Abstract
In this paper, we model uncertainty in both the objective function and the constraints for the robust semi-infinite interval equilibrium problem involving data uncertainty. We particularize these conditions for the robust semi-infinite mathematical programming problem with interval-valued functions by extending the results from the literature. We introduce the dual robust version of the above problem, prove the Mond–Weir-type weak and strong duality theorems, and illustrate our results with an example.
Keywords:
robust optimization; equilibrium problem; semi-infinite programming; interval-valued functions; optimality MSC:
90C46; 90C33; 90C34; 90C70
1. Introduction
Uncertainty can be treated from fuzzy theory or interval analysis. We will use the latter method to capture uncertainty in the objective function and robust programming to capture uncertainty in the constraints.
On the other hand, in economics, it is often interesting, in addition to looking for maxima and minima, to find the points where equilibrium is achieved. In the 1960s, Fan [] studied the theory of equilibrium in Euclidean spaces. Suppose we have a nonempty closed set where and a bifunction . In an equilibrium problem (EP), the aim is to find such that
Far from being a particular problem, the equilibrium problem groups together other significant mathematical problems:
- The classical optimality problem, where and f is a real valued function.
- Let us suppose that is the space of all continuous linear mappings from Y to Z and . The variational inequality problem involvingThe geometrical interpretation of the inner product is that the angle between the vectors and is less than or equal .A particular case of a variational problem is the Signorini Problem. This problem consists of finding the elastic equilibrium configuration of an anisotropic non-homogeneous elastic body, resting on a rigid frictionless surface and subject only to its mass forces. This problem can be modeled as follows:And this problem can be expressed by the variational inequality:
- Fixed point problems: Let us suppose a closed set . Then, a fixed point of a mapping is any such that . This problem is an EP by simply considering
- Saddle point problems: Let us assume two closed sets, and ; a saddle point of a function is any such that
- Walras model of economic equilibrium: Let us assume we have a market structure with perfect competition. We have n commodities, a price vector and the excess demand mapping , where indicates the family of all subsets of . We can define a price as a vector of equilibrium price if it solvesIn 1990, Dafermos [] proved that a price is said to be an equilibrium price vector if it solves the EP, which consists of finding such that such that
- The Nash equilibrium problem: when starting from n enterprises, each enterprise i may possess generating units. Let r denote the vector whose entry stands for the power generation by unit j. Assume that the price is a decreasing affine function of s with , where N is the number of all generating units. We can formulate the benefit achieved by the enterprise i asWe keep in mind that is said to be an equilibrium point of the model ifWith , we obtain an EP.
In recent years, computational studies have been carried out in parallel with theoretical studies. To find solutions to these equilibrium problems in a practical way, we rely on auxiliary problems.
For any scalar , we consider as
Clearly, with the assumption of B, . It is considered the classical Auxiliary Equilibrium Problem (AEP), the purpose of which is to find such that
Li et al. [] and Babu et al. [] reported that EP and AEP problems are equivalent under some assumptions. These authors, together with others, such as Tran et al. [], Yao et al. [] and Nguyen et al. [], have proposed algorithms for the solution as an equilibrium problem.
If we now turn our attention to finding the solution of an optimization problem, including the worst case of all existing scenarios, we are in Robust Optimization. Goberna et al. [] studied, in an uncertain environment, the optimality and duality of a robust problem for the linear multiobjective problem. Robust optimization has a wide spectrum of real-world applications, in particular, finance [], energy [], and internet routing [].
In this article, our focus is on equilibrium problems with infinite constraints, which have been called semi-infinite equilibrium problems. The first steps of this mathematical theory were established at the beginning of the last century by Haar [] and Charnes et al. []. Semi-infinite programming has countless applications in physics, economics, engineering design, etc. (see refs. [,,] and the references cited therein or the work of Vaz et al. [], where the authors describe robot trajectories as a semi-infinite programming problem). Recently, Upadhyay et al. [] have studied multiobjective semi-infinite programming problems in the novel field of Hadamard manifolds.
Sometimes, we cannot obtain or observe parameters with precision, as is the case with irrational numbers. Interval optimization problems serve as a surrogate option for dealing with uncertain parameters that cannot be precisely calculated. One solution for trapping uncertainty is to use intervals, which is the basis of interval analysis. Moore [] and Lodwick [] made efforts to fix the arithmetic of working with intervals and to avoid an accumulation of errors leading to a disastrous final result. Jayswal et al. [] studied generalized invexity by defining the intervals as a parametric function.
Lodwick et al. [] applied interval analysis to radiation therapy, and Cecconello et al. [] applied it to modeling the behavior of SARS-CoV-2. Jiang et al. [] proved that it is possible to obtain an uncertain friction coefficient without knowing its probabilistic distribution but by considering an interval. The consideration of the distance between atoms as an interval was the subject of study by Costa et al. []. Also, Osuna et al. [] formulated the portfolio problem proposed by Markowitz using intervals.
Historical Background
Some of the milestones in the study of EP are the article by Ansari and Flores-Bazán [] on Euclidean spaces and by Wei and Gong [] on real normed spaces. Our work in this paper will focus on considering constrained equilibrium problems and the use of interval-valued functions at the objective.
Kim [] emphasized studying the duality of an uncertain multiobjective robust optimization problem.
In the last few years, in our opinion, the most interesting works have been by Tung [] and Ahmad et al. []. Jayswal et al. [] studied the interval-valued optimization problem but not the EP. Properties are extended to a multiobjective case by Ahmad et al. [] and to a case of constraints with uncertainty by Jaichander et al. []. Antczak and Farajzadeh [] investigated the KKT conditions in a non-smooth case. Tung [] dealt with semi-infinite convex optimization with multiple interval-valued objective functions but no EP. Therefore, our contribution lies in the consideration of equilibrium problems, problems more general than those of mathematical programming.
Ruiz-Garzón et al. [] proposed extending the classical KKT conditions for the constrained vector equilibrium problem on Hadamard spaces, facing the challenge of substituting straight lines for geodesics. Equilibrium problems with interval-valued functions (IVF) were studied by Ruiz-Garzón et al. [], but not with uncertainty, and by Tripathi and Arora [], but without considering IVF or duality models. Our breakthrough is in treating uncertainty in both the constraints and the objective function in a single model.
This article brings to the foreground the novel study of the optimality conditions for semi-infinite interval equilibrium problems involving data uncertainty (RSIEPU). Our contributions are as follows:
- We present EP with infinite constraints and IVF in the objective and uncertainty in the constraints to handle imprecision.
- We achieve the necessary and sufficient conditions of optimality for the RSIEPU problem involving data uncertainty.
- We particularize these conditions for the robust semi-infinite mathematical programming problem with constraints (RSIPU).
- We present and obtain duality theorems of the Mond–Weir type and illustrate our results with an example.
This approach is part of the search for more global or general problem models than those previously dealt with by other authors, as is the case with the equilibrium problems that group others; it addresses the importance of the treatment of uncertainty, so common in our daily lives, and has applications to economics or energy, which have been discussed above.
Deliniation. The paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, we outline the notation and lemmas we will use and the intervals and semi-infinite programming. Section 3 is devoted to proving the necessary and sufficient optimality conditions for RSIEPU involving data uncertainty. We will clarify the results with an example. In Section 4, we present the optimality conditions of the RSIPU and duality theorems for the Mond–Weir-type dual problem. What is demonstrated in this article encompasses previous results obtained by other authors. We finish the article with some conclusions, ideas for further development, and references.
2. Tools
In this section we will outline the semi-infinite programming lemmas (see ref. []) and the definition of the interval-valued function that we will use in this article.
Lemma 1.
The convex hull of , , is a compact set if is a nonempty compact subset of . Moreover, if , then the convex cone containing the origin generated by , , is a closed cone.
Lemma 2.
Assume that the following are true:
- S and P are arbitrary (possibly infinite) index sets; maps S onto , and so does .
- The set is closed.
Then, (I) and (II) are equivalent:
- I:
- has no solution ;
- II:
- .
Lemma 3.
Assume that is an arbitrary collection of convex sets in and . Then, every nonzero vector of can be expressed as a non-negative linear combination of n or fewer linear independent vectors, each belonging to a different .
Let be the family of all bounded closed intervals in . We will remember the LU-order to decide when an interval is smaller or larger than another one.
Definition 1.
Let and be two closed intervals in . We write the following:
- .
- and and , with a strict inequality.
- .
We can extend the concept of function to IVF considering and let D be an open and non-empty subset of . Obviously, , where end-point functions and are real-valued functions and must verify the inequality for every to ensure that an interval is obtained.
Remark 1.
We can study the context or background of these concepts in Lodwick [] and Osuna et al. [].
3. Robust KKT Optimality Conditions
We then introduce the semi-infinite interval equilibrium problem with uncertainty in both the constraints and the objective function through interval-valued functions.
Consider the functions and , where . In this case, is an uncertainty parameter that lies in some convex and compact set . The set-valued mapping is defined as for all . So the points in the graph of are of the type .
A semi-infinite interval equilibrium problem involving data uncertainty is defined as finding such that
where
and we consider an arbitrary nonempty infinite index set denoted by T.
The robust formulation for SIEPU (called a robust semi-infinite interval equilibrium problem with uncertainty) is given as finding
Here, is an uncertain parameter for SIEPU. We consider the robust feasible region to be the set
For a point , the active constraint set is given as
We denote the set of active constraint multipliers at as
where is the collection of all the functions .
We suppose that the condition is satisfied for infinite values of and there exist finitely such that .
If there exist a finite set such that for , then we say that .
Definition 2.
If there exists no such that , then we say that is an optimal solution to RSIEPU.
Remark 2.
The Definition 2 is equivalent to there existing no such that . In this case, RSIEPU is a problem of real functions, not IVF.
Let us remember the classic concepts:
Definition 3.
Suppose S is a nonempty subset of M and .
- (a)
- The contingent cone of S at is
- (b)
- The negative polar cone of S in M is , and the strictly negative polar cone of S in M is
The properties that constraints must satisfy to ensure that the KKT conditions are necessary conditions of optimality are called constraint qualification and constitute a fundamental hypothesis to establish the validity of the conclusions of the KKT theorem. We will use one of them, the Abadie constraint qualification (ACQ).
Definition 4.
If the negative polar cone and the set
is closed, then the ACQ holds at .
First, we will address the necessary condition of optimality where we will make use of the lemmas of Section 2.
Theorem 1.
Let S be a nonempty convex subset of M, and let and be differential mappings at , a feasible point. Let .
Suppose that is an optimal solution of RSIEPU and ACQ holds at . Then, there exist , and , , such that
Proof.
Our first objective is to prove
(a) If , then .
Then, expression (3) is satisfied.
(b) Assume that . By reductio ad absurdum, suppose, the other way around, that there exists such that .
Since , there exists and such that for all k. It follows that
Therefore,
If we assume that then
which is in contradiction with being an optimal solution of RSIEPU, and therefore, the expression (3) holds.
Therefore, there is no , verifying
Furthermore, from Lemma 1, we are assured that is a compact set, and therefore,
is closed.
Based on Lemma 2, we obtain
According to Lemma 3, there exist and such that
Thus, the initial condition of KKT (1) is satisfied.
To justify the truth of the KKT’s ultimate condition, let W be a set in which such that
and we can see that W is a nonempty open convex set. It is clear that
for all and . According to the separation theorem, there exist and such that
Letting , we obtain . As and , we determine that
Thus,
Therefore the KKT conditions are verified. □
We will now tackle the proof of sufficient optimality conditions, for which we will need convexity assumptions.
Theorem 2.
Let S be a nonempty convex subset of M, and let and be differential mappings at , a feasible point. Let .
Proof.
As , verifying (1), there exist and , where is a finite subset of , such that
Since and , we determine that
Due to convexity at , we determine that
Suppose, on the contrary, that is not an optimal solution for RSIEPU. Then, there exists , verifying
Previous inequality together with imply that
Using the convexity assumption of at , we obtain
Through generalized convexity conditions, we can also obtain sufficient optimality conditions.
Theorem 3.
Let S be a nonempty convex subset of M, and let , and be differential mappings at , a feasible point. Let .
Proof.
Assume, on the contrary, that is not an optimal solution for RSIEPU; then, there is such that , and using the hypothesis of pseudoconvexity of at , we obtain . Since ,
As and , we obtain . This, along with , yields
The quasiconvexity assumption of at implies
Then,
Remark 3.
The theses of the theorems obtained in this paper generalize those proven by Wei and Gong [] in normed spaces and the optimality conditions given in Ruiz-Garzón et al. [] from semi-infinite interval equilibrium problems to uncertainty constraints, as well as the achievements made by Tripathi and Arora [] involving data uncertainty to IVF.
Remark 4.
It should be noted that the first KKT condition (1) does not involve the upper bound of the interval-valued function.
To sum up, our first milestone was to obtain KKT-type optimality conditions for the solutions of RSIEPU. We will clarify the above optimality conditions with the following example:
Example 1.
Let us begin with RSIEPU: find such that
where , and , with representing differentiable functions. For ,
is closed, i.e., ACQ holds at . Now, there exist and
such that
where and are convex, and therefore, is pseudoconvex and is quasiconvex at . Hence, all the premises in Theorem 3 show that is a solution of RSIEPU.
4. Particular Case
Robust Dual Model
We will turn our attention to a particular problem of equilibrium problems.
Thus, we will be able to study the semi-infinite interval programming problem with constraints (SIPU), defined as:
where
and T is an arbitrary nonempty infinite index set where and are differential mappings at .
We introduce the robust formulation for the previous problem:
The notation S denotes the robust feasible region:
Definition 5.
If there is no satisfying , then the point is an optimal solution for RSIPU.
We can therefore reach the following result for RSIPU.
Corollary 1.
Let S be a nonempty convex subset of M, and let , be differential mappings at , a feasible point.
Proof.
The proof follows the lines of those of the previous theorem when only considering RSIPU as a special case of RSIEPU by taking . □
Remark 5.
The results obtained by Tung [] can be considered to be particular cases of those obtained here involving data uncertainty.
In the development of mathematical optimization, the dual model is important, since the solutions of the dual and primal models are related, and there are advantages of using one model or the other depending on the occasion.
We turn our attention to the following Mond–Weir-type dual robust semi-infinite program:
We derive the following weak duality result:
Theorem 4.
Let r be a feasible solution to RSIPU and be a feasible solution to DRSIPU. Assume that is pseudoconvex at u and is quasiconvex at u. Then, the following cannot hold .
Proof.
From the feasibility hypothesis of r for RSIPU, we have , and the dual feasibility of gives for . Combining these, we obtain
Based on the quasiconvexity of at u, we obtain
Due to the first dual feasibility condition,
Hence,
Suppose, on the contrary, that the hypothesis is not true, i.e., ; then, . The pseudoconvexity of at u implies that
Let us illustrate this theorem with an example:
Example 2.
Let us think about the following problem:
where , and , with representing differentiable functions. For ,
is closed, i.e., ACQ holds at . Now, there exist and
such that
where is pseudoconvex and is a quasiconvex function at . Hence, all the hypotheses in Theorem 1 show that is a solution of RSIPU.
Let us formulate the dual model:
The point is a feasible solution to RSIPU, and (0, 1, 1, 1) verifies the feasibility conditions of DRSIPU. The premises of the weak duality theorem hold at these points. Hence, the weak duality relation holds between RSIPU and DRSIPU.
Remark 6.
This weak duality theorem (Theorem 4) extends Proposition 4 by Tung [] to uncertainty constraints, Proposition 5.1 by Jayswal et al. [] and Theorem 4.1 by Ahmad et al. [] to interval-valued functions or the Wolfe dual problem given by Jaichander et al. [] to Mond-Weir dual problem.
Theorem 5.
Let be an optimal solution to RSIPU and ACQ be satisfied at . Then, there exist , and , , such that is a feasible solution to DRSIPU and the two objective values are equal. Further, if the hypothesis of weak duality holds for all feasible solutions , then is an optimal solution to DRSIPU.
Proof.
Since is an optimal solution to RSIPU and ACQ is verified at , then according to Theorem 1, there exist , and , , such that
which yields that is a feasible solution to DRSIPU and the corresponding objective values are equal. Suppose that is not an optimal solution to DRSIPU; then, there exists a feasible solution to DRSIPU such that , which contradicts the weak duality. Hence, is an optimal solution to DRSIPU. □
Remark 7.
This strong duality theorem (Theorem 5) extends Proposition 5 by Tung [] to uncertainty constraints, Proposition 5.2 by Jayswal et al. [] and Theorem 4.2 by Ahmad et al. [] to interval-valued functions or the Wolfe dual problem given by Jaichander et al. [] to Mond-Weir dual problem.
Remark 8.
The study of duality and the success of its economic interpretation dates back to the beginning of mathematical programming, in particular, to Von Newmann, as a result of his work in game theory; in practice, it may be that the robust dual version is not always easier to deal with than the primal problem. The model to be solved must be chosen.
5. Conclusions
What has been achieved with this article is summarized as follows concerning the existing literature:
- We introduce RSIEPU involving data uncertainty by addressing the treatment of uncertainty in the objective function and the constraints.
- We achieve the necessary and sufficient conditions of optimality for RSIPU. The results obtained in this paper extend the theorems given by Wei and Gong [] in normed spaces and the optimality conditions given in Ruiz-Garzón et al. [] from semi-infinite interval equilibrium problems to uncertainty constraints, as well as the results achieved by Tripathi and Arora [] involving data uncertainty to interval-valued functions.
- We introduce DRSIPU and we prove the weak and strong theorems of duality. We generalize the results by Tung [], Jayswal et al. [], Ahmad et al. [] and Jaichander et al. [].
Finally, we believe it is appropriate to continue to persevere in obtaining applications of these results in the economic field.
Author Contributions
Conceptualization, G.R.-G.; writing—original draft preparation, G.R.-G., R.O.-G., A.R.-L. and A.B.-M.; writing—review and editing, G.R.-G., R.O.-G., A.R.-L. and A.B.-M.; funding acquisition, G.R.-G. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding
This research was supported by MICIN through grant MCIN/AEI/PID2021-123051NB-100.
Institutional Review Board Statement
Not applicable.
Informed Consent Statement
Not applicable.
Data Availability Statement
Data are contained within the article.
Acknowledgments
The authors would like to thank the Instituto de Desarrollo Social y Sostenible (INDESS) for providing the facilities for the preparation of this work. The authors extend their gratitude and consideration towards the referees for the suggestions they provided that have improved this article.
Conflicts of Interest
The authors declare no conflicts of interest.
References
- Fan, K. A generalization of Tychonoff’s fixed point theorem. Math. Ann. 1961, 142, 305–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dafermos, S. Exchange price equilibria and variational inequalities. Math. Program. 1990, 46, 391–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, X.B.; Zhou, L.W.; Huang, N.J. Gap functions and descend methods for equilibrium problems on Hadamard manifolds. J. Nonlinear Convex Anal. 2016, 17, 807–826. [Google Scholar]
- Babu, F.; Ali, A.; Alkhadi, A.H. An extragradient method for non-monotone equilibrium problems on Hadamard manifolds with applications. Appl. Numer. Math. 2022, 180, 85–103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tran, D.Q.; Dung, M.L.; Nguyen, V.H. Extragradient algorithms extended to equilibrium problems. Optimization 2008, 57, 749–776. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yao, Y.; Adamu, A.; Shehu, Y.; Yao, J.C. Simple proximal-type algorithms for equilibrium problems. J. Glob. Optim. 2024, 89, 1069–1098. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nguyen, T.T.V.; Strodiot, J.J.; Nguyen, V.H. Hybrid methods for solving simultaneously an equilibrium problem and countably many fixed point problems in a Hilbert space. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 2014, 160, 809–831. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goberna, M.A.; Jeyakumar, V.; Li, G.; Vicente-Perez, J. Robust solutions of multiobjective linear semi-infinite programs under constraint data uncertainty. SIAM J. Optim. 2014, 24, 1402–1419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gabrel, V.; Murat, C.; Thiele, A. Recent advances in robust optimization: An overview. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2014, 235, 471–483. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, B.; Li, A.; Wang, L.; Feng, W. Robust optimization for energy transactions in multi-microgrids under uncertainty. Appl. Energy 2018, 217, 346–360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Doolittle, E.K.; Kerivin, H.L.M.; Wiecek, M.M. Robust multiobjective optimization with application to Internet routing. Ann. Oper. Res. 2018, 271, 487–525. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Haar, A. Uber lineare Ungleichungen. Acta Math. Szeged 1924, 2, 1–14. [Google Scholar]
- Charnes, A.; Cooper, W.W.; Kortanek, K.O. Duality, Haar programs and finite sequence spaces. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1962, 48, 783–786. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Goberna, M.A. Linear semi-infinite optimization: Recent advances. In Continuous Optimization, Current Trends and Modern Applications; Applied Optimization Series; Jeyakumar, V., Rubinov, A.M., Eds.; Springer Science & Business Media: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2005; Volume 99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goberna, M.A.; López, M.A. Linear semi-infinite programming theory: An updated survey. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2002, 143, 390–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- López, M.A.; Still, G. Semi-infinite programming. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2007, 180, 491–518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vaz, A.I.F.; Fernandes, E.M.G.P.; Gomes, M.P.S.F. Robot trajectory planning with semi-infinite programming. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2004, 153, 607–617. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Upadhyay, B.B.; Ghosh, A.; Treanţă, S. Efficiency conditions and duality for multiobjective semi-infinite programming problems on Hadamard manifolds. J. Glob. Optim. 2024, 89, 723–744. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Moore, R.E. Interval Analysis; Prentice Hall: Englewood Cliffs, HJ, USA, 1966. [Google Scholar]
- Lodwick, W.A. Constrained Interval Arithmetic; University of Colorado at Denver, Center for Computational Mathematics: Denver, CO, USA, 1999. [Google Scholar]
- Jayswal, A.; Stancu-Minasian, I.M.; Banerjee, J.; Stancu, A.M. Sufficiency and duality for optimization problems involving interval-valued invex function in parametric form. Oper. Res.—Int. J. (ORIJ) 2015, 15, 137–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lodwick, W.; Newman, F.; Neumaier, A. Optimization under uncertainty: Methods and applications in radiation therapy. In Proceedings of the 10th IEEE International Conference on Fuzzy Systems (Cat. No.01CH37297), Melbourne, VIC, Australia, 2–5 December 2001; Volume 2, pp. 1219–1222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cecconello, M.S.; Mizukoshi, M.T.; Lodwick, W. Interval nonlinear initial-valued problem using constraint intervals: Theory and an application to the SARS-CoV-2 outbreak. Inf. Sci. 2021, 577, 871–882. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jiang, C.; Han, X.; Liu, G.R.; Li, G.Y. The optimization of the variable binder force in U-shaped forming with uncertain friction coefficien. J. Mater. Process. Technol. 2007, 182, 262–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Costa, T.M.; Bouwmeester, H.; Lodwick, W.A.; Lavor, C. Calculating the possible conformations arising from uncertainty in the molecular distance geometry problem using constraint interval analysis. Inform. Sci. 2017, 425–416, 41–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Osuna-Gómez, R.; Hernández-Jiménez, B.; Chalco-Cano, Y.; Ruiz-Garzón, G. New efficiency conditions for multiobjective interval-valued programming problems. Inf. Sci. 2017, 420, 235–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ansari, Q.H.; Flores-Bazán, F. Generalized vector quasi-equilibrium problems with applications. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 2003, 277, 246–256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wei, Z.F.; Gong, X.H. Kuhn-Tucker optimality conditions for vector equilibrium problems. J. Inequal. Appl. 2010, 2010, 842715. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kim, M.H. Duality theorem and vector saddle point theorem for robust multiobjective optimization problems. Commun. Korean Math. Soc. 2013, 28, 597–602. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tung, L.T. Karush-Kuhn-Tucker optimality conditions and duality for convex semi-infinite programming with multiple interval-valued objective functions. J. Appl. Math. Comput. 2020, 62, 67–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ahmad, I.; Kaur, A.; Sharma, M. Robust optimality conditions and duality in semi-infinite multiobjective programming. Acta Math. Univ. Comen. 2022, 91, 87–99. [Google Scholar]
- Jayswal, A.; Ahmad, I.; Banerjee, J. Nonsmooth interval-valued optimization and saddle-point optimality criteria. Bull. Malays. Math. Sci. Soc. 2016, 39, 1391–1411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jaichander, R.R.; Ahmad, I.; Kummari, K. Robust semi-infinite interval-valued optimization problem with uncertain inequality constraints. Korean J. Math. 2022, 30, 475–489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Antczak, T.; Farajzadeh, A. On nondifferentiable semi-infinite multiobjective programming with interval-valued functions. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2022, 19, 8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ruiz-Garzón, G.; Osuna-Gómez, R.; Ruiz-Zapatero, J. Necessary and sufficient optimality conditions for vector equilibrium problem on Hadamard manifolds. Symmetry 2019, 11, 1037. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ruiz-Garzón, G.; Osuna-Gómez, R.; Rufián-Lizana, A.; Beato-Moreno, A. Semi-infinite interval equilibrium problems: Optimality conditions and existence results. Comp. Appl. Math. 2023, 42, 248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tripathi, I.P.; Arora, M.A. Robust optimality conditions for semi-infinite equilibrium problems involving data uncertainty. J. Appl. Math. Comput. 2024, 70, 2641–2664. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).