Next Article in Journal
New Insights into the Impact of Local Corruption on China’s Regional Carbon Emissions Performance Based on the Spatial Spillover Effects
Next Article in Special Issue
Development of a Low-Cost Remote Fault Detection System for a Photovoltaic Power Plant
Previous Article in Journal
Joint Optimization of Allocations and Relocations in One-Way Carsharing Systems with Two Operators
Previous Article in Special Issue
Multiple Industrial Induction Motors Fault Diagnosis Model within Powerline System Based on Wireless Sensor Network
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Research on Promotion and Application Strategy of Electric Equipment in Plateau Railway Tunnel Based on Evolutionary Game

School of Economics and Management, Beijing Jiaotong University, Beijing 100044, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2022, 14(22), 15309; https://doi.org/10.3390/su142215309
Submission received: 27 October 2022 / Revised: 15 November 2022 / Accepted: 16 November 2022 / Published: 17 November 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Electric Power Equipment Sustainable Development)

Abstract

:
Under China’s modern development concept, it is necessary to promote the application of electric equipment to improve the construction environment of high-altitude railway tunnels and to address the efficiency reduction in high-altitude construction of traditional fuel oil equipment. Based on the analysis of the development status of electric equipment for tunneling projects in China, a tripartite evolutionary game approach is used to establish the game payment matrix of the government, equipment manufacturers, and construction units. The impact of the relevant parameters on the tripartite strategy is investigated based on numerical simulations. It has been shown that in the early stages of popularization and application, the government should actively regulate and control, and in the later stages of popularization and application, the government should play a leading role in market mechanisms. Evolutionary stability strategies are affected by the brand revenue that manufacturers earn through technological innovation on electric equipment and the additional research and development costs that need to be paid. The conclusions of this study can help provide a reference for the promotion and application strategy of electric equipment in China’s plateau railway tunnels.

1. Introduction

Compared to the plains, the plateau region has low temperature, low pressure, insufficient oxygen, and large temperature differences [1,2,3]. Conventional oil-powered machinery equipment suffers from severe power loss and increased usage costs [4]. In addition, because of the narrow construction site and limited ventilation, conventional oil-powered machinery and equipment emit additional pollutants and consume large amounts of oxygen, exacerbating the health hazards to workers in the tunnels from the anoxic environment on the plateau [5,6,7,8]. Additionally, the quality of Chinese workers has improved significantly along with the material standard of living of all Chinese people, and the demand of workers for a better working environment is increasing with each passing day [9,10]. The traditional hand-carried, shoulder-to-shoulder, dusty tunneling operation has struggled to be embraced by a fresh generation of workers. The destruction of sensitive and fragile areas of the ecological environment along the plateau railway by oil-powered mechanical equipment is also contrary to the building of ecological civilization, as required by China’s ‘carbon peak and carbon neutrality’ goals [11,12,13,14]. In addition, rising domestic fuel prices have created multiple challenges for the use of conventional oil-powered machinery equipment [15]. In this paper, we aim to construct a three-agent evolutionary game model of the government, equipment manufacturers, and construction units, and study the promotion and application strategies of new energy equipment. At the same time, the influence of the relevant parameters on the tripartite strategy is analyzed through numerical simulation to provide suggestions and references for the application of new energy devices in railway tunneling projects on the plateau.
Several scholars have conducted studies from the perspective of tunneling equipment configuration in order to provide an application scheme for plateau railway tunneling equipment by integrating well-established equipment systems and optimizing selection strategies under the available technological means [16,17]. Taking the Guiyang-Guangzhou high-speed railway tunnel project as an example, Zhang et al. [18] analyzed several fundamental problems restricting the construction efficiency and safety. In developing and applying the rapid construction technology and matching equipment of the tunnel invert, the tunnel construction time was shortened. Song and Xia [19] proposed a self-organizing map-global particle swarm optimization algorithm and applied it to the optimization of the construction machinery unit combination for the F4 section of the Wushaoling Tunnel. After applying the optimization algorithm, the total carbon emissions were reduced by 88.4 percent compared to the original mechanical system configuration, which serves as a reference for other tunnel construction projects. Based on the analysis of environmental factors affecting the high-altitude construction of the Sichuan-Tibet railway tunnel, Xing and Feng [20] comprehensively considered the factors of equipment efficiency, economy, and construction quality, and provided advice on equipment selection for the key processes of drilling and blasting construction. Wang et al. [21] sorted out the policy conditions for the promotion and application of new energy equipment, combined with the unique environment of the plateau railway tunnel, summarized the advantages of electric equipment, and proposed applications. Under the modern development concept, it is necessary to implement electric equipment to achieve zero emissions during construction and to improve the construction environment of the plateau railway tunnel.
As an emerging industry, few scholars have attempted to analyze the promotion and application strategies of tunneling power equipment from a management perspective. Compared with electric equipment in tunnels, new energy vehicles have taken a long time to develop in the world [22,23,24,25,26,27], and their promotion and application strategies can be used as a reference.
In the promotion and application process of new energy vehicles, the government, manufacturers, consumers, and other interested subjects are commonly involved. Technical problems such as immature core technologies and imperfect safeguards for new energy vehicles are inevitable in the early stages of new energy vehicle development, limiting consumer enthusiasm for purchase [28,29,30,31]. Sun et al. [32] pointed out that increased R&D investment by vehicle enterprises can effectively motivate consumers to buy new energy vehicle products, stressing the importance of vehicle enterprises in promoting and applying new energy vehicles through the evolutionary game and system dynamics methods. However, excessive investment in R&D will increase the cost burden of enterprises. Therefore, in the early stage of technological development, government subsidies to enterprises are beneficial to stimulate their enthusiasm for innovation [33,34]. Li et al. [35] used a complex network evolutionary game method to explore the dynamic impacts of government policies on electric vehicle diffusion in different scale networks. The results show that production subsidies for enterprises are more favorable to the overall spread of electric vehicles than purchase subsidies for consumers. Yu et al. [36] pointed out through empirical analysis that the government’s subsidy policy should be dynamically adjusted according to the specific situation of new energy vehicle enterprises. However, subsidization may lead to allocation unfairness and inefficiencies. A prior subsidy will constitute an effective incentive, and auto enterprises should also respond in a timely manner to the policies on the transformation and upgrading.
Some scholars [37,38] have discussed the influence of consumers’ purchase behavior on enterprises’ innovation behavior and emphasized the main role of the market in innovation. In this case, the government should consider appropriate purchase subsidies or tax incentives for consumers to stimulate market vitality and promote enterprise innovation [39]. Zhao et al. [40] further explored the impact of government subsidies for consumers on the proliferation of new energy vehicles. By building a three-stage evolutionary game model, Zhao noted that continuing to extend the period of financial subsidies for new energy vehicles at the national level is a powerful measure to support the sustainable development of the new energy vehicle industry in the context of COVID-19 pandemic.
Existing research has focused on the promotion of new energy vehicles in various ways. However, as an emerging industry, few scholars have attempted to analyze the promotion and application strategies of electric equipment for tunneling from a management perspective. Compared to new energy vehicles, consumers of tunnel electric equipment are mainly construction units. In China’s railway construction system, construction units play the role of consumers more easily regulated by the government, and equipment manufacturers face a broader market, both of which value industry demonstration and leadership. On this basis, government regulation has a wider range of means and methods to apply. By adopting the three-party evolutionary game approach, numerous scholars [41,42,43,44,45,46] have investigated the strategies of three-party actors, supplemented by numerical simulation means, to explore the key impact factors in the game.

2. Background

The drilling and blasting method has a long history in the construction of railway tunnel. Because of its advantages of flexible and flexible adaptability, it is the most widely used method in the construction of railway tunnel. Compared to the TBM method, the drilling and blasting method is more refined and engineering disaster prevention techniques are more flexible when dealing with high-risk sections of the plateau and tunnel. It is a necessary means to deal with extreme risk sections of tunnels. However, the extreme working conditions on the plateau have led to traditional drilling and blasting construction, which is mainly artificial and cannot be carried out naturally. Therefore, it is necessary to improve the traditional drilling and blasting method in the plateau railway tunnel construction. Forming the supporting technology of the whole process mechanization can ensure the construction quality, reduce the labor intensity of operators, reduce the major safety risks of tunnel construction, and ensure the construction schedule.
Traditional drilling and blasting tunnel equipment can be classified into three categories according to their power source: (1) Pure diesel power equipment: common in muck transfer equipment, such as excavators, loaders, dumpers, etc. (2) Diesel-electric hybrid equipment: widely used in advance geological prediction, excavation operation, initial lining, the use of diesel power walking, electric power work. (3) Pure electric equipment: common in secondary lining equipment, such as invert trestle, waterproof board trolley, lining trolley, etc.
Currently, most of the mechanical equipment in tunnel construction is implemented with purely electric or diesel-electric hybrid power systems, but the muck-transfer lines are still dominated by purely diesel power equipment. Muck transfer operations accounted for approximately half of the total cycle time throughout the drilling and blasting method. The problem of mechanical devices and humans competing for oxygen in a plateau tunnel construction environment is prominent as the workload and transport distance increase. Required by the modern development strategy, Chinese well-known engineering machinery companies have introduced purely electric excavators, loaders, dumper machines, and other equipment to realize all-electric muck transfer equipment, which provides a viable solution to the efficiency reduction of traditional fuel oil equipment and the oxygen competition between equipment and humans in plateau tunnel construction.
The major advantages of the electric equipment include:
(1)
Zero exhaust emissions, low noise, effectively improve the tunnel working environment. Compared with fuel-based equipment, electric equipment achieves zero tailpipe emissions [47]. In addition, the motor drive considerably reduces the noise in the working environment compared to the fuel equipment, and the improvement on the tunnel working environment is evident.
(2)
It solves the problem of oxygen competition between fuel equipment and people, and relieves the pressure on the ventilation system. The oxygen content of the tunnel environment in the plateau is thin, so it is necessary to enhance ventilation and timely oxygen generation to replenish the oxygen content of the tunnel environment. In contrast to fuel equipment, electric equipment does not require oxygen-consuming combustion and does not consume oxygen in the tunnel, which solves the problem of oxygen competition between fuel equipment and people, and relieves the pressure of ventilation and oxygen production in the plateau tunnel [48,49].
(3)
In the plateau environment, electric equipment ensures working efficiency. The efficiency of fuel oil equipment decreases as the oxygen content decreases due to altitude hypoxia [4]. Electric equipment effectively avoids this situation and ensures the operational efficiency of mechanical equipment.
(4)
Electrical equipment has a long maintenance cycle and low maintenance costs, which reduce the cost of use. Engine systems of fuel equipment require regular replacement and maintenance of oil, oil filters, air filters, and fuel filters. As the altitude increases and the dust content and air humidity increase in the working environment, the frequency of maintenance of fuel equipment needs to increase and the cost of maintenance increases accordingly [50]. The maintenance of the frequency motor system of electric equipment is greatly reduced and the cost of maintenance is considerably reduced.
(5)
The energy cost of electric equipment is much lower than that of oil equipment. Based on a crude calculation of fuel prices and electricity prices, the energy consumption cost of electric equipment is about half that of fuel equipment [51].

3. Methods

3.1. Problem Description and Basic Assumptions

In China, major infrastructure projects such as the Plateau Railway project and the Hong Kong-Zhuhai-Macao Bridge project are generally funded by the state. Such projects are a lifeline for the country’s social and economic development and an essential platform for the country to encourage technological innovation [52,53,54]. In the construction of the railway tunnel project in the plateau, the promotion and application of electric equipment can considerably guarantee the ecological benefits of the plateau and lead to the transformation and upgrading of the traditional manufacturing industry into the field of environmental protection. In the future, how to promote and apply electric equipment to ensure the ecological benefits of the plateau in a large number of upcoming plateau railway projects, as represented by the Sichuan-Tibet Railway project [55], has become a focus of research and consideration for the government. At the present stage, however, the electric equipment for tunneling is still in the early stages of research and development. There are still application issues arising from immature technology, such as high equipment purchase costs, short battery life, and peak power upper limits, which limit the enthusiasm of construction units for generalization and application. Under the special conditions of the plateau railway tunnel, equipment manufacturers still have to pay a certain amount of financial and material resources to carry out technological innovations to provide a systematic and modular complete set of promotion and application programs [56]. In order to match electrical equipment with actual projects, front-line tunnel construction units need to carry out practical applications of electrical equipment, while assisting manufacturers in the trial and error of equipment technology innovations to enable technological updates and upgrades. As the technology of electric equipment is not yet mature, front-line tunnel construction units will inevitably increase the cost of maintenance and the purchase of spare equipment during their application.
In the promotion and application of electric equipment in the railway tunnel project on the plateau, the game process among government, equipment manufacturers, and construction units exist at different stages in the development of the electric equipment (Figure 1). Based on the above analysis, the following assumptions are made in order not to change the essence of the analysis problem.
Assumption 1.
Game agents.
There are three main agents in the game, namely government, equipment manufacturers, and construction units, all of which have bounded rationality. They constantly adjust their strategic choices in the game and make decisions based on their own interests [57,58].
Assumption 2.
The behavior strategies of the government.
The behavioral strategy sets of the government are S1 = {Positive regulation, Negative regulation}. Positive regulation means that the government takes certain measures to regulate the electrical equipment industry, including awarding incentives to manufacturers that implement technological innovations in electrical equipment, or subsidizing construction units that purchase and use electrical equipment. Negative regulation means that the government does not adopt any means to regulate the electrical equipment industry and does not intervene in whether manufacturers implement technological innovations in electrical equipment. At the same time, it does not interfere with the purchase and application of electrical equipment by frontline construction units and allows the market to adjust the configuration freely. The probabilities of Positive regulation and Negative regulation chosen by the government are x and 1 − x (0 ≤ x ≤ 1), respectively.
Assumption 3.
The behavior strategies of the equipment manufacturers.
The behavioral strategy sets of the equipment manufacturers are S2 = {Positive innovation, Negative innovation}. Positive innovation means that equipment manufacturers can iterate the configuration of electrical equipment through technological innovation, improve its construction efficiency and endurance time, and reduce the production cost of equipment by increasing the industrial chain, thus lowering the factory price. Negative regulation means that the manufacturer does not make technological innovations consistent with the maintenance of the current production technology of electric devices. The probabilities of Positive innovation and Negative innovation chosen by the equipment manufacturers are y and 1 − y (0 ≤ y ≤ 1), respectively.
Assumption 4.
The behavior strategies of the construction units.
The behavioral strategy sets of the construction units are S3 = {Positive application, Negative application}. Positive application refers to electric equipment purchased by the construction unit from the equipment manufacturer and applied in the tunnel construction line. Negative applications refer to the use of conventional equipment for production and construction, rather than electric equipment. The probabilities of Positive application and Negative application chosen by the construction units are z and 1 − z (0 ≤ z ≤ 1), respectively.
Assumption 5.
Hypotheses of relevant parameters in evolutionary game models and their meanings (Table 1 for details).

3.2. Evolutionary Game Model

Based on the behavioral strategies of the government, equipment manufacturers, and construction units, it can be concluded that there are eight game combinations among them, as shown in Table 2. See Table 3 for the perceived payoff matrix for the three-agents game.

3.3. Replicator Dynamic Analysis

Based on the above analysis and evolutionary principles of evolutionary game theory, when the expected payoff of a strategy is higher than the overall average expected payoff, the strategy will evolve and evolve in the system. The evolution process can be described by the replicator kinetic equation.

3.3.1. Government

Assume that the payoff expectation is U11 when government chooses Positive regulation, the payoff expectation is U12 when government chooses Negative regulation, and average payoff expectation is U1.
U 11 = y z G 1 G 2 + G 4 + G 5 E 4 C 4 + y 1 z G 1 G 2 + G 3 + G 4 E 4 + z 1 y G 1 G 2 + G 5 C 4 + 1 y 1 z G 1 G 2 + G 3
U 12 = y z G 1 + G 4 + G 5 + y 1 z G 1 + G 4 + z 1 y G 1 + G 5 + 1 y 1 z G 1
U 1 = x U 11 + 1 x U 12
According to the stability theorem of differential equation and government’s replication dynamic equation, it can be known the government’s replication dynamic equation is as follows.
F x = d x d t = x ( U 11 U 1 ) = x 1 x U 11 U 12 = x ( 1 x ) G 2 G 3 + y E 4 + z C 4 + G 3
The derivative of the replicator dynamics equation of x can be further calculated below
d F x d x = 1 2 x G 2 G 3 + y F 4 + z G 3 + C 4
Then, three circumstances are discussed separately according to Formula (5).
Obviously, x = 0, x = 1, z = G 3 G 2 y F 4 G 3 + G 4 are the roots of F(x) = 0. Based on the stability theorem put forward by Friedman in 1991, when F(x) = 0, F’(x) ≤ 0, x is an ESS.
(1)
When z = G 3 G 2 y F 4 G 3 + G 4 , then for any x ∈ [0, 1], F(x) = 0, d F x d x = 0 , the x-axis is in a stable state, and any strategies of the government are stable.
(2)
When 0 z < G 3 G 2 y F 4 G 3 + G 4 , d F x d x x = 0 > 0 , d F x d x x = 1 < 0 , we can see that x = 1 is the only ESS. At this time, the government chooses Positive regulation is the optimal strategy.
(3)
When 1 z > G 3 G 2 y F 4 G 3 + G 4 , d F x d x x = 0 < 0 , d F x d x x = 1 > 0 , we can see that x = 0 is the only ESS. At this time, the government chooses Negative regulation is the optimal strategy.
The dynamic evolution diagram of government’s decision making is shown in Figure 2.

3.3.2. Equipment Manufacturers

Assume that the payoff expectation is U21 when equipment manufacturers choose Positive innovation, the payoff expectation is U22 when equipment manufacturers choose Negative innovation, and average payoff expectation is U2.
U 21 = x z F 1 + F 2 F 3 + F 4 + x 1 z F 1 + F 2 F 3 + F 4 + z 1 x F 1 + F 2 F 3 + 1 x 1 z F 1 + F 2 F 3
U 22 = x z + x 1 z + z 1 x + 1 x 1 z F 1
U 2 = y U 21 + 1 y U 22
According to stability theorem of differential equation and equipment manufacturers’ replication dynamic equation, it can be known the equipment manufacturers’ replication dynamic equation is as follows.
F y = d y d t = y U 21 U 2 = y 1 y U 21 U 22 = y 1 y F 2 F 3 + x F 4
The derivative of the replicator dynamics equation of y can be further calculated below
d F y d y = 1 2 y F 2 F 3 + x F 4
Then, three circumstances are discussed separately according to Formula (10).
Obviously, y = 0, y = 1, x = F 3 F 2 F 4 are the roots of F(y) = 0. Based on the stability theorem put forward by Friedman in 1991, when F(y) = 0, F’(y) ≤ 0, y is an ESS.
(1)
When x = F 3 F 2 F 4 , then for any y ∈ [0, 1], F(y) = 0, d F y d y = 0 , the y-axis is in a stable state, and any strategies of the equipment manufacturers are stable.
(2)
When 0 x < F 3 F 2 F 4 , d F y d y y = 0 < 0 , d F y d y y = 1 > 0 , we can see that y = 0 is the only ESS. At this time, the equipment manufacturers choose negative innovation is the optimal strategy.
(3)
When 1 x > F 3 F 2 F 4 , d F y d y y = 0 > 0 , d F y d y y = 1 < 0 , we can see that y = 1 is the only ESS. At this time, the equipment manufacturers choose positive innovation is the optimal strategy.
The dynamic evolution diagram of equipment manufacturers’ decision making is shown in Figure 3.

3.3.3. Construction Units

Assume that the payoff expectation is U31 when construction units choose Positive application, the payoff expectation is U32 when construction units choose Negative innovation, and average payoff expectation is U3
U 31 = x y C 1 + C 3 + C 4 + x 1 y C 1 C 2 + C 4 + y 1 x C 1 + C 3 + 1 x 1 y C 1 C 2
U 32 = x y C 1 G 3 + x 1 y C 1 G 3 + y 1 x + 1 x 1 y C 1
U 3 = z U 31 + 1 z U 32
According to stability theorem of differential equation and construction units’ replication dynamic equation, it can be known the construction units’ replication dynamic equation is as follows.
F z = d z d t = z U 31 U 3 = z 1 z U 31 U 32 = z 1 z x C 4 1 y C 2 + y C 3 + x G 3
The derivative of the replicator dynamics equation of z can be further calculated below
d F z d z = 1 2 z x C 4 1 y C 2 + y C 3 + x G 3
Then, three circumstances are discussed separately according to Formula (15).
Obviously, z = 0, z = 1, y = C 2 x C 4 + G 3 C 2 + C 3 are the roots of F(z) = 0. Based on the stability theorem put forward by Friedman in 1991, when F(z) = 0, F’(z) ≤ 0, z is an ESS.
(1)
When y = C 2 x C 4 + G 3 C 2 + C 3 , then for any z ∈ [0, 1], F(z) = 0, d F z d z = 0 , the z-axis is in a stable state, and any strategies of the equipment manufacturers are stable.
(2)
When 0 y < C 2 x C 4 + G 3 C 2 + C 3 , d F z d z z = 0 < 0 , d F z d z z = 1 > 0 we can see that z = 0 is the only ESS. At this time, the construction units choose negative application is the optimal strategy.
(3)
When 1 y > C 2 x C 4 + G 3 C 2 + C 3 , d F z d z z = 0 > 0 , d F z d z z = 1 < 0 we can see that z = 1 is the only ESS. At this time, the construction units choose positive application is the optimal strategy.
The dynamic evolution diagram of construction units’ decision making is shown in Figure 4.

3.4. Tripartite Game Equilibrium Solution

According to the Jacobian matrix theory which was proposed by Friedman, there are eight local equilibrium points in the system: P1(0,0,0), P2(0,0,1), P3(0,1,0), P4(0,1,1), P5(1,0,0), P6(1,0,1), P7(1,1,0), and P8(1,1,1). The stability of the equilibrium point is obtained by analyzing the local stability of the Jacobian matrix. The Jacobian matrix of this system is composed of differential Equations (5), (10) and (15) as shown in the Formula (16).
J = 1 2 x G 2 G 3 + y F 4 + z G 3 + C 4 x 1 x F 4 x 1 x G 3 + C 4 y 1 y F 4 1 2 y F 2 F 3 + x F 4 0 z 1 z C 4 + G 3 z 1 z C 2 + C 3 1 2 z x C 4 1 y C 2 + y C 3 + x G 3
The eigenvalues of Jacobian matrix are obtained by substituting eight equilibrium points into Jacobian matrix, as shown in Table 4.
The possible stable equilibrium points in the game are P1 (0,0,0), P4 (0,1,1). However, the satisfaction of the stability condition at the equilibrium point still requires further analysis.
If E2E3 < 0, G3G2 < 0, that means the equipment manufacturers’ brand benefits that carrying out positive innovation of electric equipment to increase is less than the additional R&D costs incurred by the equipment manufacturers in adopting positive innovation for electric equipment. In addition, the fines imposed by the government on construction units that pollute the environment during supervision and regulation are less than the human, material, and financial costs incurred by the government when it adopts a positive regulation strategy. In this case, Negative regulation, Negative innovation, Negative application is ESS.
If E3E2 < 0, that means the equipment manufacturers’ brand benefits that carrying out positive innovation of electric equipment to increase is greater than the additional R&D costs incurred by the equipment manufacturers in adopting positive innovation for electric equipment. Negative regulation, Positive innovation, Positive application is ESS.

4. Numerical Example

4.1. Case Description and Parameter Settings

By analyzing the game of the government, the equipment manufacturers, and the construction units, it can be found that the equilibrium points of the evolution of the three parties are P1 (0,0,0) and P4 (0,1,1) under certain parameters. Since point P1 (0,0,0) has no research significance, the following research is mainly conducted for P4 (0,1,1). The parameter condition of point P4 is limited to E3E2 < 0. This equilibrium point is consistent with the tendency of government regulation to go to 0 under long-term development conditions, and the production and application of new energy devices is freely regulated by the market, in accordance with the law of market evolution. Based on the equations of the tripartite replicator dynamics and the analysis of the equilibrium stable point, the strategies of the tripartite cooperative behavior are directly affected by the initial intentions of the tripartite and the variable parameters. The initial parameter settings are listed in Table 5. Meanwhile, the tripartite initial intentions are set to (0.2,0.2,0.2).
Numerical simulations were performed using MATLAB R2021a software and the results are shown in Figure 5. It can be seen from Figure 5 that the evolutionary stable state of the system is (0,1,1), which is consistent with the above conclusion, and the model is effective.

4.2. The Impact of Selecting an Initial Change of Strategy on Evolutionary Results

4.2.1. Government

When the initial intention of equipment manufacturers and construction units remain unchanged (y = z = 0.2), selected the initial strategy x of the government is (0.0, 0.2, 0.4, 0.6, 0.8, 1.0), the influence of tripartite initial intention on their behavioral strategies is analyzed.
Figure 6a shows that the equipment manufacturers’ intention y converges to 1 regardless of the government’s initial intention. As the initial intention of the government department increases, the convergence rate of the equipment manufacturer’s intention accelerates. Therefore, equipment manufacturers will innovate electric equipment positively regardless of the government’s strategy, and their innovation intentions will increase as the government’s regulate strategy intentions increase.
Figure 6b shows that the construction units’ intention y converges to 1 regardless of the government’s initial intention. As the initial intention of the government department increases, the convergence rate of the construction units’ intention accelerates. Therefore, construction units will apply electric equipment positively regardless of the government’s strategy, and their application intentions will increase as the government’s regulate strategy intentions increase.

4.2.2. Equipment Manufacturers

When the initial intention of government and construction units remain unchanged (x = z = 0.2), the selected initial strategy y of the government is (0.0, 0.2, 0.4, 0.6, 0.8, 1.0), the influence of tripartite initial intention on their behavioral strategies is analyzed.
Figure 7a shows that the government’s intent x converges to zero when the equipment manufacturers’ initial intent is non-zero. At the same time, with the increase of the initial intention of the equipment manufacturers, the convergence speed of the intention x of the government accelerates, which means that when the equipment manufacturers have the positive intention to innovate, the government departments gradually tend to regulate negatively, while when the equipment manufacturers have no intention to innovate, the government departments have the intention to regulate positively.
Figure 7b shows that shows that the construction units’ intent z converges to 1 when the equipment manufacturers’ initial intent is non-zero. At the same time, with the increase of the initial intention of the equipment manufacturers, the convergence rate of the construction units’ intention z is accelerated, indicating that when the equipment manufacturers have the positive intention to innovate, the construction units’ intention to apply electric equipment increases, and when the equipment manufacturers have no intention to innovate, the construction units gradually have negative intention to apply.

4.2.3. Construction Units

When the initial intention of government and equipment manufacturers remain unchanged (x = y = 0.2), the selected initial strategy z of the construction units is (0.0, 0.2, 0.4, 0.6, 0.8, 1.0), the influence of tripartite initial intention on their behavioral strategies is analyzed.
Figure 8a shows that the government’s intention x converges to 0 regardless of the initial intention of the construction units. At the same time, with the increase of the initial intention of the construction unit, the convergence speed of the government’s intention x is accelerated, indicating that no matter what the strategy of the construction unit is, the government will gradually give up the regulation of electric equipment, and its regulation intention will decrease with the increase of the application intention of the construction unit.
Figure 8b shows that the equipment manufacturer’s intention y converges to 1 regardless of the initial intention of the construction units, and the equipment manufacturer’s innovation intention is not greatly affected by the application strategy of the construction units.

4.3. The Impact of Selecting a Parameter Change of Strategy on Evolutionary Results

According to the replica dynamics equation and the equilibrium stationary point analysis, the three-agent behavior strategy can be affected by some parameters. On the basis of unchanged initial parameters (Table 5), sensitivity analysis was carried out by changing parameters such as G3, E4, C4 and E3.
The following conclusions are drawn from the numerical simulations.
  • When the government departments regulate the implementation of environmental pollution of construction units to impose fines, construction units tend to positively apply (see Figure 9).
  • When the incentives of government departments for manufacturers to carry out electric equipment technology innovation increase, equipment manufacturers tend to positively innovate (see Figure 10).
  • When the construction units get more subsidies from government departments through the deployment and application of electric equipment, the construction unit tends to positively apply it (see Figure 11).
Figure 9. The impact of G3 on evolutionary results of construction units.
Figure 9. The impact of G3 on evolutionary results of construction units.
Sustainability 14 15309 g009
Figure 10. The impact of E4 on evolutionary results of equipment manufacturers.
Figure 10. The impact of E4 on evolutionary results of equipment manufacturers.
Sustainability 14 15309 g010
Figure 11. The impact of C4 on evolutionary results of equipment manufacturers.
Figure 11. The impact of C4 on evolutionary results of equipment manufacturers.
Sustainability 14 15309 g011
In addition, it can be seen from Figure 12 that when E3 is greater than E2 the equipment manufacturers tend to innovate electric equipment negatively. In contrast, when E2 is greater than E3 the equipment manufacturers tend to innovate electric equipment positively.

5. Results and Discussion

In this paper, we develop a three-agent evolutionary game model among the government, equipment manufacturers, and construction units based on the state of development of the electrical equipment industry in a plateau railway tunnel and analyze the game relations and factors that influence the strategic choices of the parties. Based on the above equilibrium points and the results of numerical simulation, the following conclusions and recommendations are drawn.
(1)
In the early stage of the development of the new energy industry, the government should actively carry out regulation and encourage equipment manufacturers to innovate and upgrade the electric equipment. Based on the strengthened certification of electric equipment specifications, preferential policies such as accelerated depreciation, value-added tax, and income tax reduction should be given to electric equipment manufacturers to reduce risks for equipment manufacturers in the early stages of research and development. At the same time, the government should adopt mandatory and encouraging policies for construction units: improve market acceptance and application demonstration of electric equipment through the promulgation of preferential policies such as tax reduction and exemption. By imposing a plateau pollution tax, the cost of plateau applications of conventional fuel oil equipment is increased, resulting in a relative reduction in expenditure on electric equipment. The government may take incentives such as bid requirements and contract performance to require and encourage the participating construction units to purchase a certain proportion of electric equipment in the first line, thereby promoting the promotion and application of electric equipment. In the long-term context, to achieve the goal of promoting and applying electric equipment in railway tunnels on the plateau, government departments must be market-oriented, play a leading role in market mechanisms, and encourage innovative production to drive the industry.
(2)
The innovation enthusiasm of equipment manufacturers is affected by their innovation cost. In the early stage of industrial development, the high cost of innovation will affect the innovation decisions of equipment manufacturers, and the government should give a certain level of support. Equipment manufacturers should actively respond to calls from government departments to formulate a strategy for electric equipment development, strengthen research and development of core technologies for electric equipment, and actively carry out technological updates and iterations to enhance market competitiveness. At the same time, the equipment manufacturer should take the initiative to contact line construction units, understanding plateau tunnel construction specifically needs a line of electric equipment, actively carry out live trial, plateau tunnel around the overall cost and battery life, the size of the equipment, plateau, such as the stability and safety charging pile in actual combat vehicle technology research and development and the core components technical research.
(3)
Construction units should actively respond to the call of government departments, take the initiative to deploy electric equipment in the tunnel construction line, take the lead in demonstration and application, improve the working environment of plateau tunnels, and gradually ban traditional fuel oil equipment with the trend of industrial upgrading. At the same time, the construction unit shall be equipped with auxiliary plant trial and error, technological innovation for plateau railway tunnel space is relatively closed, low pressure, low oxygen, dust, damp environment, and the possibility of high geothermal, water inrush and gas outburst, rock burst mud such as geological environment, actively summarize feedback early application of electric equipment, application problem, and the key technical problems in the pilot demonstration area, accelerating industrial upgrading.
The electric equipment provides a feasible solution to the problem of reducing the efficiency of traditional fuel equipment and the oxygen competition between equipment and people in the construction of plateau railway tunnel, which greatly ensures the health of frontline construction personnel and the fragile ecological environment of plateau, and the value it brings is immeasurable.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, X.Y., Y.L. and K.L.; data curation, X.Y.; investigation, X.Y., Y.L., K.L. and G.H.; methodology, X.Y., K.L. and G.H.; resources, X.Y. and Y.L.; software, X.Y., K.L. and X.Z.; supervision, Y.L. and X.Z.; visualization, G.H.; writing—original draft, X.Y.; writing—review and editing, Y.L. and X.Z. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was supported by the Fundamental Research Funds for the Railway Research Institute Group Limited Foundation of China (Grant No. 2021YJ111).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Moore, G. Surface pressure record of Tibetan Plateau warming since the 1870s. Q. J. R. Meteor. Soc. 2012, 138, 1999–2008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Du, H.; Xue, X.; Wang, T.; Lu, S.; Liao, J.; Li, S.; Fan, Y.; Liu, X. Modeling dust emission in alpine regions with low air temperature and low air pressure—A case study on the Qinghai-Tibetan Plateau (QTP). Geoderma 2022, 422, 115930. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Saha, K.; Vandendool, H.; Saha, S. On the annual cycle in surface pressure on the tibetan plateau compared to its surroundings. J. Clim. 1994, 7, 2014–2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Guo, D.; Li, G.; Hu, N.; Hou, J. System Dynamics Analysis of Man-Machine Efficacy in Plateau Mines. IEEE Access 2021, 9, 18072–18084. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Attfield, M.D.; Schleiff, P.L.; Lubin, J.H.; Blair, A.; Stewart, P.A.; Vermeulen, R.; Coble, J.B.; Silverman, D.T. The Diesel Exhaust in Miners Study: A Cohort Mortality Study with Emphasis on Lung Cancer. J. Natl. Cancer Inst. 2012, 104, 869–883. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Li, C.; Jiang, Z.; Zhang, G.; Feng, X.; Zeng, F. Dust pollution during shotcrete process in high-altitude tunnel based on numerical simulation. Particuology 2022, 75, 82–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Wang, J.; Kong, X.; Fan, Y.; Jiang, X.; Lu, K. Reduced pressure effects on smoke temperature, CO concentration and smoke extraction in tunnel fires with longitudinal ventilation and vertical shaft. Case Stud. Therm. Eng. 2022, 37, 102311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Feng, X.; Jiang, Z.; Zhang, G.; Luo, X.; Zeng, F. Study on CO diffusion law and concentration distribution function under ventilation after blasting in high-altitude tunnel. J. Wind Eng. Ind. Aerodyn. 2022, 220, 104871. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Su, Y.; Liu, M.; De Silva, P.V.; Østbye, T.; Jin, K. Health-related quality of life in Chinese workers: A systematic review and meta-analysis. Glob. Health Res. Pol. 2021, 6, 29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Wu, P.; Yang, F.; Zheng, J.; Wei, Y. Evaluating the Highway Tunnel Construction in Western Sichuan Plateau Considering Vocational Health and Environment. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 4671. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Zhang, P.; Hu, J.; Zhao, K.; Chen, H.; Zhao, S.; Li, W. Dynamics and Decoupling Analysis of Carbon Emissions from Construction Industry in China. Buildings 2022, 12, 257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Dong, Z.L.; Wang, B.S.; Li, J. Effects of Petroleum Hydrocarbon Contamination on Soil Bacterial Diversity in the Permafrost Region of the Qinghai-Tibetan Plateau. Soil Sediment Contam. Int. J. 2020, 29, 322–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Zhang, M.; Pei, W.; Zhang, X.; Lu, J. Lateral thermal disturbance of embankments in the permafrost regions of the Qinghai-Tibet Engineering Corridor. Nat. Hazards 2015, 78, 2121–2142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Wang, G.; Yan, X.; Zhang, F.; Zeng, C.; Gao, D. Traffic-Related Trace Element Accumulation in Roadside Soils and Wild Grasses in the Qinghai-Tibet Plateau, China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2014, 11, 456–472. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Foroutan, F.; Mousavi Gazafrudi, S.M.; Shokri-Ghaleh, H. A Comparative Study of Recent Optimization Methods for Optimal Sizing of a Green Hybrid Traction Power Supply Substation. Arch. Comput. Method E 2021, 28, 2351–2370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Xiang, Z.M.; Yuan, R.A. Mechanical Equipment Coordination and Operation Mode of Wuhan-Guangzhou Passenger Dedicated Line Large Cross-Section Tunnel Construction. Adv. Mater. Res. 2011, 393–395, 166–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Wang, F.; Zhou, K.; Zhou, L. Study on Adaptability of Mechanized Matching Construction of Sichuan-Tibet Railway Tunnel. Mod. Tunn. Technol. 2020, 57, 57–62. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  18. Zhang, H.; Sun, J.; Ma, H.; Chen, S.; Huang, M. Development and Application of Mechanized Matching Equipment for High-Speed Railway Tunnel Construction. Procedia Manuf. 2019, 32, 952–959. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Song, Z.; Xia, Z. Carbon Emission Reduction of Tunnel Construction Machinery System Based on Self-Organizing Map-Global Particle Swarm Optimization with Multiple Weight Varying Models. IEEE Access 2022, 10, 50195–50217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Xing, B.; Feng, H. Suggestions and considerations on equipment selection for constructing Sichuan-Tibet railway tunnels at high altitudes. Tunn. Constr. 2021, 41, 1644–1653. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  21. Wang, Z.; Han, Y.; Xing, P. Study on application of electric new energy equipment in new railway tunnel construction in plateau mountainous area. Railw. Eng. Technol. Econ. 2022, 37, 10–13. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  22. Axsen, J.; Kurani, K.S. Early U.S. Market for Plug-In Hybrid Electric Vehicles. Transp. Res. Rec. J. Transp. Res. Board 2009, 2139, 64–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Wang, Z.; Wang, C.; Hao, Y. Influencing factors of private purchasing intentions of new energy vehicles in China. J. Renew. Sustain. Energy 2013, 5, 63133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Hirte, G.; Tscharaktschiew, S. The optimal subsidy on electric vehicles in German metropolitan areas: A spatial general equilibrium analysis. Energy Econ. 2013, 40, 515–528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Xie, Y.; Wu, D.; Zhu, S. Can new energy vehicles subsidy curb the urban air pollution? Empirical evidence from pilot cities in China. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 754, 142232. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Hoen, A.; Koetse, M.J. A choice experiment on alternative fuel vehicle preferences of private car owners in the Netherlands. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2014, 61, 199–215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Erdem, C.; Şentürk, İ.; Şimşek, T. Identifying the factors affecting the willingness to pay for fuel-efficient vehicles in Turkey: A case of hybrids. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 3038–3043. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Carley, S.; Krause, R.M.; Lane, B.W.; Graham, J.D. Intent to purchase a plug-in electric vehicle: A survey of early impressions in large US cites. Transp. Res. Part D Transport. Environ. 2013, 18, 39–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Li, J.; Zhou, Y.; Yu, D.; Liu, C. Consumers’ Purchase Intention of New Energy Vehicles: Do Product-Life-Cycle Policy Portfolios Matter? Sustainability 2020, 12, 1711. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Rahbari, O.; Vafaeipour, M.; Omar, N.; Rosen, M.A.; Hegazy, O.; Timmermans, J.; Heibati, S.; Bossche, P.V.D. An optimal versatile control approach for plug-in electric vehicles to integrate renewable energy sources and smart grids. Energy 2017, 134, 1053–1067. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Egbue, O.; Long, S. Barriers to widespread adoption of electric vehicles: An analysis of consumer attitudes and perceptions. Energy Policy 2012, 48, 717–729. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Sun, H.; Wan, Y.; Lv, H. System Dynamics Model for the Evolutionary Behaviour of Government Enterprises and Consumers in China’s New Energy Vehicle Market. Sustainability 2020, 12, 1578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Jiang, C.; Zhang, Y.; Bu, M.; Liu, W. The Effectiveness of Government Subsidies on Manufacturing Innovation: Evidence from the New Energy Vehicle Industry in China. Sustainability 2018, 10, 1692. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Lee, E.Y.; Cin, B.C. The effect of risk-sharing government subsidy on corporate R&D investment: Empirical evidence from Korea. Technol. Forecast. Soc. 2010, 77, 881–890. [Google Scholar]
  35. Li, J.; Jiao, J.; Tang, Y. An evolutionary analysis on the effect of government policies on electric vehicle diffusion in complex network. Energy Policy 2019, 129, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Yu, F.; Wang, L.; Li, X. The effects of government subsidies on new energy vehicle enterprises: The moderating role of intelligent transformation. Energy Policy 2020, 141, 111463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Ozaki, R.; Sevastyanova, K. Going hybrid: An analysis of consumer purchase motivations. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 2217–2227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Earl, J.; Fell, M.J. Electric vehicle manufacturers’ perceptions of the market potential for demand-side flexibility using electric vehicles in the United Kingdom. Energy Policy 2019, 129, 646–652. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Gallagher, K.S.; Muehlegger, E. Giving green to get green? Incentives and consumer adoption of hybrid vehicle technology. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2011, 61, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Zhao, D.; Ji, S.; Wang, H.; Jiang, L. How do government subsidies promote new energy vehicle diffusion in the complex network context? A three-stage evolutionary game model. Energy 2021, 230, 120899. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Jiang, K.; You, D.; Merrill, R.; Li, Z. Implementation of a multi-agent environmental regulation strategy under Chinese fiscal decentralization: An evolutionary game theoretical approach. J. Clean Prod. 2019, 214, 902–915. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Liu, K.; Liu, Y.; Zhou, H.; Kou, Y.; Ji, Q.; Li, D. Evolutionary game and numerical simulation of participants’ collaborative behavior in integrated project delivery project. Alex Eng. J. 2021, 60, 373–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Hou, J.; Li, B. The Evolutionary Game for Collaborative Innovation of the IoT Industry under Government Leadership in China: An IoT Infrastructure Perspective. Sustainability 2020, 12, 3648. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Fang, Y.; Wei, W.; Liu, F.; Mei, S.; Chen, L.; Li, J. Improving solar power usage with electric vehicles: Analyzing a public-private partnership cooperation scheme based on evolutionary game theory. J. Clean Prod. 2019, 233, 1284–1297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Wang, J.; Hu, Y.; Qu, W.; Ma, L. Research on Emergency Supply Chain Collaboration Based on Tripartite Evolutionary Game. Sustainability 2022, 14, 11893. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Li, D.; Wang, Y. Online Learning Management for Primary and Secondary Students during the COVID-19 Epidemic: An Evolutionary Game Theory Approach. Sustainability 2022, 14, 12416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Karaoglan, M.U. Drive cycle performance analysis for various powertrain alternatives of zero-emission battery electric military vehicles. Int. J. Global Warm. 2021, 25, 482–497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Sanxiang, S.; Yunxia, Z. in Monitoring of Harmful Gas for Yangbajing 1# Tunnel in High Altitude Plateau. In Proceedings of the 2014 Sixth International Conference on Measuring Technology and Mechatronics Automation, Zhangjiajie, China, 10–11 January 2014; pp. 410–412. [Google Scholar]
  49. Wu, B.; Zhao, R.; Meng, G.; Xu, S.; Qiu, W.; Chen, H. A numerical study on CO migration after blasting in high-altitude tunnel by inclined shaft. Sci. Rep. 2022, 12, 14696. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  50. Woś, P.; Michalski, J. Effect of Initial Cylinder Liner Honing Surface Roughness on Aircraft Piston Engine Performances. Tribol. Lett. 2011, 41, 555–567. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  51. Anselma, P.G.; Belingardi, G. Fuel cell electrified propulsion systems for long-haul heavy-duty trucks: Present and future cost-oriented sizing. Appl. Energy 2022, 321, 119354. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Lu, C.; Liu, J.; Liu, Y.; Liu, Y. Intelligent construction technology of railway engineering in China. Front. Eng. Manag. 2019, 6, 503–516. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Lu, C.; Cai, C. Challenges and Countermeasures for Construction Safety during the Sichuan–Tibet Railway Project. Engineering 2019, 5, 833–838. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Qiu, Y.; Chen, H.; Sheng, Z.; Cheng, S. Governance of institutional complexity in megaproject organizations. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2019, 37, 425–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Zhang, D.; Sun, Z.; Fang, Q. Scientific problems and research proposals for Sichuan–Tibet railway tunnel construction. Undergr. Space 2021, 7, 419–439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Wang, S.; Zhao, F.; Liu, Z.; Hao, H. Heuristic method for automakers’ technological strategy making towards fuel economy regulations based on genetic algorithm: A China’s case under corporate average fuel consumption regulation. Appl. Energy 2017, 204, 544–559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Zhao, T.; Liu, Z. A novel analysis of carbon capture and storage (CCS) technology adoption: An evolutionary game model between stakeholders. Energy 2019, 189, 116352. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Liu, K.; Zhou, H.; Kou, Y.; Zhang, J.; Zhou, X.; Zhang, X. Simulation study on passive buildings’ demand incentive based on evolutionary game. J. Intell. Fuzzy Syst. 2019, 37, 3163–3174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The relationship between the three agents.
Figure 1. The relationship between the three agents.
Sustainability 14 15309 g001
Figure 2. Dynamic evolution diagram of government’s decision-making.
Figure 2. Dynamic evolution diagram of government’s decision-making.
Sustainability 14 15309 g002
Figure 3. Dynamic evolution diagram of equipment manufacturers’ decision-making.
Figure 3. Dynamic evolution diagram of equipment manufacturers’ decision-making.
Sustainability 14 15309 g003
Figure 4. Dynamic evolution diagram of construction units’ decision-making.
Figure 4. Dynamic evolution diagram of construction units’ decision-making.
Sustainability 14 15309 g004
Figure 5. Evolution path of three-agent game.
Figure 5. Evolution path of three-agent game.
Sustainability 14 15309 g005
Figure 6. Evolution path of initial intention x change. (a) The effect on the y value, (b) The effect on the z value.
Figure 6. Evolution path of initial intention x change. (a) The effect on the y value, (b) The effect on the z value.
Sustainability 14 15309 g006aSustainability 14 15309 g006b
Figure 7. Evolution path of initial intention y change. (a) The effect on the x value, (b) The effect on the z value.
Figure 7. Evolution path of initial intention y change. (a) The effect on the x value, (b) The effect on the z value.
Sustainability 14 15309 g007aSustainability 14 15309 g007b
Figure 8. Evolution path of initial intention z change. (a) The effect on the x value, (b) The effect on the y value.
Figure 8. Evolution path of initial intention z change. (a) The effect on the x value, (b) The effect on the y value.
Sustainability 14 15309 g008aSustainability 14 15309 g008b
Figure 12. The impact of E3 on evolutionary results of equipment manufacturers.
Figure 12. The impact of E3 on evolutionary results of equipment manufacturers.
Sustainability 14 15309 g012
Table 1. Hypotheses of relevant parameters in evolutionary game models and their meanings.
Table 1. Hypotheses of relevant parameters in evolutionary game models and their meanings.
AgentsParametersDescriptions
GovernmentG1Government’s initial benefits.
G2The human, material, and financial costs incurred by the government in adopting Positive regulation strategies.
G3The fines imposed by the government on construction units that pollute the environment during regulation and regulate.
G4The government’s industrial upgrading benefits that the equipment manufacturers carry out positive innovation of electric equipment.
G5The government’s ecological benefits that the construction units carry out positive application of electric equipment.
Equipment manufacturersE1Equipment manufacturers’ initial benefits.
E2The equipment manufacturers’ brand benefits from carrying out positive innovation of electric equipment to increase.
E3The additional R&D costs incurred by the equipment manufacturers in adopting positive innovation for electric equipment.
E4The additional incentives provided by the government to the equipment manufacturers that carry out positive innovation of electric equipment.
Construction unitsC1Construction units’ initial benefits.
C2The additional costs incurred by maintenance and purchase of spare equipment due to immature technology when applying electric equipment for the construction units before the equipment manufacturer carries out positive innovation.
C3The reduced costs that the construction unit applies the electric equipment after the equipment manufacturer carries out positive innovation.
C4The government subsidies for the construction units by carrying out positive application of electric equipment.
Table 2. Set of three-agent game strategies.
Table 2. Set of three-agent game strategies.
Equipment Manufacturers
Positive Innovation (y)Negative Innovation (1 − y)
Construction Units
Positive Application (z)Negative Application (1 − z)Positive Application (z)Negative Application (1 − z)
GovernmentPositive regulation (x)(Positive regulation, Positive innovation, Positive application)(Positive regulation, Positive innovation, Negative application)(Positive regulation, Negative innovation, Positive application)(Positive regulation, Negative innovation, Negative application)
Negative regulation (1 − x)(Negative regulation, Positive innovation, Positive application)(Negative regulation, Positive innovation, Negative application)(Negative regulation, Negative innovation, Positive application)(Negative regulation, Negative innovation, Negative application)
Table 3. Perceived payoff matrix for the three-agents game.
Table 3. Perceived payoff matrix for the three-agents game.
Behavioral StrategiesGovernment’s Benefits Equipment Manufacturers’ BenefitsConstruction Units’ Benefits
(Positive regulation, Positive innovation, Positive application)G1G2 + G4 + G5E4C4E1 + E2E3 + E4C1 + C3 + C4
(Positive regulation, Positive innovation, Negative application) G1G2 + G3 + G4E4E1 + E2E3 + E4C1G3
(Positive regulation, Negative innovation, Positive application)G1G2 + G5C4E1C1C2 + C4
(Positive regulation, Negative innovation, Negative application)G1G2 + G3E1C1G3
(Negative regulation, Positive innovation, Positive application)G1 + G4 + G5E1 + E2E3C1 + C3
(Negative regulation, Positive innovation, Negative application)G1 + G4E1 + E2E3C1
(Negative regulation, Negative innovation, Positive application)G1 + G5E1C1C2
(Negative regulation, Negative innovation, Negative application)G1E1C1
Table 4. Eigenvalues of Jacobian matrix.
Table 4. Eigenvalues of Jacobian matrix.
Equilibrium Pointλ1λ2λ3Stability Condition
P1 (0,0,0)E2E3G3G2C2E2E3 < 0, G3G2 < 0
P2 (0,0,1)C2E2E3G2C4unstable point
P3 (0,1,0)C3E3E2G3G2E4unstable point
P4 (0,1,1)E3E2C3C4E4G2E3E2 < 0
P5 (1,0,0)G2G3C4C2 + G3E2E3 + E4unstable point
P6 (1,0,1)C4 + G2E2E3 + E4C2C4G3unstable point
P7 (1,1,0)C3 + C4 + G3E4+G2G3E3E2E4unstable point
P8 (1,1,1)G2 + C4 + E4C3C4G3E3E2E4unstable point
Table 5. The initial parameter settings.
Table 5. The initial parameter settings.
AgentsGovernmentEquipment ManufacturersConstruction Units
ParameterG1G2G3G4G5E1E2E3E4C1C2C3C4
Assignment1005510101001510510010155
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Yang, X.; Liu, Y.; Liu, K.; Hu, G.; Zhao, X. Research on Promotion and Application Strategy of Electric Equipment in Plateau Railway Tunnel Based on Evolutionary Game. Sustainability 2022, 14, 15309. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142215309

AMA Style

Yang X, Liu Y, Liu K, Hu G, Zhao X. Research on Promotion and Application Strategy of Electric Equipment in Plateau Railway Tunnel Based on Evolutionary Game. Sustainability. 2022; 14(22):15309. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142215309

Chicago/Turabian Style

Yang, Xiaoxu, Yuming Liu, Kai Liu, Guangzhong Hu, and Xi Zhao. 2022. "Research on Promotion and Application Strategy of Electric Equipment in Plateau Railway Tunnel Based on Evolutionary Game" Sustainability 14, no. 22: 15309. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142215309

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop