Next Article in Journal
Study on Controlled Low-Strength Materials Using Ultra-Rapid-Hardening Cement and Stone Sludge for Backfill and Subbase Application in Road Excavation and Restoration Work
Next Article in Special Issue
Eco-Friendly Technology Derivation and Planning for Rooftop Greenhouse Smart Farm
Previous Article in Journal
Industry 4.0 Maturity of General Contractors: An In-Depth Case Study Analysis
Previous Article in Special Issue
What Is the Impact of the Energy Class on Market Value Assessments of Residential Buildings? An Analysis throughout Northern Italy Based on Extensive Data Mining and Artificial Intelligence
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Urban Density and Land Leverage: Market Value Breakdown for Energy-Efficient Assets

Department of Civil Environmental and Architectural Engineering (DICEA), University of Padua, Via Venezia 1, 30151 Padova, Italy
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Buildings 2024, 14(1), 45; https://doi.org/10.3390/buildings14010045
Submission received: 23 October 2023 / Revised: 18 December 2023 / Accepted: 20 December 2023 / Published: 22 December 2023

Abstract

:
A real estate asset comprises land and improvements. The proportions of these components vary over time and across locations. Notably, the land value component is consistent over time, unaffected by depreciation. Consequently, the weight of land value in determining the overall asset value is crucial, particularly in those improvements that are highly sensitive to depreciation, such as energy-efficient buildings. While several studies have explored the relationship between energy-efficient building consumption and urban density, there is currently a research gap concerning the relationship between land value and the value of efficient improvements built on it. Before investigating this potential relationship, it is imperative to preliminary examine any possible correlations between land values and land density. To verify this correlation, we captured the “Land Leverage” of a real estate property by calculating the ratio between the value of the land and the total value of the real estate property and correlating it with the allowable density. Our analysis of the Land Leverage (LL) trend in a restricted development area over a ten-year period demonstrates that LL increases with the level of permitted density in a neighborhood. This evidence will serve as the foundation to verify whether Land leverage, through urban-densification strategies, might be a pivotal factor in driving the values of energy-efficient assets.

1. Introduction

Houses, better identified as real properties (RP), are recognized to be bundled goods. Both academic literature and Uniform Standards have recognized RP as a bundle of land, improvements, and associated rights [1,2,3,4]. By definition, real estate (RE) encompasses the physical land along with all natural and manmade elements attached or appurtenant to it. RP’s definition includes the concept of RE, incorporating ownership rights over the RE, also referred to as a bundle of rights [5]; see Figure 1. This distinction is relevant as our study aims to quantify the value of the land as a percentage of the total value, taking it for granted that these two values are separable and independently assessable [6]. The land value ratio, i.e., the ratio of the land’s value to the total real property value, is also called Land Leverage in the literature (LL).
Given that the value of the land is not sensitive to depreciation due to functional, economic, or physical obsolescence, it is relevant to define its leverage as a pivotal factor to investigate not only real estate market trends but also the trends of the values of the features and the performances of the improvements that are built on it, commonly defined as buildings.
In developed regions, urban areas stand as significant contributors to climate change and greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions, consuming approximately 60% to 80% of global energy consumption, accounting for an equal share of global carbon dioxide emissions [7]. Meanwhile, buildings play a pivotal role in energy consumption, reaching a higher percentage (38.1%) of total energy consumption within the European Union, surpassing other sectors such as transportation (33.3%) and industry (25.9%) [8]. In particular, the residential sector, which is the larger stock in RE, holds the primary responsibility for energy consumption within buildings [9]. Considering this, one of the most interesting features to be investigated in the building sector is the energy efficiency performance of an asset and its change in value. To explore the relationship between the value of energy-efficient buildings and the value of the land, we are currently engaged in a larger-scale project that comprises three distinct phases (Figure 2). In Phase I, which has already been concluded, we verified correlations between land prices and densification policies, suggesting that density is a value-added feature that affects land prices, with higher values in denser areas [10,11]. Following Phase I’s findings, which highlighted that density changes the percentage composition of economic factors such as the incidence of costs and land value [10], we are currently developing Phase II to investigate possible correlations between density and Land Leverage. The insights from Phase II will serve as the groundwork for our future research (Phase III), aiming to investigate the potential impact of urban densification strategies on leveraging land as a key factor in enhancing the value of energy-efficient real estate assets.
Given the scope of this larger research project, this study wants to investigate possible relationships between land value, accounted as Land Leverage, and urban density. To achieve this, we collected a time series of sales that occurred in Boston between 2012 and 2022. The database comprises land transactions within a delimited region near the Seaport area. This area was involved in 2016 in an urban planning change that increased the permitted Floor Area Ratio (FAR) limit, increasing the area’s permitted density. Our analysis seeks to determine whether urban density can affect Land Leverage and, consequently, trends within the RE market. The outcomes of this study will provide insights into the dynamics of densification on RE market prices, broken down into land and improvement values. These results will provide insights in Phase III into how densification policies might influence the values of energy-efficient improvements.
There are five sections in this study. Following the introduction in Section 1, Section 2 details the related literature review, and Section 3, after presenting the case study and data, designs materials and methodology, including the research design and search strategy. Section 4 deals with the results obtained, and it presents the discussion focusing on the relationship between Land Leverage and density. Section 5 discusses the conclusion, limitations, and future research directions.

2. Literature Review

The literature has extensively investigated the existing relationship between building energy consumption and urban density. Most of these studies centered on the impact of building design, height, and urban density on energy efficiency and consumption. They revealed that denser urban developments result in lower energy consumption within urban areas [12,13,14,15,16,17,18,19,20,21]. Considering that density is a factor that primarily influences construction costs and land values, several studies have been run on the correlation between density and costs; however, to date, there are no studies that specifically investigate the potential relationship between the value of the land and value of energy-efficient buildings (EEBs), which are built on it. To fill this gap, this is investigated in Phase III of our study. This paper will also lay the preliminary basis, focusing on Phase II, where we will investigate the possible correlation between Land Leverage and urban density.
In the literature, there is a long tradition that studies land value trends in urban economics. In the early literature, land values accounted for their distance from the urban center to explain spatial price trends [22,23,24]. As a result of their research, the higher demand for land in close proximity to the urban center affects the overall prices, identifying a gradient of appreciation on these values. This price gradient has been translated into a Land Leverage gradient, i.e., the ratio of land value to total property value, which varies within urban areas [3]. The literature features numerous studies on how Land Leverage varies over time, across location, and over land usage to capture price volatility—for example, due to inflation, construction costs, gross domestic product (GDP), and population growth [2].
The value of an asset hinges on four main characteristics, abbreviated as DUST (Demand, Utility, Scarcity, and Transferability). Considering these four dimensions, the literature has extensively investigated the relationship between the land ratio and market demand and scarcity across time and location. According to Scarcity Theory, land values will continue to rise because of scarcity, and this trend will persist in the foreseeable future. The increase in land value is the foremost driver of purchase price growth. Moreover, the resilience of Land Leverage against depreciation can significantly impact a landowner’s eligibility to secure financing.
In addition, the LL ratio is used by banks and lenders to assess the worth of a property and the amount of financing they are ready to offer. For these reasons, given the profound impact of LL on RE market values, it is crucial to study the relationship that exists between land value and the values of the improvements. However, considering the “DUST” features, the existing literature only partially investigated how the value of land can be influenced by its utility. Utility can be described by the potential for land to be developed with improvements. This transformability can be investigated through two zoning aspects: the potential use of the developable land (i.e., residential or commercial use) or the allowable volume to be built on the parcel of land. While the former has received considerable attention in the literature [3,25], there is a gap in exploring the latter aspect that warrants further investigation.
As previously mentioned, several studies have concentrated on examining the existing correlation between LL and the RE market trends across time, location, and land use. In the early XI century, the literature started investigating LL in relationship with house price trends throughout the US. Bostic et al. accounted for land values with two different approaches. In the first approach, they compared the prices of vacant lots with their prices after development. In the second approach, they used the assessed values assigned to land and improvements as determined by the local property tax assessor office. Both samples yield comparable findings regarding the impact of Land Leverage on house price inflation within a city [3]. Similarly, Davis and Heathcote [26], analyzing residential land sales from the late 1970s to the early 2000s, found that land prices quadrupled while improvement prices grew by only one third. Over this period, LL increased by 27% in 30 years (from 35% in 1975 to 46% in 2006). They calculated the land price indexes by considering housing market values of the 2000 decennial census for RE prices and construction costs released by the Federal Housing Finance Agency and by the Bureau of Economic Analysis, to be subtracted to obtain land values. Considering the above, they calculated a LL index through time, and further, they regressed these values (real house, land, and structure prices) on a set of independent variables, such as real per capita income, demographic variables, inflation rates, mortgage rates, and Treasury Bill rates. By considering Land Leverage within this framework, they gained valuable insights into the dynamics of house prices. Another relevant study, involving the residual land value method, was developed by Davis and Palumbo [27]. By using residential construction cost data to assess the price of housing stock, they investigated LL for residential single-family developments in several US metropolitan areas between 1984 and 2004. They accounted for an increase in LL of 51% during the considered time frame. Verifying the rise in land prices, recent studies during the last decade focused on LL as a function of the RE market value using spatial autoregressive models to estimate the factor decomposition results of housing prices [2,4,28,29,30,31]. Summarizing, to separate the land value from the other components of the property value to calculate the LL, the above-mentioned studies applied two methods. Some studies focused on the unit sale price of vacant, unimproved land parcels, comparing them with RE market prices in the same areas [32,33,34,35]. Meanwhile, other studies, similar to the current work’s aims, estimated the land value by applying the residual land value method as a residual by subtracting the development cost from the sale price of the developed property [4,26,27,36,37,38,39,40].
In line with the purpose of our current research, which aims to explore the potential correlation between LL and urban density, we analyzed the existing literature available. Copious literature has been produced on the relationship between land prices and urban density as one of the two main factors (land use policy vs. location) able to determine land supply elasticity [28,41]. However, very limited literature has been written on the land-to-building ratio. Sever studies focused on the influence of land use plans or zoning laws on land values [10,11,42,43,44,45,46]. Urban growth boundary constraints, densification policies, and building permits represent common tools within land use plans and zoning regulations. Building permits, alongside zoning and planning restrictions, exert a significant influence on the density of urban development [47]. Constraints placed on the density of developable land diminish achievable profits, reducing developers’ willingness to pay and consequently decreasing total land value. Numerous studies have corroborated the intuitive economic theory that the greater the potential development volume, the greater the land value, which varies significantly across cities and locations within cities [48,49,50]. These empirical studies have demonstrated a direct correlation between land values and the effective FAR of a parcel. Two recent studies demonstrated that density and therefore densification policies are value-added tools able to increase land value on a FAR basis. This indicates that communities and developers valued density with a greater willingness to pay, internalizing the economic, social, and environmental sustainability benefits [10,11], and that the land market is considerably distorted by excessive administrative interventions by local governments [51]. Alongside studies on density and price increases, there are studies that have verified and quantified the rise in sales prices and rents of energy-efficient assets. In Germany, through the application of a hedonic price model, Taruttis and Webe found a positive correlation between EEBs and their sale prices, with an average increase of 6.9% when energy efficiency climbs by 100 kWh/m2 [52]. Moreover, their study unearthed regional differences, attributing lower energy-efficiency premiums to factors like housing scarcity and increased purchasing power per capita. In China, the results, however, lead to a smaller increase in property prices, approximately 0.583% in higher EEBs [53]. In the US, several studies confirmed price premiums for EEBs ranging from 1.2% to 16.5% across the States [54,55,56,57,58,59]. Furthermore, a recent literature review has been conducted on approximately 50 previous studies worldwide regarding the price premium that consumers are willing to pay for energy-efficient buildings [60]. This study identifies the most commonly used approach as the hedonic price model and reveals that all studies have estimated a positive price premium with a rather diversified range across continents, states, and property types [60,61,62,63]. All these studies are important because by identifying a price premium and thus a marginal price related to energy efficiency that society is willing to pay, they lay the groundwork and guide government policies in creating sustainability awareness. The ecological impact of such assets is therefore reflected in both social and financial aspects and performances. By implementing political and social actions, like urban densification, governments and local administrations can enhance not just the socio-ecological quality of urban areas but also improve the financial and economic performance of real estate assets [64,65,66].
The literature has thus far confirmed two crucial points: (i) the existence of a price premium in highly energy-efficient buildings and (ii) the increase in value in areas with higher density. However, a direct examination of the potential correlation between price premiums of energy-efficient buildings and urban density has not yet been conducted. To fill this gap, which will be addressed in Phase III of our study, we want to first investigate whether and how density can influence land prices in terms of Land Leverage. Land Leverage represents the distribution of values between improvements and vacant land, defining the non-depreciating portion of the asset value. The current phase of our research will focus on a specific area where recent changes in land use regulations have altered urban density. The aim is to empirically assess the effects of densification tools on Land Leverage.

3. Materials and Methods

3.1. Data

The survey was held in a limited neighborhood in the Seaport District of Boston. This area went through a densification zoning process in 2016 that allowed for higher and denser developments, increasing permitted FAR. Prior to 2016, this area, called Dorchester Corridor, spanning 144 acres, was characterized by low population density and was experiencing a depopulation trend. The new urban plan, approved in 2016 by the Local Authorities, increased the local density from the previously approved 2.0 FAR, allowing for additional building heights of up to 300 feet. Considering the setback requirements, building floor plate dimensions, and lot coverage constraints, the potential redevelopment gross area has now been expanded to 4.7 FAR, effectively more than doubling the previous density level.
The overall sample includes 112 land transactions that occurred during the last decade (2012–2022) in this restricted Corridor. The collected data have been sampled from Massachusetts Land Records [67], Registry of Deeds [68], and includes, where available, the address of the asset, recording date of transaction, book and page of the deed, sale price (LVi), and grantor and grantee. For each transaction, we estimated the potential density of each parcel with two approaches. Where the parcel was already improved, we reported the Gross Floor Area (GFAi) of the existing improvements. If vacant, and redevelopment plans were presented at the time of the transaction, we used the proposed GFAi to calculate the potential FAR of the sold parcel. If no development plans were presented, we applied the allowable FAR per the existing urban plan. For each land sale, we therefore calculated the maximum allowable GFAi for each parcel.
Additionally, we collected construction cost prices (CCi) sourced from Marshall Valuation Services in manuals, which provide annual building cost data categorized by type, class, and quality of the finishing throughout the US. We adjusted these direct costs, accounting for location, building height, number of stories, and building class. Additionally, we recalibrated these costs (aCCi) to encompass indirect expenses and developer profit as a percentage of the direct costs.
Finally, to verify any potential correlation between land price trends and the RE market and construction costs trend, we defined two different indexes. We collected 398 transactions of residential multifamily that occurred in the same timeframe period and in the same geographical area to build a Multifamily Transaction Price Index [10]. Ultimately, using the above-mentioned costs published by Marshall Valuation Services, we inferred a Construction Cost Index covering the analyzed timeframe.

3.2. The Method—Measuring Land Leverage

To calculate Land Leverage for each transaction of our survey, we applied the reverse equivalent of the land residual technique. Usually, this method estimates the building value as equal to the cost to replace the existing improvement minus its depreciation, both assessed at the time of sale. The land value is then determined as the difference between the property value and depreciated replacement cost. As said, the residual land value is a commonly employed method for determining the value of land suitable for development. This method involves subtracting all costs associated with the development, including profit, while excluding the land cost from the total value of the project. The model’s assumptions rely on the premise that the construction costs to build a brand-new building, eventually accounting for depreciation, are easily determined in the local market. In our case, since we collected land values, we used this method to estimate the production costs of the allowable development to be added to land value to obtain the overall RE value of the developed land. The method involves calculating the construction cost of each potential development to be built in the sold parcel by multiplying the allowable FAR by the adjusted construction cost per square foot, as published by Marshall and Swift. No physical, functional, or economic depreciation was factored into our considerations as we are considering building a brand-new asset.
For each transaction (i), the total value of a RE development, REVi, can be separated into the value of the land, LVi, and the value of the improvements, IVi, as follows:
REVi = LVi × IVi
As previously mentioned, LVi are known data that we collected over the indicated timeframe. Instead, we calculated the IVi values as follows:
IVi = GFAi × aCCi
where aCCi is the adjusted Construction Cost (USD/SF) of the potential improvement to be built, and the GFAi is the gross floor area that can be built by law in the sold land parcel, and it is calculated as follows:
GFi = FARi × BLi
where FARi is the Floor Area Ratio allowed and BLi is the buildable land area of the sold parcel in square feet.
As said in the previous section, the Construction Costs (aCCi) have been derived from the annually updated Construction Costs Manuals published by Marshall Valuation Services. We selected the most appropriate costs (USD/SF) in relation to the allowable development, considering type, class, and quality. We adjusted these direct costs, accounting for location, building height, number of stories, and building class. We also revised these construction costs, including indirect costs (10% of the base Construction Cost CCi) and developer profit (15% of the CCi), as direct cost percentages to obtain the production costs of the potential development.
Having calculated the overall REVi for each transaction, Formula (1), we can finally determine the Land Leverage (LLi) as follows:
LL i = L V i R E V i
To verify the possible correlation between density and Land Leverage, we finally divided the overall land transaction sample into two groups (Figure 3). GroupB included the LLi for each transaction that occurred before plan approval over a period of time between 2012 and 2015. GroupA included the LLi for each transaction that occurred after plan approval during the timeframe spanning from 2016 to 2022.
Moreover, aiming to verify possible similarities in market trends, we compared the land’s historical price trend with residential price and construction cost trends during the survey period. To accomplish this, we calculated an annual index normalizing the average annual transaction prices for land transaction ( L I i ), for residential transaction ( R I i ), and for construction cost prices ( C I i ). The indexes were calculated as follows:
I i = ( A A U P i × 100 ) / A A U P b a s e
where i indicates the year, Ii is the annual price index calculated for each year, A A U P b a s e is the Annual Average Unit Price (or cost) recorded in the base year 2012, and A A U P i is the Annual Average Unit Price (or cost) in year i. A A U P i was reported on an SF of GFA basis for land transactions and on an SF basis for residential transactions and for Construction Costs.
After creating the above-described indexes ( L I i , R I i , C I i ), we compared them in Figure 4 to verify similarities. Since we want to test a possible common trend in price and cost variations through the selected period that could suggest a similar trend in RE market conditions, we calculated the annual variation for each index to test the analysis of variance (ANOVA) between these three groups.
Finally, we tested the mean difference of the LLi between the two groups (GroupB and GroupA) to verify if there is a significant difference in the Land Value Ratio before and after densification.

4. Results and Discussion

The average Land Leverage (LLi) within the sample stands at 35.5%, indicating that the building leverage (BLi) is 64.5%. As summarized in Table 1 and visualized in Figure 5, the difference observed in LLi between GroupB and GroupA amounts to 16.3%, which corresponds to the increase in the land ratio after increasing the allowable density, from an average of 32.50% in GroupB up to 37.80% in GroupA. Further, we can verify that the number of transactions increased by approximately 12.3% before and after zoning approval, with 10 average annual land sales before 2016, up to 11.08 after up-zoning tool approval, accounting for a partial year in 2022.
The other two columns in Table 1 represent the prices (RP) and Construction Costs (CCs) that have been used to compose the Residential Transaction Index ( R I i ) and the Construction Cost Index ( C I i ), as per Formula (5).
Per Figure 4, which compares the trends of the three indexes that have been calculated using Formula (5), we can confirm that the Land Transaction Price Index ( L I i ) increased faster than the other two indices. The Residential Transaction Price Index ( R I i ), which represents RE property values (including land, improvements, and rights), increases faster than the Construction Costs Index ( C I i ), but lesser than that of the Land Transaction Price Index. Since 2012, L I i has increased by 360.9%, R I i has increased by 89.1%, and C I i has increased by 24.9%. When considering only the period following densification zoning approval, their respective indices have grown by 209.2%, 16.5%, and 17,1%, which corresponds to an average annual increase of 34.9% and 2.8% for R I i and C I i , respectively. These results suggest a notably heightened increase in the Land Transaction Price Index, which appears to be significantly impacted by densification policies. However, to verify whether the RE market trends (represented by the indexes of residential sales and construction costs) have the same growth as the land market through the selected period, we ran an ANOVA test on the annual variation for each index ( L I i , R I i , C I i ). The p-value of the test rejected the null hypothesis, confirming a difference among group means of the three analyzed trends and that their variation is not correlated with an average trend (Figure 6 and Figure 7), confirming our initial hypothesis.
According to the Land Leverage Hypothesis, in an RE market where residential prices have risen faster than Construction Costs (as confirmed by Figure 4), land values have increased at an even greater rate [3]. Within this market, properties with a greater LL should experience a more significant increase in price appreciation. The distribution of the LL seems to increase after densification approval, as shown in Figure 8. To corroborate this hypothesis, we ran a two-sample t-test between the two groups (p-value: 0.025; significance level: 0.05). The results of the test reject the null hypothesis of equality between the means of the two groups, endorsing the suggestion that the Land Leverage observation in GroupA is higher than LL in GroupB (Table 2). According to the performed test, the estimated difference is −0.0529, with a 95% Confidence Interval for the difference at −0.098884 −0.006964, confirming our assumptions (Figure 8).
This outcome suggests that Land Leverage was affected by increased area densification, increasing land unit values. As land parcels are not subject to depreciation, we can assert that an increase in land value will enhance the asset’s future price stability. Referring to Figure 4 and Figure 6, it becomes evident that the L I i has increased by approximately 3-fold compared to R I i before the zoning change and by more than 11 times following densification approval. This confirms that land transactions have captured the highest increase in price compared to existing residential transactions. Parcels sold in GroupA, which are likely to be developed into residential assets sooner or later, will be placed on the market with a price premium in comparison to similar assets. This increase can be attributed to the Land Leverage rise, implying an increase in land value relative to the total asset value. This preliminary result is very relevant because, by changing the value ratios between the improvements and the underlying land, it stabilizes the fluctuations in the asset’s value guaranteed by the underlying non-depreciable land. As is known, the depreciation of a property is attributable to physical obsolescence, external obsolescence, and functional obsolescence stemming from the aging of the improvements. The obsolescence tends to increase not only with the decrease in the residual life of the asset but also with the increase in the percentage of technology included in the improvements’ physical components, which tends to depreciate much more rapidly compared to other features. Land, being inherently immune to obsolescence, does not undergo depreciation caused by age. This characteristic ensures that assets where the weight of Land Leverage is higher than others are more stable concerning market fluctuations and over time. In summary, the rise in LL in comparison to the total asset value has led to a reduced portion of the value prone to depreciation. This shift in proportions has consequently bolstered the asset’s future resilience in maintaining its value over time. The parcels involved in densification have elevated the proportion of value attributed to land, thereby rendering assets more stable and less susceptible to real estate market fluctuations and future improvement obsolescence.
This outcome suggests that in high-density areas, the future depreciation in value, particularly noticeable in highly energy-efficient buildings, will exert a lesser influence on the overall fluctuation of the RE asset due to the substantial weight of the land value. Phase I of the study demonstrated a positive correlation between urban density and land value, confirming density as a value-added feature impacting land prices. Furthermore, the results from Phase II have further supported the existing correlation between Land Leverage and urban density, illustrating that denser areas possess higher leverage, enhancing asset resilience against value fluctuations and depreciation. This stability in asset value will be transferred to the forthcoming energy-efficient improvements developed on these vacant parcels. Considering that both land value and Land Leverage have increased due to densification policies, these urban planning tools will consequently influence the price appreciation and premium of the improvements built in denser areas. Considering that (i) the literature has already confirmed that EEBs achieve a market price premium [55,56,57,59,66,69] and that (ii) the current study has verified that density affects land prices, increasing Land Leverage, we can think that EEBs, constructed in denser areas, could benefit from an increased value resulting from these two factors. Verifying and quantifying this dual value increment will be the aim of the next step (Phase III) of our research project.

5. Conclusions

This paper shows the results obtained in Phase II of the study, investigating the possible relationship between urban density and Land Leverage. This phase demonstrated that LL increases with the potential density of the land after demonstrating correlations between land prices and densification policies in Phase I. We analyzed a time series of land sales in a restricted area of Boston, where a densification process occurred in 2016. We used 2016 as the watershed year between two moments during which permitted density underwent changes. Having established that density alterations impact the percentage composition of economic factors such as cost values, we verified how densification tools, through land values, have the potential to enhance the stability of the real estate market, reducing its susceptibility to fluctuations stemming from shifts in costs, inflation, and obsolescence of the improvements. The suggestion arose from the observation that construction costs are generally quite uniform within an RE market, and thus it must be the case that asymmetric appreciation must arise from asymmetric exposure to common shocks to land values. As Bostic et al. suggested, in the RE market, where RE prices usually rise faster than construction costs, land values rise even more, causing an increase in Land Leverage as well.
In this paper, by analyzing the LL trend over time, we have demonstrated how the level of permitted density in a neighborhood can affect LL. Such evidence will serve as the basis for the next step in our research (Phase III), where we aim to explore whether Land Leverage, facilitated by urban densification tools, could play a pivotal role in driving the values of energy-efficient assets. This finding can provide insights into various significant phenomena within the RE market, particularly those related to the evolution of prices over time. We contend that the level of land indebtedness is a crucial factor, and it enhances our comprehension of property price dynamics. The breakdown of RE prices into two separate components, such as land and improvements, is crucial as it allows these values to evolve at a different trend. This distinction also becomes necessary when studying how density, influencing Land Leverage, might affect the value of energy efficiency improvements. The values of EEBs in denser areas where Land Leverage is also higher could also be influenced by the increase in land values and in LL, as demonstrated in this study. The future steps of our research will focus on quantifying the increase in the value of EEBs built in denser areas. In the future Phase III of our research project, we aim to verify and quantify the correlation between energy-efficiency improvements valued at replacement cost minus depreciation and land values, considering that their values cannot appreciate faster than construction costs.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization: R.C. and G.M.; methodology, investigation, resources, data curation, and writing—original draft preparation: R.C.; writing—review and editing, R.C. and G.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This study was funded by NOP on Research and Innovation (PON Ricerca e Innovazione) 2014–2020, Asse IV–Action IV.4 and Action IV.6—“Research Contracts on Green Themes” (Ministry of University and Research MUR—DM 1062/2021) “Towards green transition: new indicators for the assessment of territorial projects development” (TGTIndex), Cod. 19-G-14046-1. The views and opinions expressed are solely those of the authors.

Data Availability Statement

The data presented in this study are available on request from the corresponding author. The data are not publicly available due to due to confidentiality agreements on some of the transaction information.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Appraisal Standard Board. Uniform Standards of Professional Appraisal Practice (USPAP); The Appraisal Foundation: Washington, DC, USA, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  2. Bourassa, S.C.; Hoesli, M.; Scognamiglio, D.; Zhang, S. Land leverage and house prices. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2011, 41, 134–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bostic, R.W.; Longhofer, S.D.; Redfearn, C.L. Land leverage: Decomposing home price dynamics. Real Estate Econ. 2007, 35, 183–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Copiello, S. An Empirical Study of Land Leverage as a Function of Market Value Using a Spatial Autoregressive Model; Springer International Publishing: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  5. Detty, T. Basic Appraisal Principles; Hondros Learning, LLC: Westerville, OH, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  6. Hendriks, D. Apportionment in property valuation: Should we separate the inseparable? J. Prop. Investig. Financ. 2005, 23, 455–470. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Gossop, C. Low carbon cities: An introduction to the special issue. Cities 2011, 28, 495–497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Eurostat. Consumption of Energy. 2023. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/interactive-publications/energy-2023 (accessed on 9 October 2023).
  9. Conticelli, E.; Proli, S.; Tondelli, S. Integrating energy efficiency and urban densification policies: Two Italian case studies. Energy Build. 2017, 155, 308–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Canesi, R. Urban Policy Sustainability through a Value-Added Densification Tool: The Case of the South Boston Area. Sustainability 2022, 14, 8762. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Canesi, R.; D’Alpaos, C.; Marella, G. A Case of Local Community Engagement for Urban Regeneration: The South Boston Area. In Urban Regeneration Through Valuation Systems for Innovation; Springer International Publishing: Cham, Switzerland, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  12. Güneralp, B.; Zhou, Y.; Ürge-Vorsatz, D.; Gupta, M.; Yu, S.; Patel, P.L.; Fragkias, M.; Li, X.; Seto, K.C. Global scenarios of urban density and its impacts on building energy use through 2050. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2017, 114, 8945–8950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  13. He, X.; Yu, Y.; Jiang, S. City centrality, population density and energy efficiency. Energy Econ. 2023, 117, 106436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Ali-toudert, F. Energy Efficiency of Urban Buildings: Significance of Urban Geometry, Building Construction and Climate Conditions. In Proceedings of the The Seventh International Conference on Urban Climate, Yokohama, Japan, 29–32 July 2009. [Google Scholar]
  15. Hui, S.C.M. Low energy building design in high density urban cities. Renew. Energy 2001, 24, 627–640. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Resch, E.; Bohne, R.A.; Kvamsdal, T.; Lohne, J. Impact of Urban Density and Building Height on Energy Use in Cities. Energy Procedia 2016, 96, 800–814. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Huo, T.; Cao, R.; Xia, N.; Hu, X.; Cai, W.; Liu, B. Spatial correlation network structure of China’s building carbon emissions and its driving factors: A social network analysis method. J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 320, 115808. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  18. Bertoncini, M.; Boggio, A.; Dell’Anna, F.; Becchio, C.; Bottero, M. An application of the PROMETHEE II method for the comparison of energy requalification strategies to design Post-Carbon Cities. AIMS Energy 2022, 10, 553–581. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Fiorillo, D.; Galuppini, G.; Creaco, E.; De Paola, F.; Giugni, M. Identification of Influential User Locations for Smart Meter Installation to Reconstruct the Urban Demand Pattern. J. Water Resour. Plan. Manag. 2020, 146, 04020070. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Gabrielli, L.; Ruggeri, A.G.; Scarpa, M. Roadmap to a Sustainable Energy System: Is Uncertainty a Major Barrier to Investments for Building Energy Retrofit Projects in Wide City Compartments? Energies 2023, 16, 4261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Bragolusi, P.; D’Alpaos, C. The valuation of buildings energy retrofitting: A multiple-criteria approach to reconcile cost-benefit trade-offs and energy savings. Appl. Energy 2022, 310, 118431. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Alonso, W. Location and land use: Toward a general theory of land rent. In Toward a General Theory of Land Rent; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA; London, UK, 1964; pp. 101–142. [Google Scholar]
  23. Mills, E.S. An Aggregative Model of Resource Allocation in a Metropolitan Area. Am. Econ. Rev. 1967, 57, 197–210. [Google Scholar]
  24. Muth, R.F. The Derived Demand for Urban Residential Land. Urban Stud. 1971, 8, 243–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Nichols, J.B.; Oliner, S.D.; Mulhall, M.R. Swings in commercial and residential land prices in the United States. J. Urban Econ. 2013, 73, 57–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Davis, M.A.; Heathcote, J. The price and quantity of residential land in the United States. J. Monet. Econ. 2007, 54, 2595–2620. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Davis, M.A.; Palumbo, M.G. The price of residential land in large US cities. J. Urban Econ. 2008, 63, 352–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Fan, J.; Zhou, L.; Yu, X.; Zhang, Y. Impact of land quota and land supply structure on China’s housing prices: Quasi-natural experiment based on land quota policy adjustment. Land Use Policy 2021, 106, 105452. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Diewert, W.E.; de Haan, J.; Hendriks, R. Hedonic Regressions and the Decomposition of a House Price Index into Land and Structure Components. Econom. Rev. 2015, 34, 106–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Kuminoff, N.V.; Pope, J.C. The Value of Residential Land and Structures during the Great Housing Boom and Bust. Land. Econ. 2013, 89, 1–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Costello, G. Land price dynamics in a large Australian urban housing market. Int. J. Hous. Mark. Anal. 2014, 7, 42–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Clapp, J.M. The substitution of urban land for other inputs. J. Urban Econ. 1979, 6, 122–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Clapp, J.M. The elasticity of substitution for land: The effects of measurement errors. J. Urban Econ. 1980, 8, 255–263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Thorsnes, P. Consistent estimates of the elasticity of substitution between land and non-land inputs in the production of housing. J. Urban Econ. 1997, 42, 98–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Hicks, U.K. Can Land Be Assessed for Purposes of Site Value Taxation? In The Assessment of Land Value; Holland, D., Ed.; CABI: Wallingford, UK, 1970; pp. 9–24. [Google Scholar]
  36. Gyourko, J.; Saiz, A. Reinvestment in the housing stock: The role of construction costs and the supply side. J. Urban Econ. 2004, 55, 238–256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Canesi, R.; Marella, G. Residential construction costs: An Italian case study. Int. J. Appl. Eng. Res. 2017, 12, 2623–2634. [Google Scholar]
  38. Canesi, R.; Antoniucci, V.; Marella, G. Impact of socio-economic variables on property construction cost: Evidence from Italy. Int. J. Appl. Bus. Econ. Res. 2016, 14, 9407–9420. [Google Scholar]
  39. Bottero, M.; Caprioli, C.; Oppio, A. A Literature Review on Construction Costs Estimation: Hot Topics and Emerging Trends; Springer International Publishing: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  40. Nesticò, A.; De Mare, G.; Frusciante, B.; Dolores, L. Construction costs estimate for civil works. A model for the analysis during the preliminary stage of the project. In Computational Science and Its Applications—ICCSA 2017; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  41. San Juan, L. The housing supply and demand mismatch and its relationship with house prices. Econ. Bull. 2023, 9, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Ottensmann, J.R. Urban Sprawl, Land Values and the Density of Development. Land. Econ. 1977, 53, 389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Mittelbach, F.G.; Cunningham, P. Some Elements in Interregional Differences in Urban Land Values; University of California at Los Angeles, Real Estate Research Program, Reprint 31; University of California at Los Angeles: Los Angeles, CA, USA, 1964. [Google Scholar]
  44. Mathur, S. Impact of Urban Growth Boundary on Housing and Land Prices: Evidence from King County, Washington. Hous. Stud. 2014, 29, 128–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Capozza, D.R.; Helsley, R.W. The fundamentals of land prices and urban growth. J. Urban Econ. 1989, 26, 295–306. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Tsai, Y.H. Location-demand-based residential floor area ratio distribution method. Urban Stud. 2013, 51, 2685–2702. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Newburn, D.A.; Ferris, J.S. The effect of downzoning for managing residential development and density. Land Econ. 2016, 92, 220–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Gao, X.; Asami, Y.; Katsumata, W. Evaluating Land-Use Restrictions concerning the Floor Area Ratio of Lots. Environ. Plan. C Gov. Policy 2016, 24, 515–532. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Brueckner, J.K. Urban sprawl: Diagnosis and remedies. Int. Reg. Sci. Rev. 2000, 23, 160–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Brueckner, J.K.; Fu, S.; Gu, Y.; Zhang, J. Measuring the Stringency of Land-Use Regulation: The Case of China’s Building-Height Limits. SSRN Electron. J. 2021, 99, 1–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Han, W.; Zhang, X.; Zheng, X. Land use regulation and urban land value: Evidence from China. Land Use Policy 2020, 92, 104432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Taruttis, L.; Weber, C. Estimating the impact of energy efficiency on housing prices in Germany: Does regional disparity matter? Energy Econ. 2022, 105, 105750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Zhang, B.; Zhang, Y.; Li, J.; Song, Y.; Wang, Z. Does the energy efficiency of buildings bring price premiums? Evidence from urban micro-level energy data. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2023, 181, 113315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Walls, M.; Gerarden, T.; Palmer, K.; Bak, X.F. Is energy efficiency capitalized into home prices? Evidence from three U.S. cities. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2017, 82, 104–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Aroul, R.R.; Rodriguez, M. The Increasing Value of Green for Residential Real Estate. J. Sustain. Real Estate 2017, 9, 112–130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Pride, D.; Little, J.; Mueller-Stoffels, M. The value of residential energy efficiency in interior Alaska: A hedonic pricing analysis. Energy Policy 2018, 123, 450–460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Bruegge, C.; Carrión-Flores, C.; Pope, J.C. Does the housing market value energy efficient homes? Evidence from the energy star program. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2016, 57, 63–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Bloom, B.; Nobe, M.; Nobe, M. Valuing Green Home Designs: A Study of ENERGY STAR® Homes. J. Sustain. Real Estate 2011, 3, 109–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Zhang, L.; Li, Y.; Stephenson, R.; Ashuri, B. Valuation of energy efficient certificates in buildings. Energy Build. 2018, 158, 1226–1240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Copiello, S.; Donati, E. Is investing in energy efficiency worth it? Evidence for substantial price premiums but limited profitability in the housing sector. Energy Build. 2021, 251, 111371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Robinson, S.; McAllister, P. Heterogeneous Price Premiums in Sustainable Real Estate? An Investigation of the Relation between Value and Price Premiums. J. Sustain. Real Estate 2015, 7, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Cajias, M.; Piazolo, D. Green performs better: Energy efficiency and financial return on buildings. J. Corp. Real Estate 2013, 15, 53–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Bisello, A.; Antoniucci, V.; Marella, G. Measuring the price premium of energy efficiency: A two-step analysis in the Italian housing market. Energy Build. 2020, 208, 109670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Fuerst, F.; McAllister, P. Eco-labeling in commercial office markets: Do LEED and Energy Star offices obtain multiple premiums? Ecol. Econ. 2011, 70, 1220–1230. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Zhang, L.; Li, X.; Yu, J.; Yao, X. Toward cleaner production: What drives farmers to adopt eco-friendly agricultural production? J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 184, 550–558. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Lee, C.L.; Gumulya, N.; Bangura, M. The Role of Mandatory Building Efficiency Disclosure on Green Building Price Premium: Evidence from Australia. Buildings 2022, 12, 297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Galvin, W.F. Massachusetts Land Records. Available online: https://www.masslandrecords.com/ (accessed on 24 November 2023).
  68. Murphy, S.J.; Galvin, W.F. Registry of Deeds. Available online: https://www.masslandrecords.com/Suffolk (accessed on 24 November 2023).
  69. Kahn, M.E.; Kok, N. The capitalization of green labels in the California housing market. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2014, 47, 25–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Real property’s components. Source: authors.
Figure 1. Real property’s components. Source: authors.
Buildings 14 00045 g001
Figure 2. Details of the research project phases. Source: authors.
Figure 2. Details of the research project phases. Source: authors.
Buildings 14 00045 g002
Figure 3. Geo-localization of the land transactions per group (GroupB and GroupA). The height of the graph bars represents the LLi for each transaction. Source: authors.
Figure 3. Geo-localization of the land transactions per group (GroupB and GroupA). The height of the graph bars represents the LLi for each transaction. Source: authors.
Buildings 14 00045 g003
Figure 4. Land Transaction Price Index ( L I i ), Residential Transaction Price Index ( R I i ), and Construction Costs Index ( C I i ), base: 2012. Source: authors.
Figure 4. Land Transaction Price Index ( L I i ), Residential Transaction Price Index ( R I i ), and Construction Costs Index ( C I i ), base: 2012. Source: authors.
Buildings 14 00045 g004
Figure 5. RE market value distribution between Land Leverage (Green) and building leverage (blue) on a USD/SF of GFA between the two groups. Source: authors.
Figure 5. RE market value distribution between Land Leverage (Green) and building leverage (blue) on a USD/SF of GFA between the two groups. Source: authors.
Buildings 14 00045 g005
Figure 6. Boxplot of the annual variation for Land Leverage and Residential and Construction Costs Indexes ( L I i , R I i , and C I i ).
Figure 6. Boxplot of the annual variation for Land Leverage and Residential and Construction Costs Indexes ( L I i , R I i , and C I i ).
Buildings 14 00045 g006
Figure 7. ANOVA test results of the annual variation for Land Leverage and Residential and Construction Costs Indexes ( L I i , R I i , and C I i ).
Figure 7. ANOVA test results of the annual variation for Land Leverage and Residential and Construction Costs Indexes ( L I i , R I i , and C I i ).
Buildings 14 00045 g007
Figure 8. Land Leverage distribution. The dashed line divides the data into two groups (GroupB in green and GroupA in blue).
Figure 8. Land Leverage distribution. The dashed line divides the data into two groups (GroupB in green and GroupA in blue).
Buildings 14 00045 g008
Table 1. Descriptive statistics for LL GroupB, LL GroupA, residential prices (RP), and Construction Costs (CCs).
Table 1. Descriptive statistics for LL GroupB, LL GroupA, residential prices (RP), and Construction Costs (CCs).
VariableLLiLLi GroupBLLi GroupARP ($/SF)CC ($/SF)
Mean0.3550.3250.378581.742176.924
SE Mean0.0120.0180.01518.3641.133
Median0.3480.3200.357541.821179.300
StDev0.1270.1130.125368.19711.988
Minimum0.0970.0970.12730.246155.518
Maximum0.6400.5360.6402389.969198.541
Count112.00040.00072.000402.000112.000
Table 2. Two-sample t-test and CI: LLi GroupB; LLi GroupA.
Table 2. Two-sample t-test and CI: LLi GroupB; LLi GroupA.
NMeanStDevSE Mean
LLi GroupB400.32500.11300.0180
LLi GroupA720.37800.12500.0150
Difference = mu (LLi GroupB) − mu (LLi GroupA)
Estimate for difference: −0.052924
95% CI for difference: (−0.098884; −0.006964)
t-Test of difference = 0 (vs. not =): t-Value = −2.29; p-Value = 0.025; DF = 87
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Canesi, R.; Marella, G. Urban Density and Land Leverage: Market Value Breakdown for Energy-Efficient Assets. Buildings 2024, 14, 45. https://doi.org/10.3390/buildings14010045

AMA Style

Canesi R, Marella G. Urban Density and Land Leverage: Market Value Breakdown for Energy-Efficient Assets. Buildings. 2024; 14(1):45. https://doi.org/10.3390/buildings14010045

Chicago/Turabian Style

Canesi, Rubina, and Giuliano Marella. 2024. "Urban Density and Land Leverage: Market Value Breakdown for Energy-Efficient Assets" Buildings 14, no. 1: 45. https://doi.org/10.3390/buildings14010045

APA Style

Canesi, R., & Marella, G. (2024). Urban Density and Land Leverage: Market Value Breakdown for Energy-Efficient Assets. Buildings, 14(1), 45. https://doi.org/10.3390/buildings14010045

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop