Next Article in Journal
How Low-Code Tools Contribute to Diversity, Equity, and Inclusion (DEI) in the Workplace: A Case Study of a Large Japanese Corporation
Previous Article in Journal
Integrating Technology Roadmaps into the Construction of Learning Indicators
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Towards a General Theory of Sustainable Development: Using a Sustainability Window Approach to Explore All Possible Scenario Paths of Economic Growth and Degrowth

1
Finland Futures Research Centre, University of Turku, 20014 Turku, Finland
2
School of Architecture, Planning and Environmental Policy, University College Dublin, D04 V1W8 Dublin, Ireland
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2024, 16(13), 5326; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16135326
Submission received: 3 April 2024 / Revised: 10 June 2024 / Accepted: 16 June 2024 / Published: 22 June 2024

Abstract

:
Across decades of contemporary discussion on sustainable development, a core concern has been the balance between economic, social, and environmental dimensions. A critical strand of the debate focuses on economic growth versus economic degrowth and, more specifically, on whether economic growth can be sustainable in environmental terms and whether degrowth can be sustainable in social terms. This conceptual and theoretical article used the Sustainability Window, or “SuWi”’ method, to theoretically determine the sustainable window of economies. The window is defined as the upper and lower bounds of future change in GDP that could be deemed in line with achieving both environmental and social sustainability. The conceptual analysis considers all theoretically possible scenario paths for development by combining the outcome paths of economic, environmental, and social dimensions with the environmental and social productivities of GDP. Through SuWi analysis, it is found that only four of the logically possible scenario paths could be considered theoretically “sustainable”—two cases involving economic growth and two of degrowth. In the cases of each of the four paths, sustainability only emerges where they adhere to strict conditions in terms of environmental and social outcomes, as well as related productivities. The SuWi approach and its applied analytical formulas have many potential uses in 21st-century policymaking for sustainability, including supporting the United Nations Sustainable Development Goals. It provides a unique and comprehensive theoretical and analytical framework that enables the categorisation of the complex challenges of sustainability and quantitative analysis of policy choices. Such foresight analysis could greatly assist in providing an evidence base for future development planning and policy formulation, ex ante of locking in a pathway. Further implementation in applied studies that explore a comprehensive indicator set, robust and consistent across all relevant dimensions, offers a promising opportunity to advance empirical analysis of key questions in sustainable development globally at a critical juncture in human history.

1. Introduction

Across forty years of evolution in thinking on sustainable development, the debate on the place of growth has been central [1,2,3]. While economic growth can be linked to improvements in welfare and poverty alleviation, it is now broadly accepted that it is also a mega-driver of global climate change and ecological breakdown [4,5,6] and drives problems of equity and growing in-country inequality [7,8,9,10]. The question of how to achieve sustainable development in the 21st century continues to be accompanied by disagreement on the role of economic growth, including the growth–degrowth debate [11,12], prospects for green growth [13], limits to growth [14], and questions on the implications of productivity growth [15].
There is a broad scientific literature focusing on economic growth and economic development issues, especially in the field of development studies and research [16,17,18,19,20,21]. Economic growth and economic development are two related but distinct concepts that measure the performance and progress of a country or region. Referring to this broad scientific discussion, key differences between these two central concepts can be identified: (1) Economic growth refers to the change in the amount of goods and services produced in a given period of time, while economic development refers to the improvement of human well-being of the population in terms of health, politics, social or any other specific socio-cultural themes of social systems deemed relevant. (2) Economic growth is usually measured by real Gross Domestic Product (GDP), which is the value of goods and services produced by the national economy at constant prices, with many empirical studies relying on this indicator. (3) On the other hand, economic development is often measured using the Human Development Index (HDI), a key statistical indicator taking into account life expectancy, education level, and purchasing power parity (PPP) income per capita. (4) Economic growth is one of the components of economic development, but it is neither the only nor necessarily the most important one. Contemporaneously, the “happiness” of the population is often measured and given analytical and policy importance [3,5]. Economic development also requires other socio-cultural factors, such as political stability, rule of law, low level of corruption, environmental protection, equality, human rights, and cultural diversity [22,23,24,25]. It is important to note that economic growth can, in some cases, become an obstacle to economic development, where growth in the economy drives harm or delivers public bads, with examples including environmental degradation, natural resource depletion, increasing inequality, social unrest or loss of cultural identity. When acknowledging that there are a variety of social priorities that are accorded value [3] in the context of achieving sustainable development, the process of economic development must then deliver a balance between economic growth and other priorities [26,27,28].
The original idea of sustainable development, proposed by the Brundtland Commission’s report “Our Common Future”, was of three “pillars”: economy, environment, and society [29,30]. Scientometric reviews of global research on sustainability and sustainable development reveal that the Brundtland Report has been an important and highly impactful report for global sustainability research [31,32,33,34]. Several research traditions based on the Brundtland Report use indicators to analyse the different dimensions of sustainability [35,36,37]. For instance, Holden et al. [35] suggest using four main composite indicators–ecological footprint, the Human Development Index (HDI), the Gini coefficient, and the share of renewable energy—in order to cover the four main dimensions of sustainability: (i) safeguarding long-term ecological sustainability, (ii) satisfying basic human needs, and promoting (iii) intragenerational equity and (iv) intergenerational equity. Figure 1 illustrates the ubiquitous three intersecting circles of sustainability and common alternative depictions from Purvis et al. [38]. The following article discusses the interpretation of sustainable development over time in terms of economic growth, social development, and ecological sustainability.
Sustainability has diverse origins from the 17th century onwards [39], yet the modern concept, which arrived in the mainstream in the 1980s, emerged from The Club of Rome’s “Limits to Growth” [40]. This world systems scenario study was criticised by many economists, as the simulation did not include a price mechanism, the primary signalling mechanism for consumer behaviour [41,42,43]. Many economists, political scientists, ecologists, and scientists started thinking about optimal growth paths and how to provide for the growing human population in a world that had limited empirical analysis of global systems at the time. This branch of literature extended to scarcity, overpopulation, and environmental degradation [27,44,45,46,47,48]. Yet, in line with the Brundtland definition of sustainable development [29], economic growth has continued to persist centrally in debates. A conventional taxonomy of possibilities for growth could be presented as follows: (1) there must be continued economic growth, (2) there cannot be economic growth beyond a certain limit, and (3) economic growth must decline, as limits have already been exceeded. While the former assumes that economic growth is necessary for social development and can be ecologically sustainable, the latter two characterisations broadly contend that growth is neither necessary for social development nor can it be environmentally sustainable.
A range of economists and system theory scholars have contributed to these discussions. In the economics literature, the first approach—there must be growth—was articulated in the Brundtland Commission report, and the neoclassical approach to sustainable development was found primarily in the writings of Robert Solow [49] and Joseph Stiglitz [50]. Endogenous growth theory also has a sustainable growth model [51,52] related to Solow–Stiglitz’s thinking. Herman Daly was critical of this approach, noting that there cannot be economic growth beyond a certain limit, or there cannot be economic growth [53,54,55,56,57,58]. The third approach—economic growth must decline as limits have already been exceeded—was linked to the degrowth movement led by Joan Martinez-Alier [2,19,43,59,60,61] and Serge Latouche [62,63]. The work of Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen [64] on entropy and economics is fundamental to this strand as a key contributor to steady-state and degrowth economics.
In seeking to understand the relationship of growth to pollution, the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) by Grossman and Krueger [65] has been a dominant approach among economists. However, the results of EKC studies vary depending on the pollutant and other factors outside of income, with questions on its empirical robustness [66]. In line with recognising the need to explore other drivers outside of income, including structural and intensity effects, attention shifted to further disaggregation of the analysis. The IPAT and Kaya identities have been important in sustainability evaluation by deepening an understanding of the systemic driving forces of environmental problems, including the role of economic growth. The IPAT identity [67,68,69] defines major reasons for environmental impact (I) as a multiplicative identity of Population (P), Affluence (A), and Technology (T). The Kaya identity is a specific application of the IPAT identity that identifies the major drives of carbon dioxide emissions, such as population, GDP per capita, the energy intensity of the economy, and carbon intensity of the energy mix [70]. Decades of decomposition analysis studies have deepened knowledge of these drivers, including activity, structure, and intensity effects [71]. These studies have emphasised how increased affluence has been driving global resource consumption and related emissions, and this has highlighted the necessity to decouple the impact of affluence from environmental impact through both structural and technological factors. While sustainability analysis, such as in the case of an EKC, can be performed on a single dimension, it has been noted that this approach fails to comprehensively address all three dimensions of sustainability, requiring a more complex analysis of multiple dimensions [72,73].
While the purpose of this paper is not to present a comprehensive literature review on sustainable development research, context can be established by referring to useful review articles on the issue of sustainable development and sustainability research, including assessments critical of the concept, such as [74,75,76,77,78]. In this article, we argue that the theories of sustainable development are fragmented, in parallel with the fragmentation of global governance of sustainable development [79,80]. The implications are that the theoretical starting point necessarily depends on the research topic, focus, and perspective taken [81,82]. Related to this complexity, generic theories of sustainable development that take into account all dimensions of sustainability are difficult to find in the literature. Attempts to develop theoretical approaches to the complexity of the sustainability dimensions, especially in the case of economic sustainability [83,84,85,86] and also attempts to develop a new theory of social sustainability [3,87,88] are examples of significant though rare advancements in sustainable development theory.
Sustainable development aims to enhance the resilience of social, economic, and environmental systems to withstand shocks and stresses, such as natural disasters, economic crises, or social unrest. Addressing the challenges of sustainable development requires a deep understanding of these complex interactions and feedback loops and the ability to manage them effectively through adaptive, inclusive, and systemic approaches. Complex problems relating to the nexus of unsustainable environmental and socio-economic development require robust research methods that facilitate this holistic analysis [83,84,85,86].
The Sustainability Window analysis proposed by Luukkanen et al. [48,72,89] facilitates such integrated analysis as a coherent, comprehensive, and operationalised framework that can describe the change in multiple sustainability dimensions over time. The research seeks to clarify the problem and theoretical challenge posed by Dutch economist Roefie Hueting [90] regarding conflicting goals in the sustainable development process. The Sustainability Window (SuWi) provides an integrated assessment of complex multidimensional sustainability problems by determining the maximum economic growth—to avoid negative change in the environmental condition of a selected environmental indicator—and the minimum economic growth—to achieve positive social development of a selected social indicator. These maximum and minimum levels of economic growth define the Sustainability Window and can be specified in either relative or absolute form, depending on the requirement. The approach provides a general platform for building sustainability science as an evolving academic discipline, which can point the way to sustainable development paths, addressing challenges that existing approaches have not yet fully addressed. This includes the UN Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) and inherent contradictions concerning economic growth, as emphasised by Hickel [91]. While acknowledging the complexity of theoretical discussion in the article, in conceiving all possible paths and all theoretically relevant sustainability criteria, in the application, the analytical structure of SuWi can support ease of use for analysts and ease of understanding for policymakers. SuWi can permit interdisciplinary, integrated assessment and stringent critique of policy and of future scenarios and forecasts once the selected environmental and social criteria have been appropriately understood and defended.
Cognisant of decades of debate on the role and impact of economic growth, this article seeks to determine the sustainability window as the theoretical upper and lower bounds of economic growth that could deliver social and environmental sustainability. The article considers all theoretically conceivable combinations in Section 2; this allows all logically possible combinations to be identified, also in Section 2. From the latter, Section 3 identifies those combinations that could be considered socially and environmentally sustainable by considering both possible paths and absolute targets. This rationalised process of elimination allows the article to focus on the theoretical place of economic growth in a general theory of sustainable development.

2. Materials and Methods

This section first describes the conceptualisation of the Sustainability Window (SuWi). The SuWi approach can be utilised to analyse different dimensions of sustainability, both generalised and specific. Any of the 17 dimensions of the UN Sustainable Development Goals could be used in the analysis if suitable data are available, or it could be limited to a narrower field of study. While sustainability is often analysed in three dimensions—economic, environmental and social—it is relevant to note that these dimensions can consist of numerous sub-categories. For clarity of analysis, we present the cases here using three dimensions, but the SuWi method itself does not limit the use of dimensions of development. In all cases, to identify minimum and maximum economic growth, environmental and social dimensions are analysed pairwise with GDP and then combined to produce the sustainability window of GDP. The intergenerational equity emphasised by the Brundtland Commission [29] and explicitly suggested as a fourth dimension of sustainability by Holden et al. [35] could also be included by using the dynamic SuWi approach [73,75], which allows the analysis of changes and trends over time—even over generations—in the width of the Sustainability Window and in construction of related future scenarios.
The innovation of the SuWi approach is that it provides a means to analyse development in three dimensions simultaneously. In SuWi, quantitative indicators describe the change in these three different dimensions. For the environmental dimension, indicators that track changes in environmental vectors or the state of the environment, such as greenhouse gas emissions, land-use change, biodiversity, water quality, or chemical pollution, can be selected. The increase in the value of the environmental indicator means that environmental pressure is increasing, indicating an undesirable direction of development. For the social dimension, indicators that track social processes and outcomes can be used, such as education, income, gender equality, social equity, unemployment, health, life expectancy, governance, democracy, food and water availability, or sanitation. An increase in the value of the social indicator means that social welfare is improving, indicating a desirable direction of development. In the SuWi, the economic dimension is typically described by GDP, specifically to understand the implications of economic growth paths. It is widely acknowledged that GDP, as an indicator of economic production, provides a poor proxy for human well-being, or indeed sustainability [3,74,92,93]. However, in this context, using GDP allows economic output to be separated from social and environmental dimensions toward deliberate analysis and critique of economic growth paths themselves. To determine the “sustainability window,” the analysis combines two different two-dimensional frameworks: first, development in environmental stress and economic output, and second, changes in the dimensions of social welfare and economic output. Combining these two frameworks facilitates the description of sustainability amongst all three dimensions. Because there is no general indicator describing environmental stress, different indicators could be used for it. Similarly, there is no general indicator for social welfare, and different indicators could be used for this dimension. In order to obtain a multifaceted view of sustainability, several different indicator combinations should be used in the analyses.
In this article, we apply the concepts of weak and strong sustainability in the following manner: “Weak sustainability” is defined in relative terms as an outcome where the intensity of environmental stress (Environmental stress/GDP) does not increase. In contrast, “Strong sustainability” is defined in absolute terms, where the environmental stress itself reduces from a base year value, with an associated stasis or absolute increase in social welfare. Following this, the strong Sustainability Window can then theoretically be either a case of economic growth or degrowth, where the maximum economic growth, GDPmax, avoids increasing environmental stress, and the minimum economic growth, GDPmin, avoids a decrease in social welfare. This section addresses the cases of both economic growth and degrowth to clarify the different possibilities for sustainable development in the context of change in the economy. The rationale is advanced first in a narrative form and then illustrated graphically to explain the theoretical combination of paths for the economy with possible levels of environmental stress and of social welfare. To explore the different possible system relationships, such as changes in productivity, the narrative discusses changes in environmental stress productivity and social welfare productivity. Environmental stress productivity is defined as environmental stress divided by GDP, and social welfare productivity is defined as social welfare divided by GDP for a given year and indicator. While defining absolute or productivity changes necessarily defines the related absolute or productivity indicators, the narrative form moves pairwise through different subsets of absolute and productivity indicators, thus allowing all possible cases to be theoretically explored.
Through the combination of these theoretical outcomes, the Sustainability Window, or “SuWi”, is determined. This allows for all possible scenario paths of development to be explored. To facilitate this theoretical discussion of all possible combinations, the first part of the results, Section 3, considers relative changes in environmental and social welfare outcomes in the context of economic growth and degrowth. Relative change here is defined as a change from the base year value. However, it is also recognised that to move from a grounding that could be described as “theoretically possible” to “theoretically sustainable”, a relative change by improving productivity will often not be sufficient. In many cases, for environmental indicators, such as a change in greenhouse gases, absolute limits and reductions are necessary for sustainability. This is the case even though the Paris Agreement on climate change states, “To limit global warming to 1.5 °C, greenhouse gas emissions must peak before 2025 at the latest and decline 43% by 2030”, setting a relative target. In other cases, for social welfare, an absolute increase may be required, such as in cases where poverty reduction and elimination are required. To move from relative change to absolute change, in line with a specified target, Section 3 combines target levels in the narrative explanation and related graphical presentations for illustration. Section 3, therefore, contributes to moving from outcomes that are defined more by covering the theoretically possible window—of all possible development paths—to the sustainability window of economic growth—as the actual requirements of what could be considered real-world sustainability for a given change in an economy. Within this configuration, the “development path”, is a broad multidimensional representation of how global, national or regional development may evolve across multiple drivers [94]. It is simplified in SuWi as quantitative economic, environmental, and social dimensions through change in total economic output and in the macro-environmental and social productivities of systems at the chosen level of analysis.
The SuWi approach is first demonstrated with an example case and then widened to include all possible development paths. Figure 2 illustrates an example of development in environmental and economic dimensions. The indicators for economic output (GDP) and environmental stress (Env) are indexed to have a value of 1 in the base year, indicated with point A, and having values GDP0 and Env0 on the x and y-axis. Point A determines the base year environmental stress productivity, defined as the amount of environmental stress produced per unit of economic output (of GDP), with both measured by indexed indicators, with line r1 = Env0/GDP0. In this case, an indicative final point of development is denoted by point E, which has the values GDP1 and Env1. The improved environmental stress productivity of GDP is expressed with line r2 = Env1/GDP1 (Env1/GDP1 < Env0/GDP0). However, if we assume that the criterion for environmental sustainability is that environmental stress should not increase, and under the ceteris paribus condition for environmental stress productivity r2, then the maximum sustainable economic output, in this case, is indicated by point B and has the value GDPmax. Determining that environmental stress must not increase, where the improvement in environmental stress productivity is limited, demands that sustainable GDP growth be limited.
An example of determining the minimum economic output concerning social welfare development (Soc) is shown in Figure 3. The indicators for economic output and social welfare are again indexed to have the value 1 in the base year and have values GDP0 and Soc0 on the x and y-axis. Point A determines the social welfare productivity of GDP and how much social welfare is produced per unit of GDP, with line r1 = Soc0/GDP0, which has the same value as in Figure 2 (indexed starting point). A final point of development is indicated with point S, having values GDP1 and Soc1. At this point, the social welfare productivity of GDP is expressed with line r3 = Soc1/GDP1. In this case, the criterion for social sustainability is that social welfare should not decrease. By using the ceteris paribus condition for social welfare productivity r3, the minimum sustainable economic output is indicated with point C, having the value GDPmin. The decreasing welfare productivity r3 (Soc1/GDP1 < Soc0/GDP0) defines a minimum GDP value that is higher than the base year value in order not to decrease social welfare but lower than the actual GDP1 value.
When these cases of environmental and social sustainability are combined, from Figure 2 and Figure 3, we can determine the Sustainability Window with the minimum economic output that preserves welfare and the maximum economic output that avoids increasing environmental stress, as illustrated in Figure 4. The maximum sustainable economic output, GDPmax, is defined with the productivity line r2 = Env1/GDP1 (environmental stress productivity point E) to be at point B, and the minimum sustainable economic output, GDPmin, is defined with the social welfare productivity line r3 = Soc1/GDP1 (defined by point S) to be at the point C. In this case, the real GDP growth is too high (GDP1 is higher than GDPmax), and the sustainability criteria defined by the Sustainability Window (GDPmin < GDP1 < GDPmax) are not satisfied. If welfare is to be maintained, and environmental stress not increased, then the economic Sustainability Window, SuWi, requires an outcome GDPmin < GDP1 < GDPmax.
The illustrated case shows an example where environmental stress increases while environmental stress productivity decreases, and social welfare increases with decreasing social welfare productivity. Next, a case of decreasing environmental stress and stress productivity is combined with increasing social welfare, increasing GDP, and decreasing social welfare productivity.
Figure 5 illustrates this possible development path where the economic output is growing and the environmental sustainability criteria are fulfilled. The starting point is A with environmental stress Env0 and GDP0, and the final point is E with environmental stress Env1 and GDP1. In this case, the environmental stress decreases (Env1 < Env0), and the environmental stress productivity decreases (r2 = Env1/GDP1 < Env0/GDP0), determining the maximum economic output, GDPmax, at point B not to increase environmental stress.
Figure 6 illustrates social welfare development in this case. The starting point is A, and the final point is S. In this case, social welfare increases (Soc1 > Soc0), and social welfare productivity decreases (r3 = Soc1/GDP1 < Soc0/GDP0). The productivity line r3 determines the minimum economic output, GDPmin, at point C in order not to decrease social welfare.
The results from Figure 5 and Figure 6 are combined in Figure 7 to illustrate the Sustainability Window. In this case, the maximum economic output, GDPmax, is higher than the actual GDP1, and the minimum economic output, GDPmin, is lower than GDP1. This means that the development fulfils the sustainability criteria.
The case examples presented above show that with economic growth, it is possible to achieve sustainable development but only under specified conditions. The following Figure 8, Figure 9 and Figure 10 illustrate an economic degrowth case where the economy decreases (GDP1 < GDP0). In Figure 8, the starting point is A with environmental stress Env0 and GDP0. The environmental stress decreases to E with the value Env1 (Env1 < Env0). In Figure 8, the environmental stress level Env1 and GDP level GDP1 define the productivity line r2, decreasing environmental stress productivity (Env1/GDP1 < Env0/GDP0), which determines the potential maximum sustainable economic output, GDPmax, in relation to environmental stress to be at point B.
In Figure 9, the starting point is A with social welfare at Soc0 and economic output at GDP0. At the final point S, the level of social welfare Soc1 and economic output GDP1 define the productivity line r3, in this case increasing social welfare productivity (Soc1/GDP1 > Soc0/GDP0), which determines the minimum sustainable economic output in relation to social welfare to be at point C.
To produce the sustainability window in an economic degrowth case, Figure 10 combines Figure 8 and Figure 9 as maximum and minimum GDP output to define the Sustainability Window. In this case, the sustainability criteria are fulfiled since the actual GDP output (degrowth) is within the Sustainability Window (GDPmin < GDP1 < GDPmax). It can be noticed that the potential maximum sustainable economic output GDPmax is higher than the original GDP0 level, but the actual economic level of GDP1 shows a degrowth case.
The analyses of these case examples are widened in Appendix A to illustrate all possible cases related to changes in environmental stress, environmental stress productivity, social welfare, social welfare productivity, and GDP. Based on the different combinations of these changes, a table of all possible development paths and their sustainability outcomes are combined in Table 1 and presented next in Section 3.

