E | 0.80 | 0.79 |
Ratio of scientists in industry G: /S | 0.41 | 0.43 |
Scientist structure of the energy production sector: / | 1.44 | 1.33 |
Parameter | Value | Source |
---|---|---|
Final goods production | ||
Output elasticity of substitution: | 0.95 | — |
Distribution of high energy-consumption materials: | 0.6 | Data |
Intermediates production | ||
Labor share of high energy-consumption materials: | 0.19 | Data |
Labor share of low energy-consumption materials: | 0.49 | Data |
Number of workers: L | 1 | Normalization |
Production shock of sector M in policy 1: | 0.90 | Method of moments |
Production shock of sector F in policy 2: | 0.88 | Method of moments |
Production shock of sector M in policy 3: | 0.91 | Method of moments |
Production shock of sector F in policy 3: | 0.93 | Method of moments |
Energy production | ||
Capital share of fossil energy: | 0.915 | Method of moments |
Capital share of green energy: | 0.599 | Method of moments |
Energy supply | ||
Energy elasticity of substitution: | 1.5 | Literature |
Distribution of fossil energy: | 0.5 | — |
Research | ||
Cross-sector spillovers: | 0.5 | Literature |
Diminishing returns: | 0.79 | Literature |
Scientist efficiency: | 6.017 | Method of moments |
Sector size of fossil producers: | 1 | Normalization |
Sector size of green producers: | 0.773 | Data |
Number of scientists: S | 0.01 | Data |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Xi, J.; Wu, H.; Li, B.; Liu, J. A Quantitative Analysis of the Optimal Energy Policy from the Perspective of China’s Supply-Side Reform. Sustainability 2020, 12, 4800. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12124800
Xi J, Wu H, Li B, Liu J. A Quantitative Analysis of the Optimal Energy Policy from the Perspective of China’s Supply-Side Reform. Sustainability. 2020; 12(12):4800. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12124800
Chicago/Turabian StyleXi, Jianming, Hanran Wu, Bo Li, and Jingyu Liu. 2020. "A Quantitative Analysis of the Optimal Energy Policy from the Perspective of China’s Supply-Side Reform" Sustainability 12, no. 12: 4800. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12124800