1. Introduction
Existing studies highlight that a healthy ecological environment is essential for sustainable socio-economic development as well as the enhancement in residents’ living standards [
1,
2,
3]. Maintaining the balance of ecosystems is contingent upon preserving unpolluted water resources [
4]. However, water pollution has emerged as a significant ecological challenge, placing immense strain on aquatic ecosystems globally [
5]. The issues are particularly acute in developing countries, where water quality and drinking water safety are pressing concerns [
6]. As the largest developing nation, China faces severe water pollution challenges, largely driven by its industrial sector’s high levels of pollution and energy consumption [
7]. This has resulted in issues such as eutrophication, contamination by heavy metals, and the presence of organic compounds [
8,
9], all of which have serious implications for food safety and the health of Chinese residents [
9].
Since 1979, the Chinese government has implemented a series of water pollution control policies aimed at improving water quality in both urban and rural areas [
10,
11]. These policies include the “Two Control Zones” policy [
12,
13], the River Chief System [
14], the National Specially Monitored Firms (NSMF) program [
15], and the Water Ecological Civilization City Pilot initiative [
6], among others. These efforts have led to significant advancements in controlling water pollution. Moreover, research indicates that China’s regulatory policies on water pollution not only facilitate reductions in corporate emissions, but also influence green total factor productivity (GTFP) and technological progress within firms. For instance, Huang et al. [
16] demonstrated that environmental taxes on water pollutant emissions effectively stimulate green innovation in firms. Yang et al. [
6] found that the Water Ecological Civilization City Pilot Policy fosters green technological innovation among regional firms.
Among the various environmental regulations introduced by the Chinese government, the NSMF program stands out as a key command-and-control measure. Unlike phased approaches to pollution control, the NSMF program has been continuously implemented since 2007. Each year, the Ministry of Ecology and Environment (MOE) compiles a list of industrial firms ranked by their pollutant emissions. The NSMF program includes firms whose emissions collectively represent 65% of the total industrial emissions, and these firms are subject to real-time monitoring of their emissions [
15,
17]. The NSMF program requires monitored firms to reduce their pollutant emissions, compelling them to invest more resources in cleaner production and pollution control. This, in turn, leads to an optimized resource allocation and upgraded input structures, potentially influencing the total factor productivity of these firms.
Investigating the effect of the NSMF program on the GTFP of Chinese industrial firms is of paramount importance. China faces severe pollution challenges [
18] and is committed to achieving sustainable development. Therefore, evaluating whether the NSMF program, as a key environmental regulation measure, has effectively promoted green development within firms is essential. Additionally, clarifying the fundamental mechanisms through which the NSMF program influences firms’ GTFP is valuable for elucidating how command-and-control environmental measures can advance corporate sustainability. Insights from this study could also be beneficial for other countries dealing with significant environmental and economic challenges.
Current research on the NSMF program primarily addresses effects on monitored firms’ pollutant emissions [
15,
19], social responsibility [
20], innovation capacity [
21], and investor confidence [
22]. However, there is a notable gap in the literature regarding the effect of the NSMF program on the GTFP of monitored firms. Huang et al. [
23] employed the Stochastic Frontier Analysis method to evaluate the green technology efficiency of National Specially Monitoring (NSM) thermal power plants, but did not investigate the policy’s effect on green technology efficiency more broadly. Thus, the effect of the NSMF program on firms’ GTFP, which reflects the program’s ability to foster sustainable development, warrants further exploration.
This study addresses this gap by calculating the Malmquist–Luenberger (ML) index and its decomposition indices using firm-level data from 2004 to 2013 to assess GTFP and technological progress [
24,
25,
26]. Subsequently, a time-varying difference-in-differences (DID) model is utilized to assess the effect of the NSMF program on the GTFP of water-polluting firms. This study focuses on the following two key questions: (1) Does the NSMF program enhance the GTFP of water-polluting firms? (2) If so, through which mechanisms does the NSMF program facilitate these effect improvements?
This study makes two significant contributions. First, it is the first to investigate the effect of the NSMF program on water-polluting firms’ GTFP, thereby expanding the literature on the effects of command-and-control environmental regulations on firms’ sustainability in developing economies. The empirical insights provided could inform the evolution of such regulations in developing countries and offer practical guidance for achieving sustainable development.
Second, this study investigates the mechanisms through which the NSMF program affects water-polluting firms’ GTFP. It finds that the policy promotes GTFP growth primarily by alleviating firms’ financing constraints, enhancing human capital, and improving pollution treatment technologies. Understanding these mechanisms offers deeper insights into firms’ responses and enables a more accurate assessment of the policy’s effects.
The structure of this study is organized as follows:
Section 2 provides the policy background;
Section 3 reviews the relevant literature and formulates the research hypotheses;
Section 4 describes the dataset, model, and variables; and
Section 5 reports the empirical findings.
Section 6 explores the underlying mechanisms, while
Section 7 offers concluding remarks.
2. Policy Background
Environmental regulation in China encompasses command-and-control, market-incentive, and voluntary approaches [
27]. The NSMF program stands out as a pivotal command-and-control environmental regulation [
17]. Initiated by the Chinese Environmental Protection Administration (EPA) (renamed as Ministry of Ecology and Environment after 2008) in 2007 under the “Opinions on Strengthening and Improving Environmental Statistics”, this program aims to collect timely information on pollutant emissions from highly polluting firms, facilitating strengthened law enforcement and supervision, thereby promoting corporate pollution management [
19].
The list of the first batch of NSMF is divided into three categories: water-polluting firms, air-polluting firms, and sewage treatment plants. The initial NSMF list, released in 2007, identified water-polluting firms based on their industrial emissions of chemical oxygen demand and ammonia nitrogen in 2005, prioritizing those whose emissions collectively represent 65% of the total industrial emissions. By 2016, the monitored water-polluting firms had decreased from 3115 in 2007 to 2660, as firms successfully met emission reduction targets and were subsequently removed from the list [
15]. The NSMF program expanded over time to include firms emitting heavy metals (2012), large-scale livestock and poultry operations (2013), and hazardous waste facilities (2015), reflecting China’s evolving ecological priorities. Subsequently, provincial environmental departments took over list publication from the MOE after 2016.
Under the NSMF, firms are mandated to install real-time emission monitoring systems linked to a national network, ensuring the continuous collection of accurate pollutant discharge data [
21]. Monthly supervision and on-site inspections are conducted to verify data integrity and system functionality, with findings reported to local governments to determine pollution taxation standards for monitored firms [
15]. These stringent regulatory measures underscore the heightened environmental oversight imposed on NSMF-listed entities. Exploring the effect of such regulatory intensity on the GTFP of monitored firms warrants detailed investigation.
3. Literature Review and Research Hypotheses
Some scholars, grounded in the neoclassical “cost theory”, argue that the implementation of environmental regulations escalates production costs and diminishes firms’ capacity for technological innovation [
28]. These regulations impose additional environmental management costs, such as the procurement or upgrading of pollution control equipment and the payment of sewage fees, thereby diverting resources from productive activities to environmental management or emission reduction efforts, leading to potential productivity losses [
29]. However, Porter and Linde [
30] challenged this neoclassical perspective through their well-known “Porter Hypothesis”. They contend that moderate environmental regulation can stimulate innovation and enhance productivity, thereby partially or fully offsetting the increased costs and reduced profits caused by such regulations. This, in turn, can lead to an overall increase in firms’ total factor productivity (TFP). As environmental regulation intensity and pollution control costs rise, firms are driven to increase R&D investment and pursue green technological innovations in areas such as resource input, energy consumption, and emission reduction, ultimately lowering pollution control costs [
31]. Compared to paying directly for pollution emissions, technological innovation offers higher expected returns to firms [
32], as it not only reduces pollutant emissions but also improves productivity and product quality, thereby enhancing firms’ competitiveness and increasing output. Consequently, the competitive advantage gained through productivity improvements via R&D and innovation can offset profit reductions caused by higher environmental management costs, ultimately boosting corporate TFP.
Other scholars suggest that the positive effect of environmental regulation on firms’ TFP improvement arises not only from technological advancement but also from optimizing production resource allocation efficiency [
33]. On the one hand, the enactment of environmental regulation policies, such as environmental and energy taxes, promotes the marketization of non-renewable energy prices like for coal and oil, reducing potential price distortions and curbing excessive energy and resource consumption due to low costs. This, in turn, facilitates TFP enhancement through the upgrading of factor structures. On the other hand, increased environmental regulation intensity compels firms to either install end-of-pipe pollution treatment equipment or pursue green technological innovations in production to reduce emissions, thereby increasing the demand for high-skilled talent in research and development [
31]. By enhancing human capital to replace high energy consumption and capital investment and continuously improving factor resource allocation efficiency, firms can ultimately promote TFP growth. The positive effect of environmental regulation on firms’ TFP enhancement has been corroborated by several studies [
34,
35,
36].
When firms face environmental regulation, the cost of pollution control is included in the inputs to the TFP measure, while the reduction in undesirable output is not accounted for. This approach may underestimate a firm’s actual TFP and overestimate the negative effect of environmental regulation on firm productivity. GTFP, which incorporates pollution emissions into the TFP measure, provides a more accurate assessment. Industrial production and pollution emissions are often intertwined, yet the existing literature assessing the effect of environmental regulations on firm productivity typically considers only inputs and economic outputs, neglecting pollution emissions as an undesirable output. This uneven treatment of desired versus undesired outputs may skew the evaluation of production performance and social welfare, potentially resulting in flawed policy recommendations [
37,
38]. Therefore, to accurately assess the productivity effects of environmental regulation, the GTFP indicator should be used instead of the traditional TFP measure.
Numerous studies have explored the effect of environmental regulations on firms’ GTFP. Zhang et al. [
39] and Zhang et al. [
40] found that environmental regulation can significantly increase firms’ GTFP. Li and Chen [
41] and Liu and Cui [
42] concluded that while environmental regulation may negatively impact firms’ GTFP in the short term, in the long term, such regulation can foster a “win-win” situation for both firms’ competitiveness and environmental protection [
41]. Cheng and Kong [
43] further indicated that both command-and-control and market-incentive environmental regulations can enhance firms’ GTFP, and that a combination of policies is more conducive to GTFP growth than a single policy.
Based on this analysis, we propose Hypothesis 1:
H1. The NSMFprogram significantly enhancesthe GTFP of monitored firms.
It is crucial to understand the mechanisms through which the NSMF program affects the GTFP of monitored firms. Prior research indicates that firms can improve their GTFP through external resources, such as government subsidies and bank credits [
21], as well as internal resources, including human capital and pollution treatment technologies [
44,
45,
46]. Therefore, the NSMF program may enhance monitored firms’ GTFP by alleviating financing constraints, improving human capital, and inducing an increased use of pollution treatment technologies.
First, the implementation of the NSMF program may facilitate firms’ access to government subsidies and alleviate financing constraints, thereby contributing to GTFP growth. Following the release of the NSMF list, China’s EPA mandated that local environmental departments prioritize these firms for pollution control measures and allocate dedicated funding programs, thereby enhancing firms’ access to government subsidies and bank credits. The inflow of external funds alleviates financing constraints on firms’ green technological innovation [
47], promotes technological progress, and increases the likelihood of GTFP growth.
Second, the NSMF program may drive GTFP growth by improving firms’ human capital. As noted, NSMF firms receive priority for advanced technology demonstration projects, facilitating talent acquisition and technology exchanges, thereby boosting their human capital. Human capital is a critical determinant of firms’ technological innovation capabilities [
44]. By enhancing human capital to replace high energy consumption and capital investment and continuously improving factor resource allocation efficiency [
31], the NSMF program could serve as a powerful driver for enhancing their GTFP.
Third, the NSMF program, as a classic command-and-control environmental regulatory policy [
17], is designed to strengthen pollution treatment among monitored firms. Effective pollution reduction requires firms to upgrade their pollution treatment technologies, including both end-of-pipe and source control technologies [
46,
48,
49,
50]. End-of-pipe treatment involves converting pollutants into more manageable substances before discharge [
45]. While end-of-pipe technologies typically require fewer inputs and have a lower technological threshold [
51], they are often preferred by firms with limited capital or R&D capabilities [
52]. In contrast, source control technologies aim to reduce pollutant generation at the production stage by minimizing reliance on polluting inputs like energy or raw materials and improving resource efficiency for cleaner production [
53]. Source control methods depart from the traditional “pollute first, treat later” approach by preventing pollution through cleaner production practices [
54], leading to more effective emission reductions [
46]. The adoption of both end-of-pipe and source control technologies promotes cleaner production, potentially enhancing firms’ GTFP.
We propose Hypotheses 2a, 2b, and 2c based on the preceding analysis.
H2a. The NSMF program enhances monitored firms’ GTFP by alleviating their financing constraints.
H2b. The NSMF program enhances monitored firms’ GTFP by improving their human capital.
H2c. The NSMF program enhances monitored firms’ GTFP by inducing an increased use of pollution treatment technologies.
The research framework diagram of this study is illustrated in
Figure 1.
7. Conclusions
This study utilizes the NSMF program as a quasi-experiment and employs a time-varying DID model to assess the policy’s effect on the GTFP of water-polluting firms. Additionally, the analysis investigates the mechanisms through which the policy promotes GTFP growth. The key findings are as follows:
(1) The baseline regression results indicate that the NSMF program significantly enhances the GTFP growth of water-polluting firms, with technological progress being the primary driver of this effect. This finding supports the “Porter Hypothesis”, indicating that moderate environmental regulation can stimulate innovation and enhance productivity, thereby partially or fully offsetting the increased costs caused by such regulations. Furthermore, the results imply that command-and-control environmental regulations, such as the NSMF program, can effectively promote both GTFP growth and technological advancement in developing countries like China. Thus, pollution abatement and high-quality development are not mutually exclusive objectives for regulated firms. These insights are valuable for shaping future command-and-control environmental policies and advancing sustainable development in regulatory frameworks.
(2) The mechanism analysis reveals that the NSMF program enhances GTFP growth among water-polluting firms primarily by alleviating financing constraints, improving human capital, and expediting the adoption of pollution treatment technologies. The EPA directs local governments to prioritize firms listed in the NSMF program for targeted funding aimed at pollution control. This funding alleviates financing constraints, thereby equipping firms with additional resources to either upgrade their production processes or invest in pollution abatement technologies. Additionally, firms included in the NSMF program receive priority for advanced technology demonstration projects, which supports talent acquisition and strengthens human capital. This prioritization also facilitates technological exchanges with universities, research institutes, and high-tech firms, thereby promoting the adoption of more advanced end-of-pipe and source control technologies. This result underscores the importance of accounting for the incentive effects on various GTFP growth mechanisms when designing policy interventions.
(3) This study extends the existing literature by examining the effect of command-and-control environmental regulations on sustainable development within developing economies. By assessing the effects of the NSMF program—an illustrative example of such regulations—on the GTFP of Chinese firms, we provided empirical evidence that enriches the understanding of how these regulations impact sustainable development. The NSMF program can enhance firms’ GTFP while constraining their pollution emissions, making it an important policy tool for achieving a win–win situation in both economic and environmental performance. Our findings offer significant insights for the future design and implementation of similar regulations in developing countries and propose practical strategies for firms and policymakers to foster sustainable development.
The findings of this study have several important policy implications. First, the findings underscore the significant potential of command-and-control environmental regulations, such as the NSMF program, to advance sustainable development by promoting GTFP growth among firms. Governments can implement command-and-control regulations akin to the NSMF program, compelling firms to allocate greater internal resources toward green production and energy conservation. Such regulations contribute to the overarching goal of sustainable development for both firms and society. To further incentivize sustainable development and increase the effectiveness of these regulations, the government should introduce complementary policies, such as establishing exemplary cases and creating reward funds. These initiatives would provide financial incentives to firms that demonstrate excellence in green development. These supplementary measures can further motivate firms to adopt and sustain sustainable practices.
Second, the diverse pathways to achieving GTFP growth highlight the necessity for governments to tailor incentives to various contexts. To more effectively alleviate firms’ financing constraints, the governments could supplement traditional subsidies and bank credits with targeted funds and tax reductions as rewards for firms that successfully reduce pollution, which would incentive firms’ GTFP growth and technological progress. To strengthen firms’ human capital, the government can facilitate talent acquisition and development by creating online platforms for communication between firms and universities and organizing exchange events between firms and academic institutions. For advancing pollution treatment technologies, targeted funding, low-interest loans for acquiring pollution control equipment, and subsidies for clean energy or environmentally friendly materials are recommended.
Third, the NSMF program’s effectiveness is contingent upon its management by municipal ecological and environmental authorities, who currently exercise significant autonomy. There is a risk that local authorities may lower pollution emission standards or reduce constraints to promote local economic development, potentially undermining the program’s effectiveness and leading to delayed emission reductions and GTFP growth. To mitigate this issue, future reforms to the existing environmental regulatory framework could be explored by building on the current system of vertical management for monitoring and supervision and enforcement by sub-provincial environmental agencies. By further integrating these regulatory bodies within central government departments, enforcement capabilities could be significantly strengthened.
This study is subject to several limitations. First, the unavailability of data on firms’ pollution emissions beyond 2013 precludes an assessment of the NSMF program’s effect on GTFP after this period. Future research should address this gap as post-2013 data become available. Second, the focus on heavily polluting industries leaves the effect of the NSMF program on less polluting sectors unexplored, an area that merits further investigation. Finally, while this study concentrated on command-and-control regulations, future research could investigate the effect of market-incentive and voluntary environmental regulations on GTFP.