3. Results

3.1. Possible Economic Growth Paths and Related Sustainability Outcomes

In this section, we illustrate different possible scenario paths depending on the possible direction and relative size of changes in the five variables: environmental stress (Env), social welfare (Soc), GDP, and the environmental and social welfare productivities Env/GDP and Soc/GDP. In Section 3.2, the Sustainability Window with absolute targets for environmental stress and social welfare are presented. Section 3.1 and Section 3.2 deal with strong sustainability in terms of absolute changes in the environmental stress and social welfare indicators, but the changes are, however, relative to the base year level, which is not sustainable in absolute terms. With the SuWi approach, it is also possible to analyse weak sustainability if environmental stress intensity is used instead of environmental stress as the environmental indicator. For a detailed discussion of weak and strong sustainability, see [95].
Figure 4, Figure 7, and Figure 10 above illustrate that it is possible to have several different options for future development concerning sustainability, depending on changes in the analysed variables environmental stress (Env), social welfare (Soc), economic output (GDP), and the environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) and social welfare productivity (Soc/GDP). Table 1 illustrates all the possible scenario paths related to the changes in these variables and the resultant sustainability of the development path. Appendix A includes the graphical presentations of the possible development paths indicated in the column “Reference” in Table 1.
Next, all theoretically possible development alternatives are identified for the future by using the SuWi approach, followed by the determination of the alternatives, which can fulfil the criteria of both environmental and social sustainability. First, the relevant variables of economic output (GDP), social welfare (Soc), environmental stress (Env), social welfare productivity (Soc/GDP), and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) are considered. The value of each variable can change, either increasing or decreasing over time. In terms of all possible combinations that can be hypothesised, there are 25 = 32 different possible combinations of changes, as illustrated in Table 1.
Because the productivity indicators, Soc/GDP and Env/GDP, are not independent but depend on changes in GDP, Soc, and Env, all combinations are not logically possible. For instance, when economic activity (GDP) increases, and social welfare (Soc) decreases, then social welfare productivity (Soc/GDP) cannot increase. If GDP increases and environmental stress (Env) decreases, then environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) cannot increase. Similarly, if GDP decreases and Soc or Env increases, then Soc/GDP or Env/GDP cannot decrease. For this reason, all together, 14 out of the 32 hypothesised combinations are logically impossible. These combinations are marked as “impossible” in Table 1. Among the remaining 18 logically possible combinations, six combinations can have two additional alternatives for the difference between the indexed values of environmental stress and social welfare. This difference, as shown in the column titled ΔSoc − ΔEnv in Table 1, is of great importance since it determines whether the Sustainability Window for the economic growth path is positive (GDPmax > GDPmin) or negative (GDPmax < GDPmin).
In Table 1, all 32 combinations of the five variables, the 18 logically possible combinations and the 24 different Sustainability Window analyses of the possible scenario paths are presented (see Appendix A for the graphical presentations of the 24 identified scenario paths). The sustainable cases are illustrated in Figure 11a–d; see also combinations 13, 14, 25 and 29, marked with green in Table 1.
Figure 11a,b illustrates cases where the economic output (GDP) grows, and Figure 11c,d illustrates cases where economic output decreases. In Figure 11a, welfare productivity (Soc1/GDP1 > Soc0/GDP0) increases, and in Figure 11b, welfare productivity decreases (Soc2/GDP2 < Soc0/GDP0). In both cases, environmental stress productivity decreases (Env1/GDP1 < Env0/GDP0). In Figure 11c, social welfare productivity increases, (Soc3/GDP3 > Soc0/GDP0) and environmental stress productivity increases, too (Env3/GDP3 > Env0/GDP0). In Figure 11d, social welfare productivity increases (Soc4/GDP4 > Soc0/GDP0), and environmental stress productivity decreases (Env4/GDP4 < Env0/GDP0).
The sustainable maximum and minimum economic output can be calculated using the following equations:
GDP max Env 0 = GDP 1 Env 1 ,
where
GDP max = GDP 1 × Env 0 Env 1 ,
and
GDP min Soc 0 = GDP 1 Soc 1 ,
where
GDP min = GDP 1 × Soc 0 Soc 1 ,
where Env0 is environmental stress in the base year (measured with suitable indicator and indexed to 1), Env1 is environmental stress in the analysis year, Soc0 is social welfare in the base year (measured with suitable indicator and indexed to 1), Soc1 is social welfare in the analysis year, GDP0 is the economic output in the base year, GDP1 is the economic output in the analysis year, GDPmax is the maximum economic output in order not to increase environmental stress, and GDPmin is the minimum economic output not to decrease social welfare.
These equations are valid for all the cases. A criterion for a sustainable case is the following:
GDPmin < GDP1 < GDPmax

3.2. Analysis of Sustainability Windows with Absolute Targets

It is widely accepted that in the case of many environmental stress variables, such as greenhouse gas emissions and biodiversity loss, an absolute reduction target must be defined for environmental sustainability. In these cases, rather than requiring no increase in environmental stress, the cases would necessarily be framed by the requirement to reach absolute reduction targets. This could also be necessary for social welfare, which is in line with achieving equity. This section considers the Sustainability Window for cases of absolute targets. Figure 12 illustrates a case where there is an absolute target level for environmental stress. The preliminary state of the system is described with indexed levels of environmental stress, Env0, social welfare, Soc0, and economic output, GDP0, at point A. The productivity levels are described as Soc0/GDP0 = Env0/GDP0 (indexed base year values).
If relative criteria for sustainability are used it means that the environmental stress should not increase and social welfare should not decrease. In this case, social development could arrive at point S1, with social welfare at Soc1, environmental development at E1 with environmental stress at Env0, and economic output at level GDP1. In this case, the Sustainability Window would be defined by SuWi1, where the minimum economic output is defined by GDPmin at point Smin (social welfare does not decrease from Soc0) and maximum economic output at point E1 with GDP1 (environmental stress does not increase from Env0). The described development fulfils the relative sustainability criteria identified.
However, adopting an absolute target for the environmental stress, defined with Envtarget, requires lowering the economic output to reach the point Et when environmental stress productivity is Env1/GDP1 = Envtarget/GDPmax. This defines the maximum economic output GDPmax. In this case, the minimum level of economic output is also determined using the point Smin at the level of GDPmin, where social welfare does not decrease. Now, the Sustainability Window is SuWiEt, within which the maximum environmental stress level achieves Envtarget and the minimum social welfare level is Soc0 (at Smin). In this case, the maximum social welfare level is reduced from Soc1 to Soct due to the environmental target criterion. In this type of development path, for economic output to be sustainable, the maximum economic output must be reduced, and social welfare must be reduced from Soc1 to Soct.
This type of development, with an absolute environmental target, could enable either economic growth or degrowth to be sustainable. The economic degrowth possibility is the result of improved social welfare productivity (Soc1/GDP1 > Soc0/GDP0), illustrated in Figure 13. Here, the minimum economic output is defined by GDPmin at point Smin, which is lower than GDP0 enabling sustainable economic degrowth. The Sustainability Window is determined by Smin (GDPmin) and Et, which defines the maximum GDP output, GDPmax, in the same way as in Figure 12.
Maximum GDP, in the case where we have an environmental target, can be calculated as follows:
GDP max Env target = GDP 1 Env 0 ,
where
GDP max = GDP 1 × Env target Env 0
Figure 14 illustrates a case where an absolute social welfare target is applied. The starting point is A, with social welfare at Soc0, environmental stress at Env0, and economic output at GDP0. The productivity of environmental stress is assumed to decrease to Env1/GDP1 (at point E1) and social welfare productivity to increase to Soc1/GDP1 (at point S1). Relative environmental sustainability (no increase in environmental stress) limits the maximum economic output to GDPmax at Et1. The absolute social welfare target determines the minimum economic output to be at the level of GDPmin at St, where the social target Soctarget is reached. Now, GDPmin and GDPmax define the Sustainability Window.
Minimum GDP, in the case when we have a social welfare target (Figure 14), can be calculated as follows:
GDP min Soc target = GDP 1 Soc 1 ,
where
GDP min = GDP 1 × Soc target Soc 1
Beginning with a target for the level of social welfare allows for the determination of the minimum economic output for SuWi accordingly, as shown in Figure 15, in different cases of social welfare productivity. The starting point here is again point A with Soc0 as the level of social welfare, and the Sustainable welfare target is indicated with Soctarget. At this level, the minimum economic output depends on the social welfare productivity of GDP. The social welfare productivity Soc1/GDP1 defines the lowest sustainable level of GDP as GDP1. This indicates that the economic degrowth option is possible, even with an increased target level for social welfare, if the social welfare productivity is increasing.
With the social welfare productivity level Soc2/GDP2, the minimum sustainable GDP, in relation to the sustainable target level of social welfare, must be higher than the original GDP level. With this type of change in welfare productivity, the economic degrowth option is not sustainable; even though welfare productivity is increasing, the increased target level of social welfare cannot be reached with degrowth.
In the case of social welfare productivity level Soc3/GDP3, economic output must be higher than GDP3 to fulfil the social sustainability criterion. This shows that if social welfare productivity decreases, economic output has to be higher to reach a sustainable level of social welfare.
Figure 16 illustrates a case where there are targets for both reduced environmental stress and increased social welfare in an economic degrowth situation. In this case, the environmental stress productivity can even increase (Envtarget/GDP1 > Env0/GDP0) when the social welfare productivity increases (Soctarget/GDP1 > Soc0/GDP0).
In this context, the efficiency gap could be defined as the lack of improvement in environmental efficiency [72] or social productivity to reach a defined sustainability level. Figure 17 illustrates the case of the efficiency gap, where it is assumed that the environmental stress productivity decreases from Env0/GDP0 to the level of Env1/GDP1. This is, however, not enough to reach relative environmental sustainability because the environmental stress is increasing alongside increasing GDP. The environmental stress productivity should be decreased to the level of r2 = Env0/GDP1 in order not to increase environmental stress if the GDP level is GDP1. The efficiency gap, in this case, is r1/r2, and this should be used to guide the policy planning process towards sustainability.

4. Discussion

Across the decades of contemporary thinking on sustainable development, a core debate has concerned whether economic growth can be made environmentally and socially sustainable. In more recent years, this has become a debate about economic growth versus degrowth, whether the former can be environmentally sustainable, and whether the latter can be socially sustainable [12]. This article has used the Sustainability Window, or “SuWi” approach, to theoretically determine the sustainable window of economies, as upper and lower bounds of change in GDP, that could be deemed in line with environmental and social sustainability. All theoretically possible development paths have been considered by first combining the economic, environmental, and social variables with the environmental and social productivity of GDP. The article demonstrates that of the 32 possible combinations of these five variables, 18 are logically possible.
In moving to sustainability analysis through SuWi, it is noted that there are 24 logically possible development paths, yet only four (4) of them could be considered sustainable under the assumed sustainability criteria, defined as the value of a selected environmental indicator cannot increase, and the value of a selected social indicator cannot decrease. Two of these involve economic growth and two degrowth. In these cases, the sustainability of outcomes is predicated not only on the definition of sustainability but also on the emergence of specific paths in terms of absolute change in GDP and related productivity. Once the environmental and social criteria are set, the development path must emerge according to clearly defined quantitative trends if the economic outcome is to be defended as theoretically sustainable from both environmental and social perspectives. In the two sustainable economic growth cases (increasing GDP), social welfare productivity (Soc/GDP) can decrease, but environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) must decrease in both cases to achieve sustainability. In sustainable economic degrowth cases (decreasing GDP), environmental stress productivity can decrease or increase, but social welfare productivity must increase in both cases to achieve sustainability. The analysis illustrates the importance of changes in productivity that reflect different system structures in addition to efficiency related to techno-economic change. To meet specified sustainability criteria, it is then also theoretically possible to adjust growth rates for economic growth or degrowth outcomes. By applying the SuWi analysis, this article can be described as providing a general theory for the place of economic growth in sustainable development, as it can be applied to all possible environmental and social outcomes, all possible paths of economic growth, and all possible combinations of environmental and social productivity of GDP.
In the debate on economic growth, including the classic Simon–Ehrlich wager [96], some have argued that science and technology will enable sustained growth of consumption without harmful growth in the use of natural resources by doing more with less. Others propose that this is not possible, emphasising absolute limits in the carrying capacity of the Earth, concluding that there are limits to either population growth or to material consumption in the rich world, with a necessity to reduce demand and by rapidly scaling up system change alongside technological innovation. The specifics of whether an outcome could be deemed “sustainable” are dependent on the specific environmental and social themes and the relevant criteria applied to define sustainability. Using the SuWi analysis, both relative and absolute targets can be considered in both strong and weak sustainability configurations. The SuWi approach can be used to inform about real development options globally, nationally, and regionally while noting that specific answers in applied settings will also depend upon the choice of environmental and social indicators, data availability, and the real dynamics of sustainability paths. The SuWi approach could also assist in holistic analysis and planning for the UN SDGs [34] and sustainable development, in general, to engage with the critical issues of policy coordination, to analyse synergies and trade-offs, and to assist in understanding policy dialogues about absolute and efficiency targets in evidence-based decision-making. As environmental pressures increase, while climate and ecological breakdown resonate alongside the demands of social sustainability, approaches such as SuWi may become indispensable to sustainability science and effective policymaking.
Rather than static ceteris paribus conditions, a SuWi can be performed as a dynamic integrated analysis, using time series rather than beginning and end points [74], which remains a rarity in integrated approaches. The SuWi can be applied to the estimation of an efficiency gap [72] in the case of absolute environmental or social development targets. This makes the SuWi approach a useful tool for policy analysis to indicate priority areas for improvement in efficiency. When noting the efficiency gap between actual and desired outcomes, a widening or narrowing of the window can give valuable information for policy planning and for guidance on the timing of planned actions and their extent. The minimum and maximum economic growth rates could also be used for the construction of a “doughnut model” of sustainability [97,98]. In the doughnut model, the different pairs of SuWi indicator analysis results are arranged in a radial diagram where the inner circle illustrates the minimum economic growth to guarantee sustainable social development, and the outer circle illustrates the maximum economic growth not to exceed the environmental limits of sustainability. The doughnut model can be used to attain an overall view of multidimensional sustainability and to illustrate the problematic and critical areas of development where special attention is necessary. The dynamic SuWi analysis also allows for the consideration of intergenerational equity, if there is availability of sufficient time series data.
The presented novel theoretical framework for sustainability analysis is unique in categorising all possible development paths and developing explicit rules for sustainability in each case. Future research direction should include testing the developed framework in different case studies and analysing the suitability of different indicator frameworks for the analysis. The properties of the indicators used for the analysis are critical, and their numeric characteristics should be similar. For instance, indicators having exponential growth potential, such as GDP, have distinct differences in properties in comparison to indicators with limited increases, such as the Human Development Index with a maximum value of 1. The latter would require modification to be operationalised, as illustrated by the indicators included in the Sustainable Society Index (SSI) [99].
In the analysis of sustainability processes, the complexity of systems cannot be avoided, including cyclic economic growth and associated sustainability challenges, which are implicit in the approach [100]. The SuWi can provide a platform for ex ante scenario planning to evaluate possible, desirable, and even avoidable future developments. Employing a SuWi in this manner could assist in policy planning under conditions of complexity and uncertainty, which characterise interdependent policy challenges for sustainability. In addition to considering the impact of economic development, the flexibility of SuWi permits multiple uses of key interest to empirical analysis in sustainability science in response to the heterogeneous demands of 21st-century policymaking for sustainability.

Author Contributions

Conceptualisation, J.L., J.V., J.K.-o. and T.O.; methodology, J.L., J.V. and J.K.-o.; validation, J.L. and J.V.; formal analysis, J.L.; investigation, J.L., J.V., J.K.-o. and T.O.; resources, J.L., J.V., J.K.-o. and T.O.; writing—original draft preparation, J.L., J.V., J.K.-o. and T.O.; writing—review and editing, J.L., J.V., J.K.-o. and T.O.; visualisation, J.L.; funding acquisition, J.L., J.V. and J.K.-o. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by The Academy of Finland, grant number 320229.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

All theoretical data is contained within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest. The funders had no role in the design of the study; in the collection, analyses, or interpretation of data; in the writing of the manuscript; or in the decision to publish the results.

Appendix A

This Appendix includes graphical descriptions of all 24 possible development paths presented in Table 1 in the text, regarding the Sustainability Windows of all combinations of environmental stress (Env), social welfare (Soc), economic development (GDP), environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP), and social welfare productivity (Soc/GDP). The 24 possible development paths are grouped into six graphs (Figure A1, Figure A2, Figure A3, Figure A4, Figure A5 and Figure A6). The grouping is based on possible combinations of changes in GDP and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP). In each of Figure A1, Figure A2, Figure A3, Figure A4, Figure A5 and Figure A6, four possible social welfare productivities (Soc/GDP) and related social welfare (Soc) levels are identified.
  • The original values of all variables are marked with subscript 0 (GDP0, Env0, Soc0, Env0/GDP0);
  • The new GDP, Env, and Env/GDP values have a subscript referring to the number of the group (GDP1–GDP6, Env1–Env6, Env1/GDP1–Env6/GDP6;
  • The new social welfare values have a subscript referring to the number of the group and the number of the four cases case (Soc11–Soc64), and the related social welfare productivities have corresponding subscripts (Soc11/GDP1–Soc64/GDP6);
  • The Sustainability Windows are marked with a subscript E referring to the environmental stress of the group (Env1–Env6) and with a subscript S referring to the social welfare case inside each group (Soc11–Soc64), i.e., SuWiE1S11–SuWiE6S64.

Appendix A.1. Group 1 (Figure A1)

Starting point A. Environmental steress E1 in the analysis year. Environmental stress increases (Env1 > Env0), GDP increases (GDP1 > GDP0), and environmental stress productivity increases (Env1/GDP1 > Env0/GDP0)
Social welfare can have four different options:
1.
Soc11 > Soc0 and Soc11 > Env1 and Soc11/GDP1 > Env1/GDP1 and Soc11/GDP1 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE1S11) is positive, but the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP1 > GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
2.
Soc12 > Soc0 and Soc12 < Env1 and Soc12/GDP1 < Env1/GDP1, and Soc12/GDP1 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE1S12) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP1 > GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
3.
Soc13 > Soc0 and Soc13 < Env1 and Soc13/GDP1 < Env1/GDP1, and Soc13/GDP1 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE1S13) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP1 > GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
4.
Soc14 < Soc0 and Soc14 < Env1 and Soc14/GDP1 < Env1/GDP1, and Soc14/GDP1 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE1S14) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax) even though the actual GDP growth is inside the negative SuWi (GDPmax < GDP1 < GDPmin). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
Figure A1. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP, environmental stress (Env) and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) increase.
Figure A1. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP, environmental stress (Env) and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) increase.
Sustainability 16 05326 g0a1

Appendix A.2. Group 2 (Figure A2)

GDP increases (GDP2 > GDP0), environmental stress increases (Env2 > Env0), and environmental stress productivity decreases (Env2/GDP2 < Env0/GDP0).
Social welfare can have four different options:
1.
Soc21 > Soc0 and Soc21 > Env2 and Soc21/GDP2 > Env2/GDP1 and Soc21/GDP2 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE2S21) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), but the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP2 > GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
2.
Soc22 > Soc0 and Soc22 > Env2 and Soc22/GDP2 > Env2/GDP2, and Soc22/GDP2 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE2S22) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), but the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP2 > GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
3.
Soc23 < Soc0 and Soc23 < Env2 and Soc23/GDP2 < Env2/GDP2, and Soc23/GDP2 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE2S23) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP2 > GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
4.
Soc24 < Soc0 and Soc24 < Env2 and Soc24/GDP2 < Env2/GDP2, and Soc24/GDP2 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE2S24) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax) even though the actual GDP growth is inside the negative SuWi (GDPmax < GDP2 < GDPmin). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
Figure A2. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP and environmental stress (Env) increase, and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) decreases.
Figure A2. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP and environmental stress (Env) increase, and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) decreases.
Sustainability 16 05326 g0a2

Appendix A.3. Group 3 (Figure A3)

GDP increases (GDP3 > GDP0), environmental stress decreases (E3 < E0), and environmental stress productivity decreases (Env3/GDP3 < Env0/GDP0).
Social welfare can have four different options:
1.
Soc31 > Soc0 and Soc31 > Env3 and Soc31/GDP3 > Env3/GDP3 and Soc31/GDP3 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE3S31) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is inside SuWi (GDPmin < GDP3 < GDPmax). This case fulfils the sustainability criteria.
2.
Soc32 > Soc0 and Soc32 > Env3 and Soc32/GDP3 > Env3/GDP3, and Soc32/GDP3 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE3S32) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is inside SuWi (GDPmin < GDP3 < GDPmax). This case fulfils the sustainability criteria.
3.
Soc33 < Soc0 and Soc33 > Env3 and Soc33/GDP3 > Env3/GDP3, and Soc33/GDP3 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE3S33) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), but the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP3 < GDP3min). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
4.
Soc34 < Soc0 and Soc34 < Env3 and Soc34/GDP3 < Env3/GDP3, and Soc34/GDP3 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE3S24) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside the negative SuWi (GDP3 < GDPmax < GDPmin). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
Figure A3. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP increases and environmental stress (Env) and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) decrease.
Figure A3. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP increases and environmental stress (Env) and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) decrease.
Sustainability 16 05326 g0a3

Appendix A.4. Group 4 (Figure A4)

GDP decreases (GDP4 < GDP0), environmental stress increases (E4 > E0), and environmental stress productivity increases (Env4/GDP4 > Env0/GDP0).
Social welfare can have four different options:
1.
Soc41 > Soc0 and Soc41 > Env4 and Soc41/GDP4 > Env4/GDP4 and Soc41/GDP4 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE4S41) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), but the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDPmin < GDP4 > GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
2.
Soc42 > Soc0 and Soc42 < Env4 and Soc42/GDP4 < Env4/GDP4, and Soc42/GDP4 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE4S42) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDPmin < GDP4 > GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
3.
Soc43 < Soc0 and Soc43 < Env4 and Soc43/GDP4 < Env4/GDP4, and Soc43/GDP4 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE4S43) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax) even though the actual GDP growth is inside the negative SuWi (GDP4 > GDPmax < GDPmin). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
4.
Soc44 < Soc0 and Soc44 < Env4 and Soc44/GDP4 < Env4/GDP4, and Soc44/GDP4 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE4S44) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside the negative SuWi (GDP4 < GDPmax < GDPmin). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
Figure A4. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP decreases and environmental stress (Env), and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) increase.
Figure A4. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP decreases and environmental stress (Env), and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) increase.
Sustainability 16 05326 g0a4

Appendix A.5. Group 5 (Figure A5)

GDP decreases (GDP5 < GDP0), environmental stress decreases (E5 < E0), and environmental stress productivity increases (Env5/GDP5 > Env0/GDP0).
Social welfare can have four different options:
1.
Soc51 > Soc0 and Soc51 > Env5 and Soc51/GDP5 > Env5/GDP5 and Soc51/GDP5 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE5S51) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is inside SuWi (GDPmin < GDP5 < GDPmax). This case fulfils the sustainability criteria.
2.
Soc52 < Soc0 and Soc52 > Env5 and Soc52/GDP5 > Env5/GDP5, and Soc52/GDP5 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE5S52) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), but the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP5 < GDPmin < GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
3.
Soc53 < Soc0 and Soc53 < Env5 and Soc53/GDP5 < Env5/GDP5, and Soc53/GDP5 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE5S53) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside the negative SuWi (GDP5 < GDPmax < GDPmin). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
4.
Soc54 < Soc0 and Soc54 < Env5 and Soc54/GDP5 < Env5/GDP5, and Soc54/GDP5 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, the Sustainability Window (SuWiE5S54) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside the negative SuWi (GDP5 < GDPmax < GDPmin). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
Figure A5. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP and environmental stress (Env) decrease, and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) increases.
Figure A5. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP and environmental stress (Env) decrease, and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) increases.
Sustainability 16 05326 g0a5

Appendix A.6. Group 6 (Figure A6)

GDP decreases (GDP6 < GDP0), environmental stress decreases (Env6 < Env0), and environmental stress productivity decreases (Env6/GDP6 < Env0/GDP0).
Social welfare can have four different options:
1.
Soc61 > Soc0 and Soc61 > Env6 and Soc61/GDP6 > Env6/GDP6 and Soc61/GDP6 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, Sustainability Window (SuWiE6S61) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is inside SuWi (GDPmin < GDP6 < GDPmax). This case fulfils the sustainability criteria.
2.
Soc62 < Soc0 and Soc62 > Env6 and Soc62/GDP6 > Env6/GDP6, and Soc62/GDP6 > Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, Sustainability Window (SuWiE6S62) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), but the actual GDP growth is outside SuWi (GDP6 < GDPmin < GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
3.
Soc63 < Soc0 and Soc63 > Env6 and Soc63/GDP6 > Env6/GDP6, and Soc63/GDP6 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, Sustainability Window (SuWiE6S63) is positive (GDPmin < GDPmax), but the actual GDP growth is outside the SuWi (GDP6 < GDPmin < GDPmax). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
4.
Soc64 < Soc0 and Soc64 < Env6 and Soc64/GDP6 < Env6/GDP6, and Soc64/GDP6 < Soc0/GDP0
  • In this case, Sustainability Window (SuWiE6S64) is negative (GDPmin > GDPmax), and the actual GDP growth is outside the negative SuWi (GDP6 < GDPmax < GDPmin). This case does not fulfil the sustainability criteria.
Figure A6. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP, environmental stress (Env), and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) decrease.
Figure A6. Sustainability Window in all possible cases where GDP, environmental stress (Env), and environmental stress productivity (Env/GDP) decrease.
Sustainability 16 05326 g0a6

References

  1. Meadows, D.H.; Randers, J.; Meadows, D.L. The Limits to Growth: The 30-Year Update; Green Publishing Co.: Chelsea, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  2. Kaivo-oja, J.; Vehmas, J.; Luukkanen, J. A note: De-growth debate and new scientific analysis of economic growth. J. Environ. Prot. 2014, 5, 1477–1481. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. O’Mahony, T. Toward sustainable wellbeing: Advances in contemporary concepts. Front. Sustain. 2022, 3, 807984. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Krausmann, F.; Gingrich, S.; Eisenmenger, N.; Erb, K.H.; Haberl, H.; Fischer-Kowalski, M. Growth in global materials use, GDP and population during the 20th century. Ecol. Econ. 2009, 68, 2696–2705. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. IPCC. Global Warming of 1.5 °C. An IPCC Special Report on the Impacts of Global Warming of 1.5 °C above Pre-Industrial Levels and Related Global Greenhouse Gas Emission Pathways, in the Context of Strengthening the Global Response to the Threat of Climate Change, Sustainable Development, and Efforts to Eradicate Poverty; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  6. IPBES. Global Assessment Report on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services of the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services; IPBES Secretariat: Bonn, Germany, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  7. Piketty, T. Capital in the Twenty-First Century; The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press: Cambridge, UK; London, UK, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  8. Piketty, T. About Capital in the 21st Century. Am. Econ. Rev. 2014, 105, 48–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. IPSP. Rethinking Society for the 21st Century: Report of the International Panel on Social Progress; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Leach, M.; Reyers, B.; Bai, X.; Brondizio, E.S.; Cook, C.; Díaz, S.; Espindola, G.; Scobie, M.; Stafford-Smith, M.; Subramanian, S.M. Equity and sustainability in the Anthropocene: A social–ecological systems perspective on their intertwined futures. Glob. Sustain. 2018, 1, E13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Escobar, A. Degrowth, postdevelopment, and transitions: A preliminary conversation. Sustain. Sci. 2015, 10, 451–462. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Grubb, M.; Okereke, C.; Arima, J.; Bosetti, V.; Chen, Y.; Edmonds, J.; Gupta, S.; Köberle, A.; Kverndokk, S.; Malik, A.; et al. Introduction and Framing. In Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2022; pp. 151–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Ekins, P. Economic Growth and Environmental Sustainability: The Prospects for Green Growth; Routledge: London, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  14. Collste, D.; Cornell, S.; Randers, J.; Rockström, J.; Stoknes, P. Human well-being in the Anthropocene: Limits to growth. Glob. Sustain. 2021, 4, E30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Isham, A.; Mair, S.; Jackson, T. Wellbeing and productivity in advanced economies: Re-examining the link. Ecol. Econ. 2021, 184, 106989. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Atkinson, G.; Dubourg, R.; Hamilton, K.; Munasinghe, M.; Pearce, D.; Young, C. Measuring Sustainable Development: Macroeconomics and the Environment; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  17. Boskin, M.J. Economic measurement: Progress and challenges. Am. Econ. Rev. 2000, 90, 247–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Dasgupta, P.; Mäler, K.-C. Net national product, wealth and social well-being. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2000, 5, 69–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Kaivo-oja, J.; Luukkanen, J.; Malaska, P. Sustainability evaluation frameworks and alternative analytical scenarios of national economies. Popul. Environment. A J. Interdiscip. Stud. 2001, 23, 193–215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Brock, W.A.; Taylor, M.S.; Aghion, P.; Durlauf, S.N. Chapter 28—Economic Growth and the Environment: A Review of Theory and Empirics. In Handbook of Economic Growth; Aghion, P., Durlauf, S.N., Eds.; Elsevier: London, UK, 2005; Volume 1, Part B; pp. 1749–1821. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Jorgenson, D.W.; Schreyer, P. Measuring individual economic well-being and social welfare within the framework of the system of national accounts. Rev. Income Wealth 2017, 63, S460–S477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Hueting, R. New Scarcity and Economic Growth; North-Holland: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1980. [Google Scholar]
  23. Desai, M. The measurement problem in economics. Scott. J. Political Econ. 1994, 41, 34–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Hoffrén, J. Measuring the Eco-Efficiency of Welfare Generation in a National Economy. The Case of Finland; Statistics Finland, Research Reports 233: Helsinki, Finland, 2001; ISBN 951-727-961-2. [Google Scholar]
  25. Fabozzi, F.J.; Focardi, S.; Ponta, L.; Rivoire, M.; Mazza, D. The economic theory of qualitative green growth. Struct. Chang. Econ. Dyn. 2022, 61, 242–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Max-Neef, M. Economic growth and quality of life: A threshold hypothesis. Ecol. Econ. 1995, 15, 115–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Arrow, K.; Bolin, B.; Costanza, R.; Dasgupta, P.; Folkee, C.; Holling, C.S.; Jansson, B.-O.; Levin, S.; Mäler, K.-G.; Perring, C.; et al. Economic growth, carrying capacity, and the environment. Ecol. Econ. 1995, 15, 91–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. van den Bergh, J. The GDP paradox. J. Econ. Psychol. 2010, 30, 117–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. WCED. Our Common Future. World Commission on Environment and Development; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 1987. [Google Scholar]
  30. Jamieson, D. Sustainability and beyond. Ecol. Econ. 1998, 24, 183–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Schubert, A.; Láng, I. The Literature Aftermath of the Brundtland Report ‘Our Common Future’. A Scientometric Study Based On Citations in Science and Social Science Journals. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2005, 7, 1–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Olawumi, T.; Chan, D.W.M. A scientometric review of global research on sustainability and sustainable development. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 183, 231–250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. De Toledo, R.F.; Miranda Junior, H.L.; Farias Filho, J.R.; Gomes Costa, H. A scientometric review of global research on sustainability and project management dataset. Data Brief 2019, 25, 104312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  34. Hajan, M.; Kashani, S.J. Evolution of the concept of sustainability. From Brundtland Report to sustainable development goals. In Sustainable Resource Management, Modern Approaches and Contexts; Hussain, C.M., Velasco-Muñoz, J.F., Eds.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2021; pp. 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Holden, E.; Linnerud, K.; Banister, D. Sustainable development: Our Common Future revisited. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2014, 26, 130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Gibbes, C.; Hopkins, A.L.; Díaz, A.I.; Jimenez-Osornio, J. Defining and measuring sustainability: A systematic review of studies in rural Latin America and the Caribbean. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2018, 22, 447–468. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Phillips, J. Determining the overall indicated levels, nature, dynamics and influences upon UK sustainability 2000–2018. Sci. Total Environ. 2024, 907, 168021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Purvis, B.; Mao, Y.; Robinson, D. Three pillars of sustainability: In search of conceptual origins. Sustain. Sci. 2019, 14, 681–695. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Du Pisani, J.A. Sustainable development—Historical roots of the concept. Environ. Sci. 2006, 3, 83–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Meadows, D.H.; Meadows, D.L.; Randers, J.; Behrens, W.W., III. The Limits to Growth; A Report for the Club of Rome’s Project on the Predicament of Mankind; Universe Books: New York, NY, USA, 1972. [Google Scholar]
  41. Georgescu-Roegen, N. The entropy law and the economic process in retrospect. East. Econ. J. 1986, 12, 3–25. [Google Scholar]
  42. Daly, H.E. Toward some operational principles of sustainable development. Ecol. Econ. 1990, 2, 1–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Cleveland, C.J.; Ruth, M. When, where, and by how much do biophysical limits constrain the economic process? A survey of Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen´s contribution to ecological economics? Ecol. Econ. 1997, 22, 203–223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Kaivo-oja, J. Alternative scenarios of social development: Is analytical sustainability policy analysis possible? How? Sustain. Dev. 1999, 7, 140–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Kaivo-oja, J. Social and ecological destruction in the first class: A plausible social development scenario. Sustain. Dev. 2002, 10, 63–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Dasgupta, P. The Idea of Sustainable Development. Sustain. Sci. 2007, 2, 5–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Bander, J.A. Viewpoint: Sustainability: Malthus revisited. Can. J. Econ./Rev. Can. D’économique 2007, 40, 1–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Luukkanen, J.; Kaivo-oja, J.; Vehmas, J. Comparative analysis of ASEAN countries using Sustainability Window and Doughnut Economy models. OIDA Int. J. Sustain. Dev. 2022, 15, 39–56. [Google Scholar]
  49. Solow, R.M. Is the end of the world at hand? Challenge 1973, 16, 39–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Stiglitz, J.E. Growth with exhaustible natural resources: Efficient and optimal growth paths. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1974, 41, 123–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Barbier, E.B.; Markandya, A. The conditions for achieving environmentally sustainable development. Eur. Econ. Rev. 1990, 34, 659–669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Peretto, P.F. Thought scarcity to prosperity: Toward a theory of sustainable growth. J. Monet. Econ. 2021, 117, 243–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Victor, P.A. Indicators of sustainable development. Some lessons from capital theory. Ecol. Econ. 1991, 4, 191–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Costanza, R.; Daly, H.E. Natural capital and sustainable development. Conserv. Biol. 1992, 6, 37–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Daly, H.E. Introduction to essays toward a steady-state economy. In Valuing the Earth: Economics, Ecology, Ethics; Daly, H.E., Townsend, K.E., Eds.; The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1993; pp. 267–274. [Google Scholar]
  56. Daly, H.E. Beyond Growth; Beacon Press: Boston, MA, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  57. Daly, H.E. Georgescu-Roegen versus Solow/Stiglitz. Ecol. Econ. 1997, 22, 261–266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Trainer, T. De-growth: Some suggestions from the simpler way perspective. Ecol. Econ. 2020, 167, 106436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Martinez-Alier, J. Socially sustainable economic de-growth. Dev. Chang. 2009, 40, 1099–1119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Martinez-Alier, J.; Pascual, U.; Vivien, F.-D.; Zaccai, E. Sustainable de-growth: Mapping the context, criticism and future prospects of an emergent paradigm. Ecol. Econ. 2010, 69, 1741–1747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Kaivo-oja, J.; Panula-Ontto, J.; Vehmas, J.; Luukkanen, J. Relationships of the dimensions of sustainability as measured by the sustainable society index framework. Int. J. Sustain. Dev. World Ecol. 2014, 21, 39–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Latouche, S. Degrowth economics. Why Less Should Be So Much More. Le Monde Dipl. 2004. Available online: https://mondediplo.com/2004/11/14latouche (accessed on 20 December 2023).
  63. Fournier, V. Escaping from the economy: The politics of degrowth. Int. J. Sociol. Soc. Policy 2008, 28, 528–545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Georgescu- Roegen, N. Energy and economic myth. South. Econ. J. 1975, 41, 347–381. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Grossman, G.M.; Krueger, A.B. Environmental Impacts of a North American Free Trade Agreement; Working Paper 3914; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar]
  66. Stern, D.I. The rise and fall of the Environmental Kuznets curve. World Dev. 2004, 32, 1419–1439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Commoner, B. A bulletin dialogue on ‘the closing circle’: Response. Bull. At. Sci. 1972, 28, 42–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Ehrlich, P.R.; Holdren, J.P. A bulletin dialogue on the ‘closing circle’: Critique one-dimensional ecology. Bull. At. Sci. 1972, 28, 16–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Chertow, M.R. The IPAT Equation and Its Variants. Changing Views of Technology and Environmental Impact. J. Ind. Ecol. 2001, 4, 13–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Kaya, Y. Impact of Carbon Dioxide Emission Control on GNP Growth: Interpretation of Proposed Scenarios; Paper presented to the IPCC Energy and Industry Subgroup, Response Strategies Working Group (mimeo): Paris, France, 1990. [Google Scholar]
  71. Wang, H.; Ang, B.W.; Su, B. Assessing drivers of economy-wide energy use and emissions: IDA versus SDA. Energy Policy 2017, 107, 585–599. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Luukkanen, J.; Kaivo-oja, J.; Vähäkari, N.; O’Mahony, T.; Korkeakoski, M.; Panula-Ontto, J.; Phonhalath, K.; Nanthavong, K.; Reincke, K.; Vehmas, J.; et al. Green economic development in Lao PDR: A Sustainability Window analysis of Green Growth Productivity and the Efficiency Gap. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 211, 818–829. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Waas, T.; Hugé, J.; Block, T.; Wright, T.; Benitez-Capistros, F.; Verbruggen, A. Sustainability Assessment and Indicators: Tools in a Decision-Making Strategy for Sustainable Development. Sustainability 2014, 6, 5512–5534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Lélé, S. Sustainable development: A critical review. World Dev. 1991, 19, 607–621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Bolis, I.; Morioka, S.N.; Sznelwar, L.I. When sustainable development risks losing its meaning. Delimiting the concept with a comprehensive literature review and a conceptual model. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 83, 7–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Bolis, I.; Morioka, S.N.; Sznelwar, L.I. Are we making decisions in a sustainable way? A comprehensive literature review about rationalities for sustainable development. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 145, 310–322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Gusmão Caiado, R.G.; Leal Filho, W.; Ávila, L.V. A literature-based review on potentials and constraints in the implementation of the sustainable development goals. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 198, 1276–1288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Mensah, J. Sustainable development: Meaning, history, principles, pillars, and implications for human action: Literature review. Cogent Soc. Sci. 2019, 5, 1653531. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Zelli, F.; van Asselt, H. The Institutional Fragmentation of Global Environmental Governance: Causes, Consequences, and Responses—Introduction. Glob. Environ. Politics 2013, 13, 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Heidingsfelder, J.; Beckmann, M. A governance puzzle to be solved? A systematic literature review of fragmented sustainability governance. Manag. Rev. Q. 2020, 70, 355–390. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Enders, J.C.; Remig, R. (Eds.) Theories of Sustainable Development; Routledge: London, UK, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  82. Shi, L.; Han, L.; Yang, F.; Gao, L. The Evolution of Sustainable Development Theory: Types, Goals, and Research Prospects. Sustainability 2019, 11, 7158. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Caldarola, B.; Mazzilli, D.; Napolitano, L.; Patelli, A.; Sbardella, A. Economic complexity and the sustainability transition: A review of data, methods, and literature. arXiv 2023, arXiv:2308.07172v1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Montiel-Hernández, M.; Pérez-Hernández, C.; Salazar-Hernández, B. The Intrinsic Links of Economic Complexity with Sustainability Dimensions: A Systematic Review and Agenda for Future Research. Sustainability 2024, 16, 391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Safi, A.; Wei, X.; Sansaloni, E.M.; Umar, M. Breaking down the complexity of sustainable development: A focus on resources, economic complexity, and innovation. Resour. Policy 2023, 83, 103746. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Hidalgo, C.A. The policy implications of economic complexity. Res. Policy 2023, 52, 104863. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Nocenzi, M.; Sannella, A. (Eds.) Perspectives for a New Social Theory of Sustainability; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Passos Neto, G.; Hazin Alencar, L.; Valdes-Vasquez, R. Multiple-Criteria Methods for Assessing Social Sustainability in the Built Environment: A Systematic Review. Sustainability 2023, 15, 16231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Luukkanen, J.; Kaivo-oja, J.; Vehmas, J.; Panula-Ontto, J.; Häyhä, L. Dynamic sustainability. Sustainability window analysis of Chinese poverty-environment nexus development. Sustainability 2015, 7, 14488–14500. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Hueting, R. The Brundtland Report: A matter of conflicting goals. Ecol. Econ. 1990, 2, 109–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Hickel, J. The contradiction of the Sustainable Development Goals: Growth versus ecology on a finite planet. Sustain. Dev. 2019, 27, 873–884. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Stiglitz, J.E.; Sen, A.; Fitoussi, J.P. Report by the Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress; Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress: Paris, France, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  93. Fleurbaey, M. Beyond GDP: The quest for a measure of social welfare. J. Econ. Lit. 2009, 47, 1029–1075. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Sathaye, J.; Najam, A.; Cocklin, C.; Heller, T.; Lecocq, F.; Llanes-Regueiro, J.; Pan, J.; Petschel-Held, G.; Rayner, S.; Robinson, J.; et al. Sustainable Development and Mitigation. In Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change; Metz, B., Davidson, O.R., Bosch, P.R., Dave, R., Meyer, L.A., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  95. Neumayer, E. Weak versus Strong Sustainability: Exploring the Limits of Two Opposing Paradigms; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2010. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Sabin, P. The Bet: Paul Ehrlich, Julian Simon: Our Gamble over Earth’s Future; Yale University Press: London, UK, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  97. Luukkanen, J.; Vehmas, J.; Kaivo-oja, J. Quantification of doughnut economy with the sustainability window method: Analysis of development in Thailand. Sustainability 2021, 13, 847. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Saunders, A.; Luukkanen, J. Sustainable development in Cuba assessed with sustainability window and doughnut economy approaches. Int. J. Sustain. Dev. World Ecol. 2022, 29, 176–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  99. SSI Index. Data Set Edition 2024, The Background. Available online: https://ssi.wi.th-koeln.de/documents/edition-2024/2000-2020-indicator-calculations.pdf (accessed on 15 March 2024).
  100. Vehmas, J.; Kaivo-oja, J.; Luukkanen, J. Sustainability cycles in China, India, and the world? East. Eur. Bus. Econ. J. 2016, 2, 139–164. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. (Left): a typical representation of sustainability as three intersecting circles, (right): alternative depictions: below as literal “pillars” and above as concentric circles, from Purvis et al. [38].
Figure 1. (Left): a typical representation of sustainability as three intersecting circles, (right): alternative depictions: below as literal “pillars” and above as concentric circles, from Purvis et al. [38].
Sustainability 16 05326 g001
Figure 2. Determining the maximum economic output related to the production of environmental stress.
Figure 2. Determining the maximum economic output related to the production of environmental stress.
Sustainability 16 05326 g002
Figure 3. Determining the minimum economic output in order to not decrease social welfare.
Figure 3. Determining the minimum economic output in order to not decrease social welfare.
Sustainability 16 05326 g003
Figure 4. Determining the Sustainability Window (SuWi) with the minimum (GDPmin) and maximum (GDPmax) economic output.
Figure 4. Determining the Sustainability Window (SuWi) with the minimum (GDPmin) and maximum (GDPmax) economic output.
Sustainability 16 05326 g004
Figure 5. Determining maximum economic output when environmental stress is decreasing (Env1 < Env0) and environmental stress productivity is decreasing (Env1/GDP1 < Env0/GDP0).
Figure 5. Determining maximum economic output when environmental stress is decreasing (Env1 < Env0) and environmental stress productivity is decreasing (Env1/GDP1 < Env0/GDP0).
Sustainability 16 05326 g005
Figure 6. Determining minimum economic output when social welfare is increasing (Soc1 > Soc0) and social welfare productivity is decreasing (Soc1/GDP1 < Soc0/GDP0).
Figure 6. Determining minimum economic output when social welfare is increasing (Soc1 > Soc0) and social welfare productivity is decreasing (Soc1/GDP1 < Soc0/GDP0).
Sustainability 16 05326 g006
Figure 7. Determining the Sustainability Window in a case where the actual GDP output is within the Sustainability Window (GDPmin < GDP1 < GDPmax).
Figure 7. Determining the Sustainability Window in a case where the actual GDP output is within the Sustainability Window (GDPmin < GDP1 < GDPmax).
Sustainability 16 05326 g007
Figure 8. Determining maximum economic output when the economy is decreasing (GDP1 < GDP0), environmental stress is decreasing (Env1 < Env0), and environmental stress productivity is decreasing (Env1/GDP1 < Env0/GDP0).
Figure 8. Determining maximum economic output when the economy is decreasing (GDP1 < GDP0), environmental stress is decreasing (Env1 < Env0), and environmental stress productivity is decreasing (Env1/GDP1 < Env0/GDP0).
Sustainability 16 05326 g008
Figure 9. Determining minimum economic output when the economy is decreasing (GDP1 < GDP0), social welfare is increasing (Soc1 > Soc0), and social welfare productivity is increasing (Soc1/GDP1 > Soc0/GDP0).
Figure 9. Determining minimum economic output when the economy is decreasing (GDP1 < GDP0), social welfare is increasing (Soc1 > Soc0), and social welfare productivity is increasing (Soc1/GDP1 > Soc0/GDP0).
Sustainability 16 05326 g009
Figure 10. Determining the Sustainability Window in a case where the actual decreasing GDP output (degrowth) is within the Sustainability Window (GDPmin < GDP1 < GDPmax).
Figure 10. Determining the Sustainability Window in a case where the actual decreasing GDP output (degrowth) is within the Sustainability Window (GDPmin < GDP1 < GDPmax).
Sustainability 16 05326 g010
Figure 11. (ad). The four sustainable paths of the economy, where (a,b) are paths of economic growth and (c,d) paths of economic degrowth. In all figures point A is the starting point. Points E1, E2, E3, E4 are the environmental indicator points in the analysis year. Points S1, S2, S3, S4 are the social indicator points in the analysis year.
Figure 11. (ad). The four sustainable paths of the economy, where (a,b) are paths of economic growth and (c,d) paths of economic degrowth. In all figures point A is the starting point. Points E1, E2, E3, E4 are the environmental indicator points in the analysis year. Points S1, S2, S3, S4 are the social indicator points in the analysis year.
Sustainability 16 05326 g011
Figure 12. Sustainability Window in the case of an environmental stress target Envtarget.
Figure 12. Sustainability Window in the case of an environmental stress target Envtarget.
Sustainability 16 05326 g012
Figure 13. Sustainability Window in the case where social welfare productivity Soc1/GDP1 increases and enables the reduction of the minimum economic output (degrowth) when the environmental stress target is determined.
Figure 13. Sustainability Window in the case where social welfare productivity Soc1/GDP1 increases and enables the reduction of the minimum economic output (degrowth) when the environmental stress target is determined.
Sustainability 16 05326 g013
Figure 14. Sustainability Window in the case where the social welfare target is determined.
Figure 14. Sustainability Window in the case where the social welfare target is determined.
Sustainability 16 05326 g014
Figure 15. Determining minimum economic output for different social welfare productivity levels (Soc/GDP) in the case where the level of social welfare is defined at Soctarget.
Figure 15. Determining minimum economic output for different social welfare productivity levels (Soc/GDP) in the case where the level of social welfare is defined at Soctarget.
Sustainability 16 05326 g015
Figure 16. The economic degrowth case with the both environmental and social targets.
Figure 16. The economic degrowth case with the both environmental and social targets.
Sustainability 16 05326 g016
Figure 17. Illustration of an efficiency gap for sustainability planning of the economy.
Figure 17. Illustration of an efficiency gap for sustainability planning of the economy.
Sustainability 16 05326 g017
Table 1. All combinations of GDP, environmental stress, social welfare, and related productivities with Sustainable Window analysis. The sustainable options are marked with green colour. The arrows indicate the direction of change (increase or decrease).
Table 1. All combinations of GDP, environmental stress, social welfare, and related productivities with Sustainable Window analysis. The sustainable options are marked with green colour. The arrows indicate the direction of change (increase or decrease).
Economic Output (GDP)Environ-mental Stress (Env)Environmental Stress Productivity (Env/GDP)Social Welfare (Soc)Social Welfare Productivity (Soc/GDP)No. of CombinationNo. of Logically Possible CombinationNo. of SuWi Scenario PathFigure Number in Appendix ASuWi Identifi-cation CodeSustainability WindowDGDP Inside SuWiDSoc−DEnvComments
111Figure A1E1S11PositiveNo+Unsustainable growth
2Figure A1E1S12NegativeNoUnsustainable growth
223Figure A1E1S13NegativeNoUnsustainable growth
3 Impossible
434Figure A1E1S14NegativeYesUnsustainable growth
545Figure A2E2S21PositiveNo+Unsustainable growth
656Figure A2E2S22PositiveNo+Unsustainable growth
7Figure A2E2S23NegativeNoUnsustainable growth
7 Impossible
868Figure A2E2S24NegativeYesUnsustainable growth
9 Impossible
10
11
12
1379Figure A3E3S31PositiveYes+Sustainable growth
14810Figure A3E3S32PositiveYes+Sustainable growth
15 Impossible
16911Figure A3E3S33PositiveNo+Unsustainable growth
12Figure A3E3S34NegativeNoUnsustainable growth
171013Figure A4E4S41PositiveNo+Unsustainable degrowth
14Figure A4E4S42NegativeNoUnsustainable degrowth
18 Impossible
191115Figure A4E4S43NegativeYesUnsustainable degrowth
201216Figure A4E4S44NegativeYesUnsustainable degrowth
21 Impossible
22
23
24
251317Figure A5E5S51PositiveYes+Sustainable degrowth
26 Impossible
271418Figure A5E5S52PositiveNo+Unsustainable degrowth
19Figure A5E5S53NegativeNoUnsustainable degrowth
281520Figure A5E5S54NegativeNoUnsustainable degrowth
291621Figure A6E6S61PositiveYes+Sustainable degrowth
30 Impossible
311722Figure A6E6S62PositiveNo+Unsustainable degrowth
321823Figure A6E6S63PositiveNo+Unsustainable degrowth
24Figure A6E6S64NegativeNoUnsustainable degrowth
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Luukkanen, J.; Vehmas, J.; Kaivo-oja, J.; O’Mahony, T. Towards a General Theory of Sustainable Development: Using a Sustainability Window Approach to Explore All Possible Scenario Paths of Economic Growth and Degrowth. Sustainability 2024, 16, 5326. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16135326

AMA Style

Luukkanen J, Vehmas J, Kaivo-oja J, O’Mahony T. Towards a General Theory of Sustainable Development: Using a Sustainability Window Approach to Explore All Possible Scenario Paths of Economic Growth and Degrowth. Sustainability. 2024; 16(13):5326. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16135326

Chicago/Turabian Style

Luukkanen, Jyrki, Jarmo Vehmas, Jari Kaivo-oja, and Tadhg O’Mahony. 2024. "Towards a General Theory of Sustainable Development: Using a Sustainability Window Approach to Explore All Possible Scenario Paths of Economic Growth and Degrowth" Sustainability 16, no. 13: 5326. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16135326

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop