2.1. Corporate Governance
The Korea Corporate Governance Service (KCGS) evaluates the corporate governance of listed companies in South Korea and publishes their ratings. The standard system for evaluation of governance consists of the evaluation of five subordinate governance categories (protection of shareholder rights, board of directors, disclosure, auditing body, and distribution of business profits). The protection of shareholder rights consists of convenience in exercising shareholder rights, ownership structure, and transactions with specially related parties. The board consists of the composition, operation, evaluation, and compensation of the board of directors. The disclosure section consists of company briefing sessions, predictive information, outside directors, and website disclosures. The auditing body consists of the audit committee, the non-audit service of external auditors, the protective regulations for whistleblowers, and the transparency of transactions with affiliates. Lastly, distribution of business profits is composed of price-dividend yield, dividend payout ratio, and implementation of interim or quarterly dividends.
Governance evaluation by the KCGS has been implemented since the IMF financial crisis, and the standard system was drawn up based on the governance principles of the OECD. In 1999, the Corporate Governance Improvement Committee drafted the Corporate Governance Best Practices in accordance with the current situation in South Korea, and efforts have been made to establish a governance system at the level of advanced countries for public companies and financial institutions. The improved corporate governance mechanism developed through these efforts had a positive impact on corporate values and policies [
1]. Better governance can improve the interests of managers and shareholders, thus lessening information asymmetry and agency costs, eventually improving investment efficiency [
2].
Corporate governance is an area on which empirical studies are actively conducted not only in the field of accounting but also in the field of financial management. Prior studies related to corporate governance mostly examined the relationships between corporate governance and company values/business performance, or the association between corporate governance and earnings quality [
15]. However, few studies examined the relationship between corporate governance and labor investment efficiency. Therefore, this study examines the relationship between corporate governance and labor investment efficiency.
2.2. Labor Investment Efficiency
Labor investment efficiency is defined as the difference between the actual employment growth rate and the expected employment growth rate. According to this method, the greater the extent to which the actual employment growth rate of a firm deviates from the appropriate level, the lower the labor investment efficiency [
14]. An efficient investment is made when a firm chooses an investment that brings about a positive net present value in the absence of market friction [
9]. Investment inefficiency arises from an imperfect capital market. Previous studies were conducted centering on the causes of investment inefficiency and factors that can control it in the presence of information asymmetry. Those studies have been conducted centering on agency costs as a cause of investment inefficiency and the quality of profits and mechanisms, such as corporate governance, as monitoring devices to control investment inefficiency. According to Biddle and Hilary’s (2006) [
8] study examining the relationship between investment efficiency and accounting quality, excellent accounting quality reduces information asymmetry between managers and external suppliers of capital.
In the past, studies related to labor investment were conducted by approaching the concept of investment efficiency through a model to measure labor investment efficiency. However, since labor investment efficiency is an indicator of overemployment and underemployment, this study approaches the aspects of overemployment and underemployment, rather than the concept of investment efficiency, to analyze labor investment efficiency. Jung et al. (2014) [
14] examined the quality of financial reporting and labor investment efficiency. According to the results of the analysis, the higher the quality of financial reporting, the better the labor investment efficiency, indicating that accounting quality acts as a mechanism for improvement of labor investment efficiency. Ghaly et al. (2015) [
16] tested the effects of institutional investors’ investment behavior on labor investment efficiency. As a result of the analysis, it was found that long-term investors are performing more effective monitoring, which reduces agency problems in labor investment choices.
Kang and Cho (2017) [
11] analyzed whether the quality of accounting information and the intensity of competition, which play the role of corporate governance inside and outside the company, respectively, improve the efficiency of labor investment or not. As a result of the analysis, it was found that the quality of accounting information and the intensity of competition improved labor investment efficiency. Both the quality of accounting information and the intensity of competition are interpreted as improving labor investment efficiency by suppressing managers’s opportunistic decision-making incentives, and alleviating information asymmetry between managers and external investors.
Fu and Lee (2017) [
17] examined the effect of managers’s ability and the quality of profits on labor investment decision-making, and analyzed the combined effect of managers’s ability and the quality of profits on labor investment decision-making. According to the results of the analysis, first, managers’s ability and labor investment efficiency had a positive (+) relationship. That is, according to the viewpoint of efficient contracts, as the managers’s ability increases, efforts will be made to maximize shareholder wealth by maintaining an appropriate level of employment of employees. Second, the higher the quality of profit, the higher the labor investment efficiency. The excellent quality of profits is interpreted as alleviating the moral hazard and adverse selection problems due to managers’s information superiority, and improving labor investment efficiency in terms of employment and dismissal.
Yoo and Cho (2018) [
18] analyzed the effect of managers’s characteristics on labor investment efficiency. As a result of the analysis, it was found that the better the managers’s ability, the higher the labor investment efficiency of the company. It is interpreted that if the manager’s ability is excellent, prudent labor investment will be made, leading to efficient labor investment. In addition, it was found that the higher the manager’s overconfidence propensity, the lower the efficiency of labor investment. This is interpreted as indicating that future business performance is viewed optimistically due to the manager’s overconfidence propensity, leading to various optimistic investments so that labor investment efficiency is reduced.
Mo and Lee (2019) [
19] reported that an increase in labor investment efficiency is attributed to a reduction in a firm’s over-firing problem. They document that the positive influence of unaffiliated analysts on labor investment efficiency holds when firms have high cash holdings. Le and Tran (2021) [
2] found that board reforms are positively associated with labor investment efficiency because they benefit firms in reducing over-hiring, under-hiring, and over-firing.
When the results of previous studies examined above are put together, it can be seen that labor investment efficiency can be increased by means that can reduce information asymmetry. Therefore, it is expected that the inefficient distortion of corporate resource allocation due to information asymmetry can be alleviated by corporate governance. Therefore, a hypothesis was established as follows:
Hypothesis 1 (H1). Corporate governance and labor investment efficiency will have a positive (+) relationship.
Meanwhile, large family-owned business conglomerates that exist in Asian countries have complicated transactions between affiliated firms, and they have the problem of using them to achieve their private purposes [
20]. Bae et al. (2002) [
21] reported evidence that firms belonging to chaebol groups in Korea expediently transfer wealth through internal transactions between firms. However, the internal transactions of chaebol groups do not only have negative effects; rather, these can increase the firm’s value in certain cases [
20]. A particular case is propping. Propping describes when a subsidiary is in trouble, and the parent company supports them, benefitting more than a company that is not part of the chaebol group [
20]. Bae et al. (2008) [
22] showed that subsidiaries belonging to chaebol groups in Korea increase their reported earnings and their corporate value through propping.
There are two evaluations of the Korean chaebol system. One is a positive evaluation that it played a leading role in driving the economy in the past. The other is that it hinders the efficiency of firm operations with a closed corporate governance structure centered on large shareholders, and damages ordinary minority shareholders through selfish management favoring specific households. It is also argued that the monopolistic position of the large group of firms hampers balanced development of the national economy [
20]. Particularly, companies belonging to a chaebol have a much more complex ownership and governance structure than non-chaebol companies, so that experts from outside firms are often unable to grasp the facts, even if they are always monitored. Korean chaebols are connected by complicated personal and family relationships and are engaged in numerous types of businesses [
20].
Based on the above, information asymmetry can be different depending on whether a company belongs to a chaebol group, so the relationship between corporate governance and labor investment efficiency is likely to be different. If the information asymmetry of companies belonging to a chaebol group is large, the relationship between corporate governance and labor investment efficiency will be greater than that of companies belonging to non-chaebol groups. On the other hand, if information asymmetry is small, the relationship between the two will be smaller than that of companies belonging to non-chaebol groups. Therefore, the following null hypothesis is established in relation to the effect of a chaebol group on the relationship between corporate governance and labor investment efficiency.
Hypothesis 2 (H2). The relationship between corporate governance and labor investment efficiency will differ depending on whether the company belongs to a chaebol group.