1. Introduction
The COVID-19 pandemic, as a major exogenous shock, provides a unique theoretical perspective for revisiting the price formation mechanism, spatial equilibrium theory, and asset pricing models in the real estate market (Gormsen & Koijen, 2020 [
1]; Ye, 2016 [
2]; Mo et al., 2023 [
3]). Traditional real estate economics primarily focuses on the impact of fundamental factors like income and interest rates on market equilibrium (Giglio et al., 2021 [
4]; Gupta et al., 2010 [
5]; Preece et al., 2023 [
6]). However, under the impact of significant public health events, the role of external factors such as health risks and spatial distance lacks systematic theoretical analysis (Wei & Liu, 2022 [
7]; Caballero et al., 2021 [
8]). This theoretical gap not only limits our understanding of the current trends in the real estate market but also hinders the improvement and innovation of related policy tools (Zhou et al., 2021 [
9]; Yu et al., 2023 [
10]).
We define several key concepts that are fundamental to our theoretical framework. “Health risk premium” refers to the additional return required by investors to compensate for the perceived health-related risks during pandemic periods, which directly affects asset pricing through changes in risk preferences and liquidity constraints. “Spatial equilibrium” describes a state where accounting for differences in amenities, prices, and health risks across locations, households and firms have no incentive to relocate, leading to a stable distribution of economic activities and population across space. This equilibrium is significantly altered during pandemic periods as health risks create new trade-offs in residential and workplace location decisions. Understanding these concepts is essential for analyzing how pandemic shocks restructure real estate markets through changes in risk assessment, spatial preferences, and the adoption of remote work technologies.
The existing literature on the impact of sudden events on asset prices is mainly based on utility maximization frameworks, incorporating risk premium terms to describe market responses (Campbell & Cochrane, 1999 [
11]; Nazemi et al., 2024 [
12]). However, such models often treat risks as exogenously given and fail to capture the endogenous evolution of factors like health risks and population mobility (Pedersen, 2022 [
13]; Wan et al., 2021 [
14]). At the same time, new working models such as remote work challenge traditional spatial equilibrium theories regarding the relationship between work and housing (Ehlert, 2021 [
15]; Gao et al., 2023 [
16]; Øvrelid et al., 2019 [
17]). These theoretical dilemmas highlight the need for constructing a new analytical framework.
This paper aims to construct a unified theoretical framework based on general equilibrium theory by introducing elements such as a spatial transmission equation for health risks, distance-based labor market constraints for remote work, and liquidity preference in asset markets (Lorenz et al., 2023 [
18]; Song et al., 2021 [
19]; Rana et al., 2024 [
20]). Specifically, the theoretical innovations in this paper are reflected in three main aspects:
First, by combining the SIR model from epidemiology with the location choice theory in spatial economics, we establish an endogenous decision-making mechanism for health risks (Moscone et al., 2014 [
21]; Gu et al., 2020 [
22]). By solving the utility maximization problem of representative agents under infection risk constraints, we derive the equilibrium relationship between health risks, population density, and housing prices (Merton, 1973 [
23]; Kholodilin et al., 2020 [
24]). This theoretical extension enriches the microfoundations of traditional real estate pricing models.
Second, we construct a two-sector general equilibrium model that includes a remote work sector to analyze the impact of labor market structural changes on real estate spatial equilibrium (Alonso, 1964 [
25]; Mills, 1967 [
26]; Ch et al., 2021 [
27]). The model incorporates differentiated commuting cost functions to characterize the endogenous relationship between the proportion of remote work and location choice, providing a theoretical basis for explaining real estate market differentiation during the pandemic.
Third, based on liquidity preference theory, we establish an asset pricing framework that includes health risk premiums (Costola et al., 2023 [
28]; Shiller, 2020 [
29]). By incorporating the interaction between health risks and liquidity preferences, the model is able to explain certain paradoxical phenomena observed in the real estate market during the pandemic, such as price deviations from fundamentals in some regions.
The establishment of this theoretical framework not only helps us gain deeper insights into the operational patterns of the real estate market under pandemic shocks but also provides a theoretical foundation for designing related policy tools (Chernick et al., 2023 [
30]; de La Paz et al., 2023 [
31]; Stieglitz et al., 2013 [
32]). Our analysis suggests that under significant public health events, traditional demand management policies may need to be differentially adjusted based on the spatial distribution characteristics of health risks (He et al., 2020 [
33]; Benhabib et al., 2011 [
34]). At the same time, the development of new employment models such as remote work requires policymakers to adopt more forward-looking measures in spatial planning and real estate regulation (Glaeser et al., 2005 [
4]; Sun et al., 2023 [
35]).
2. Literature Review
The development of health risks and asset pricing theory can be traced back to traditional asset pricing models. Early research focused primarily on how to incorporate external risk factors into pricing models, providing a fundamental analytical framework for understanding the impact of health risks on asset prices (Merton, 1973 [
23]; Campbell & Cochrane, 1999 [
11]). In the context of pandemics, academic discussions have delved deeper into the unique characteristics of health risks and their pricing effects. A large body of empirical research has found that health risks not only influence market expectations but also significantly heighten investors’ attention to tail risks.
Recent research has made important breakthroughs in model frameworks, particularly in attempting to integrate epidemiological models with asset pricing theory. In particular, scholars have found that the spatial diffusion characteristics of health risks can effectively explain the cross-sectional differences in asset prices when embedding the SIR model into a general equilibrium framework. At the same time, behavioral finance perspectives have provided new insights into the impact of health risks on investor behavior. These studies suggest that health risks not only alter investors’ risk preferences but also influence their investment decisions through attention allocation mechanisms (Kang et al., 2021 [
36]; Ataullah et al., 2022 [
37]; Alam et al., 2021 [
38]; Walby et al., 2016 [
39]).
In the area of panic sentiment contagion, recent scholars have achieved fruitful results through diverse research methods. The rise in social media has provided a new perspective for studying market sentiment, with studies showing that the information dissemination mechanism significantly accelerates the market panic spread (Hirshleifer et al., 2021 [
40]; Lim et al., 2021 [
41]). Notably, during crises, the spatial correlation of market sentiment exhibits a significant strengthening trend. Some pioneering studies have explored the physiological basis of panic emotions from a neuroscience perspective, finding that health risk-related news reports trigger risk-averse behavior among investors (Kang et al., 2020 [
42]). These findings provide a deeper understanding of the formation mechanisms of market sentiment.
In terms of identifying the impact of sentiment contagion on asset prices, recent studies have adopted more rigorous empirical strategies. By comparing similar regions with different social network connectivity, researchers found that sentiment contagion explained a significant portion of housing price synchronization during the pandemic (Ho et al., 2024 [
43]; Jiang et al., 2024 [
44]). More in-depth theoretical studies have introduced social learning theory into asset pricing models, analyzing the diffusion mechanism of panic emotions under incomplete information environments and constructing general equilibrium models with heterogeneous beliefs to explain the dynamic evolution of market participants’ expectations (Bikhchandani et al., 2024 [
45]; Brunnermeier et al., 2021 [
46]).
The development of spatial economics theory reflects academia’s ongoing attention to emerging technological changes. With the widespread adoption of remote work technology, researchers have expanded traditional monocentric city models (Ehlert, 2021 [
15]; Haefner et al., 2020 [
47]). Empirical studies using big data methods have recorded the spatial restructuring of office activities during the pandemic, finding significant differentiation in housing prices between commercial and residential areas (Yang et al., 2023 [
48]). In cities with higher remote work friendliness, suburban housing prices exhibited more pronounced appreciation trends (Choudhury et al., 2021 [
49]; Henderson et al., 2021 [
50]).
In the study of policy transmission mechanisms, the recent literature has increasingly focused on the spatial heterogeneity characteristics. Cross-regional studies have found that the impact of interest rate changes on housing prices varies significantly by region, mainly due to differences in the development levels of local financial markets (Gupta et al., 2010 [
5]; Liu et al., 2022 [
51]). Research on fiscal policy has focused on comparing the effects of different policy tools, finding that infrastructure investment has stronger spatial spillover effects compared to tax incentives (Deng et al., 2023 [
52]; Lima, 2020 [
53]). Recent systematic reviews and empirical studies further support these findings, with Di Liddo et al. (2023) [
54] documenting emerging trends in real estate market dynamics following COVID-19 and Holmgren Bentzer (2024) [
55] providing evidence on the persistent transformation of office vacancy patterns in Stockholm as an indicator of the “new normal” in commercial real estate markets.
At the policy coordination level, scholars have paid more attention to the interaction between monetary and fiscal policies. By constructing a DSGE model with heterogeneous agents, studies have found that the optimal policy mix varies according to the spatial characteristics of income distribution (Baccini et al., 2024 [
56]; Tian et al., 2017 [
57]). Methodological innovations, such as machine learning methods and spatial effect decomposition using high-dimensional panel data, have provided new tools for identifying policy effects (Calainho et al., 2024 [
58]; Jarrow et al., 2022 [
41]).
Firstly, while some research has started to focus on the impact of health risks on asset pricing, most studies still treat the pandemic shock as an exogenous variable, neglecting the endogenous interactions between health risks, market sentiment, and spatial structure. Although empirical studies have documented the pricing effects of health risks, they have failed to reveal the micro-mechanisms of risk transmission (He & Xia, 2020 [
59]). Secondly, regarding the spatial contagion characteristics of panic sentiment, existing studies tend to focus on correlation analysis using network data, lacking an in-depth understanding of the contagion mechanism (Meyfroidt et al., 2022 [
60]). Thirdly, research on the impact of remote work on spatial structure has rarely considered the moderating effect of health risks, making it difficult to fully explain the asymmetric adjustment phenomena observed during the pandemic. Finally, in exploring the spatial heterogeneity of policy effects, existing research often overlooks the impact of health risk distribution on policy transmission.
Based on the above understanding, this paper proposes a unified theoretical framework with the following three major innovations: First, by integrating the SIR model with asset pricing theory and introducing a dynamic health risk equation with a spatial diffusion term, it enables the endogenous treatment of the risk transmission mechanism. This innovation overcomes the limitation of existing research that treats the pandemic shock as an exogenous impact, allowing the model to better explain the dynamic interaction between risks and prices (Lim et al., 2021 [
61]). Second, this paper constructs a behavioral finance model that considers the spatial contagion of panic sentiment, using a social network structure to design an emotion diffusion equation. This provides new explanations for understanding irrational market responses during the pandemic. Third, it introduces health risk constraints into the classic spatial equilibrium framework, analyzing how the distribution of risks influences remote work decisions and location choices. This enriches the traditional theory and reveals the interactive effects of technological change and health risks in reshaping urban spatial structure (Muth, 1969 [
62]).
The theoretical scope of this study focuses primarily on the dynamic mechanisms of real estate markets under pandemic conditions, particularly by integrating epidemiological models with spatial economics principles to explore the endogenous interactions among health risks, remote work, and asset pricing. The research framework encompasses not only micro-level individual decision-making behaviors but also extends to macro-policy transmission and spatial equilibrium analysis, providing a comprehensive theoretical explanation system for the real estate market in the post-pandemic era. The application range of this framework includes, but is not limited to, urban planning policy formulation, real estate regulatory measure evaluation, and macroeconomic policy effect analysis.
Figure 1 presents the theoretical framework constructed in this paper and its underlying mechanisms. The framework centers on the equilibrium of the real estate market and depicts the market operation mechanism under pandemic impact through three transmission levels. At the upper level, the SIR transmission model
describes the spatial diffusion process of health risks, which affects population density
, thereby altering the remote work equilibrium
and labor market structure
. At the central level, these factors jointly determine the equilibrium price
of the real estate market, considering not only traditional income and commuting costs but also the discounting effect of health risks. At the lower level, the model outlines the triple feedback channels in the market: first, through the risk premium
, which affects asset pricing; second, through policy transmission
, which adjusts market operations; and third, through market sentiment
and social welfare
, reflecting the overall equilibrium state of the market. This theoretical framework not only unifies the mechanisms in the existing literature but also reveals the endogenous interactions between health risks, spatial structure, and market behavior, providing a systematic analytical tool for understanding the dynamics of the real estate market under pandemic impact. Notably, this framework highlights the following three innovative features: First, by combining the SIR model with spatial economics, it enables the endogenous treatment of the health risk transmission mechanism. Second, by introducing a differentiated commuting cost function, it portrays the reshaping effects of remote work on spatial structure. Finally, through constructing an asset pricing framework that includes health risk premiums, it reveals how health-related uncertainties reshape asset valuation and investor behavior.
4. Model Equilibrium Analysis and Theoretical Implications
Based on the above theoretical framework, this section will delve into the equilibrium characteristics of the model and its underlying policy implications, aiming to reveal the profound impacts of the pandemic on the real estate market and the critical role played by government policies. First, we examine the existence and uniqueness of the model equilibrium, given the exogenous parameter set . The model equilibrium must simultaneously satisfy the utility maximization of the representative household, the profit maximization of developers, labor market clearing, spatial equilibrium, and the health risk steady state. Under basic assumptions such as the strict concavity of the utility function, diminishing returns to scale of the production function, and the continuity and boundedness of the spatial weight kernel function, we can construct the mapping from the bounded closed convex set , which contains all possible equilibrium variable combinations, to itself. By applying the Banach Fixed Point Theorem or the Brouwer–Tychonoff Fixed Point Theorem, we can prove the existence of an equilibrium solution. Furthermore, if the utility and production functions satisfy strict concavity, then the mapping possesses contraction properties, ensuring the uniqueness of the equilibrium solution according to the Contraction Mapping Theorem. This result suggests that, even in the context of pandemic shocks, the real estate market still has endogenous stabilization mechanisms that can clear the market and ensure the effective allocation of resources.
Based on the above theoretical framework, this section will further explore the equilibrium characteristics of the model and its underlying policy implications, aiming to reveal the profound impacts of the pandemic on the real estate market and the key role played by government policies. First, we will focus on the existence and uniqueness of the model equilibrium, which is based on the exogenous parameter set . According to the model setup, achieving an equilibrium solution requires satisfying a series of key conditions, including the utility maximization of the representative household, the profit maximization of developers, labor market clearing, spatial equilibrium, and the steady state of health risks. These conditions reflect the interactions of various economic agents in the market and ensure that, even when considering the pandemic shock, the market can still achieve an effective allocation of resources.
For the mathematical proof, we first analyze the properties of the utility function. Assuming the utility function is strictly concave, this guarantees that the representative household’s optimization problem has a unique solution. Specifically, the representative household will choose the optimal residential location and consumption structure based on the spatial structure, health risks, and labor market conditions. Next, the assumption of diminishing returns to scale in the production function ensures the optimal allocation of resources between different locations, further facilitating the existence of the equilibrium solution. The continuity and boundedness of the spatial weight kernel function ensure that the interregional interactions are mathematically manageable, which is crucial for simulating the spatial propagation of health risks.
Based on these assumptions, we define the feasible solution region
, which contains all possible equilibrium variables. Specifically, the space
is a set composed of the following variables:
These variables represent the price , consumption of general goods , consumption of housing services , health risk level , and proportion of remote work in each region. Due to the strict concavity of the utility function and the diminishing returns to scale of the production function, we can prove that is a bounded closed convex set. This conclusion guarantees that all equilibrium solutions lie within this range and ensures that no unrealistic solutions will emerge during numerical solutions. Next, we construct the mapping , which maps any element of space to the equilibrium solution in the next period. The mapping can be decomposed into several component functions, each corresponding to different economic behaviors and market constraints. Specifically, the mapping includes the following component functions:
: Calculates the new equilibrium price based on the spatial equilibrium condition.
: Updates consumption based on the household’s budget constraint.
: Updates housing service consumption based on the household’s utility maximization problem.
: Updates the risk level based on the health risk dynamic equation.
: Calculates the remote work ratio based on the labor market equilibrium condition.
These component functions reflect the various economic interactions in the model and update the equilibrium variables at each time step. Specifically, adjusts the price based on the spatial equilibrium condition, while depends on the dynamic equation for the propagation of health risks to adjust the risk levels. These dynamic rules reflect the mutual influence between the real estate market and the labor market under pandemic shocks and help describe how the market achieves optimal resource allocation across different regions.
For the mapping
, we can prove that it satisfies the contraction mapping condition, i.e., there exists a constant
such that for any
, we have
This contraction property arises from the boundedness of the marginal effects between each variable in the equilibrium process. Specifically, for each region , the marginal changes between price, consumption, housing service, health risk, and the remote work ratio are all bounded within a certain range, ensuring the contraction property of the mapping . This contraction property indicates that with multiple iterations, the model will gradually converge to a stable equilibrium solution.
According to the Contraction Mapping Theorem (Banach Fixed Point Theorem), the mapping
has a unique fixed point
, i.e., there exists a unique equilibrium solution such that
This result proves that, even under the impact of the pandemic, the real estate market can still achieve market clearing and that market resources will be effectively allocated under various economic parameter constraints. Furthermore, this result suggests that regardless of how strong the pandemic shock is, the market has endogenous stabilization mechanisms that can adjust prices and demand to ensure market equilibrium.
Additionally, we emphasize several key assumptions and conclusions in the model. First, the strict concavity of the utility function ensures that the representative household can make rational choices in response to health risks and labor market structure. Second, the diminishing returns to scale in the production function and the boundedness of the spatial weight kernel function ensure that interregional interactions are manageable and do not lead to excessive market fluctuations. Finally, the contraction property of the mapping
guarantees the uniqueness of the equilibrium solution and provides a solid theoretical foundation for subsequent numerical simulations. To further illustrate the dynamic convergence toward equilibrium described by our model,
Figure 5 depicts the iterative convergence process of housing prices across different risk-level regions under pandemic shocks, clearly confirming the theoretical stability discussed above.
From the diagram, we observe that the blue solid line represents the price trajectory of low-risk areas, which shows a relatively smooth downward trend. The red dashed line indicates the price fluctuations in high-risk areas, which initially experience larger adjustments but stabilize afterward. The green line represents the price adjustments in medium-risk areas, which fall between the other two cases. These empirical observations strongly support the theoretical prediction that the market has an endogenous stabilizing mechanism.
Next, through comparative static analysis, we reveal the mechanism by which key parameters affect equilibrium. For example, the impact of the local transmission coefficient
on equilibrium can be expressed as
This result suggests that as the health risk transmission coefficient increases, housing prices decline due to the direct reduction in residents’ willingness to pay and the indirect effects on the spatial distribution of population density. This theoretical prediction aligns with the phenomenon of significant price adjustments in high-risk areas during the pandemic, confirming the applicability of the model in real-world scenarios.
To validate our theoretical propositions empirically,
Figure 6 presents comprehensive evidence from Chinese housing markets that strongly supports our model’s predictions. The top panel illustrates housing price indices across different tiers of Chinese cities from 2010 to 2024, with the vertical red dashed line marking the COVID-19 outbreak. This time series visualization reveals a notable reduction in price volatility post pandemic compared to previous market fluctuations in 2016–2017, consistent with our dynamic stability analysis that predicted market self-adjustment mechanisms would gradually stabilize prices after the initial shock. The bottom left panel demonstrates the spatial heterogeneity of housing price changes, presenting box plots that clearly show high-risk areas experienced more pronounced price adjustments, particularly in first-tier and second-tier cities. This empirical pattern precisely confirms our comparative static analysis, which predicted that the health risk transmission coefficient (β) would negatively impact equilibrium prices through both direct willingness-to-pay and indirect population density channels. The bottom right panel quantifies housing price volatility between pre-COVID and post-COVID periods across city tiers, revealing that post-pandemic volatility consistently decreased to approximately 45–50% of pre-pandemic levels. This systematic volatility reduction aligns with our theoretical framework’s prediction that health risk awareness creates a new equilibrium with different market response characteristics to exogenous shocks. Collectively, these empirical findings provide robust validation for our theoretical model, demonstrating its effectiveness in explaining real-world market dynamics during significant public health events.
The risk premium curve clearly demonstrates the non-linear relationship between risk premium and the health risk level, with the horizontal axis representing the health risk level and the vertical axis showing the risk premium. The curve exhibits a distinct non-linear feature, indicating that high-risk areas face higher risk premiums. This non-linear relationship can be described by
where
reflects the acceleration effect of risk.
At the same time, analyzing the impact of advancements in remote work technology (i.e., the increase in
) on equilibrium reveals how technological progress alters labor market structures and subsequently affects urban spatial configurations. Specifically, from the model, we can derive the following results:
where
represents the remote work ratio at location
is the housing price,
is the wage level,
represents housing service consumption,
is certain costs or tax rates, and
is the commuting distance at location
. The above equation reflects that as
increases, the remote work ratio
grows, thereby reducing dependence on commuting distance. This makes more remote areas, with higher commuting costs, attractive to residents, and the impact on housing prices is expressed as follows: as the remote work ratio increases, housing prices
begin to decrease, especially in traditional urban core areas, because the demand spillover effect is dispersed to peripheral areas.
Specifically, with technological progress, an increasing number of residents can choose to live in suburban areas or the outskirts of cities without being constrained by commuting time. This change manifests in two aspects: first, remote work technology makes living in suburban areas feasible, where housing costs are relatively lower, and modern work arrangements can still be enjoyed, and second, the demand for commuting convenience in urban centers decreases, leading to reduced housing demand in these areas, which in turn puts downward pressure on prices. Therefore, technological progress, by increasing the proportion of remote work, reduces dependence on commuting convenience, which influences residential location choices and the formation of housing prices. This result is of great significance in explaining the rise in suburban housing prices during the pandemic. With the rapid development of remote work technology, especially during the pandemic, residents no longer needed to commute long distances daily. Especially during the pandemic, residents no longer needed to commute long distances daily. This led many to move from expensive urban centers to relatively cheaper suburban or peripheral areas, further boosting the demand for suburban housing. This process highlights the critical role of technological progress in reshaping labor market structures and spatial resource allocation, providing valuable insights for future urban planning and housing policies. As the labor market gradually detaches from traditional geographical constraints, the rise in suburban housing prices reflects not only the diversification of residents’ living choices but also signals significant changes in the geographic distribution of labor demand.
In dynamic characteristic analysis, consider the linearized system around the equilibrium point:
where the Jacobian matrix
is
By analyzing the eigenvalues of this matrix, we derive the characteristic equation
, i.e.,
which gives two eigenvalues:
Based on these eigenvalues, we can further analyze the stability of the system. When and , both eigenvalues are negative real numbers, and the system exhibits local asymptotic stability. Specifically, if , that is, the local transmission rate is less than the cross-region suppression effect, the equilibrium point is locally stable.
Furthermore, we construct a Lyapunov function:
where
is positive. We then compute the derivative of the Lyapunov function along the system trajectory
:
Substituting the linearized system’s equations, we obtain
When and is chosen as specified, we obtain for all nonequilibrium points. Therefore, based on Lyapunov stability theory, under these parameter conditions, the system has global asymptotic stability.
This means that even in the presence of external shocks such as the pandemic, the market will automatically converge to an equilibrium state through endogenous adjustment mechanisms. This conclusion provides a solid theoretical basis for policymakers, demonstrating the necessity and effectiveness of policy interventions in promoting market stability.
The time series plot in the figure also provides direct empirical support for this conclusion. The vertical axis represents the degree of deviation from equilibrium, and the horizontal axis represents time. The curve shows clear signs of gradual convergence, validating the model’s stability prediction. However, we also note that when the system parameters approach the critical condition , the convergence speed noticeably slows down.
This reflects the non-linear characteristics of the market adjustment process. This phenomenon also provides valuable reference for subsequent policy adjustments and market predictions. Policy effect analysis further reveals the transmission mechanisms of monetary and fiscal policies at different health risk levels. Specifically, the impact of interest rate adjustments on housing prices can be expressed as
This indicates that an increase in interest rates will lead to a decrease in housing prices, with the impact level depending on the health risk level
. This conclusion provides important guidance for monetary policy formulation during the pandemic, especially in high-risk areas where more aggressive policy support may be needed to stabilize the real estate market. At the same time, the effects of fiscal policy show significant spatial heterogeneity, i.e.,
where
is a function dependent on location characteristics. This means that a uniform fiscal policy may produce different effects across regions, requiring policymakers to fully consider regional heterogeneity when designing fiscal measures. The three-dimensional diagram strongly supports this argument, where the X-axis represents spatial distance, the Y-axis shows health risk levels, and the
Z-axis reflects policy effects. The color gradient clearly illustrates the spatial differences in policy effects. We can observe that the policy effects indeed diminish as the distance increases and are more pronounced in high-risk areas. Differentiated policy measures should be adopted for regions with varying risk levels and stages of development to achieve more efficient resource allocation and maximize social welfare.
From the perspective of welfare economics, if we define the social welfare function as
where
represents the social cost of health risks, the optimal policy combination can be obtained by solving the social planner’s problem:
This provides a theoretical benchmark for policy design, emphasizing the necessity of balancing the control of health risks and maintaining economic vitality. Specifically, the optimal policy should find a balance between reducing the social costs of health risks and promoting economic growth. This theoretical framework helps explain the different regulatory measures adopted by various countries during the pandemic. Some regions prioritize controlling health risks and implement strict preventive measures to reduce the impact of the pandemic on public health, while others focus more on the continuity of economic activities and adopt relatively relaxed policies to maintain economic vitality. The model suggests that these policy differences may arise from different regions assigning different weights to health risks and economic losses in the social welfare function, reflecting value judgments and priorities in policymaking.
Overall, the above analysis provides a systematic theoretical framework for understanding the dynamics of the real estate market under the pandemic shock and the corresponding policy choices. The model not only reveals the impact mechanisms of new factors such as health risks and remote work on market equilibrium but also explores the role of government policies in stabilizing markets and promoting economic recovery. In particular, the analysis emphasizes the spatial heterogeneity of policy effects, which requires policymakers to consider regional characteristics fully when designing regulatory measures, adopting targeted and differentiated policy combinations to achieve more efficient resource allocation and maximize social welfare. At the same time, the model highlights the importance of the market’s own adjustment mechanisms, suggesting that policy interventions should respect market rules and provide moderate support rather than excessive interference, thus fostering the market’s self-regulation ability and achieving long-term stability and sustainable development.
5. Model Extension and Policy Implications
In this section, we further explore the impact of introducing credit constraints on real estate market equilibrium. Based on the model established in the previous sections, we incorporate credit constraints into the budget constraint and derive the new equilibrium housing price expression. Credit constraints refer to the limitations on the amount of money a household can borrow when purchasing a home, typically defined as a certain proportion of their disposable income. The introduction of this constraint alters household consumption and housing choices, subsequently impacting the market equilibrium housing price.
First, starting from the baseline model where credit constraints are not included, the household utility maximization problem can be expressed as
Meanwhile, the household’s budget constraint is
where
is the amount of housing chosen by the household,
is the consumption,
is the housing price,
is household income,
is the tax rate,
is the commuting distance,
is the proportion of remote work, and
is the weight of health risk.
When we introduce the credit constraint into the model, the household’s budget constraint changes. Specifically, the household’s housing expenditure can no longer exceed a certain proportion of their income. The credit constraint is represented as
where
is the credit constraint coefficient, reflecting the household’s borrowing capacity when purchasing a home. This constraint implies that in a more tightened credit policy environment, the household’s ability to purchase a home is restricted, thereby affecting the equilibrium housing price. At this point, the household’s optimization problem becomes
subject to the following budget and credit constraint:
To solve this optimization problem, we construct the Lagrange function and apply Kuhn–Tucker conditions. The Lagrange function is
where
and
are the Lagrange multipliers for the budget and credit constraints, respectively.
Under Kuhn–Tucker conditions, if the credit constraint is not binding (i.e.,
), the solution is the same as in the baseline model, and the equilibrium housing price is
However, if the credit constraint is binding (
), the housing price is influenced by the credit constraint, and the household’s housing expenditure will be limited by the credit constraint:
After rearranging, the new equilibrium housing price expression is
Thus, the effect of the credit constraint on the equilibrium housing price depends on the tightness of the credit constraint. When the credit constraint is more relaxed, the equilibrium housing price is primarily determined by the household’s fundamental factors (such as income, commuting distance, remote work ratio, etc.). When the credit constraint is more stringent, housing prices are constrained by the household’s borrowing capacity, and therefore, housing prices are significantly affected by changes in credit policies. To combine both cases, we can write the final equilibrium housing price expression as
This result reveals the impact of credit constraints on equilibrium housing prices under different market conditions. Specifically, when credit constraints are more relaxed, housing prices are more influenced by fundamental factors, whereas when credit constraints are more stringent, housing prices are constrained by the household’s borrowing capacity. This finding is significant for understanding the role of credit policies under different market conditions, especially in uncertain environments such as during a pandemic. Changes in credit constraints can have a significant impact on the real estate market, providing a theoretical basis for policymakers to develop more flexible financial policies.
Furthermore, we find that the introduction of credit constraints not only changes the mechanism of equilibrium housing price formation but may also influence regional differences in the real estate market. Specifically, when credit constraints are more stringent, housing prices in certain regions may be more constrained, particularly in high-risk areas. In these areas, due to the impact of health risks, residents’ location choices and consumption decisions will undergo structural changes, further altering market equilibrium. This result suggests that the effects of credit policies may differ across regions, and policymakers should design differentiated credit policies based on the specific circumstances of each region.
Based on the theoretical framework established earlier, this section further expands the model’s application scope and delves into its policy implications to comprehensively reveal the profound impact of the pandemic on the real estate market and related economic sectors. First, we consider the impact of credit market constraints on real estate market equilibrium. In the baseline model, we introduce the credit constraint
, meaning that household housing expenditure cannot exceed a certain proportion of their income, expressed as
. The introduction of this constraint modifies the equilibrium housing price expression to
. Through comparative static analysis, we find that
indicating that the relaxation of credit constraints will drive housing prices higher, but this effect may vary significantly across regions. In particular, when health risks are higher, the effect of credit policy may be diminished, i.e.,
This conclusion has important implications for understanding the differences in the effects of monetary policy across countries during the pandemic, reflecting the heterogeneous response of credit markets under different health risk scenarios, further emphasizing the need for policymakers to account for regional health risk differences and implement more refined financial policy adjustments.
Next, we expand the model to consider the heterogeneity of real estate developers, assuming that developers have different marginal cost functions
, where
and
represent the cost characteristics and economies of scale for different developers. Under this setting, the developer’s optimization problem becomes
Solving the first-order condition gives
This extension allows the model to explain differences in real estate supply elasticity across regions during the pandemic and reveals the behavior differences in developers under different market conditions. Furthermore, if developers are subject to financing constraints
, their investment decisions will be additionally restricted, i.e.,
This setting helps to understand the liquidity difficulties faced by some developers during the pandemic and reflects the regulatory role of financial markets in real estate supply under uncertain environments, further enriching the model’s practical applicability.
Third, we extend the model to a multi-period framework to analyze the role of expectations. Let
represent the value function at time
with the state
. The dynamic programming equation is expressed as
By solving this equation numerically, we can analyze the impact of expectations on market equilibrium. Specifically, when the market expects that health risks will persist, residents’ location choices and consumption decisions undergo structural changes, explaining the deep adjustments in real estate markets in certain regions during the pandemic. Additionally, the multi-period model introduces the time dimension, allowing us to capture path dependence and lag effects in dynamic decision making, thereby more accurately reflecting the evolution of the market under long-term uncertainty.
The policy implications of the model mainly manifest in the following aspects. First, regarding monetary policy, considering the significant impact of health risks on policy transmission, central banks should adopt more flexible and differentiated policies. Specifically, for regions with high health risks, more substantial credit support may be needed to alleviate the negative impact of credit constraints on housing prices and economic activity; whereas, for regions with lower risks, gradual normalization management could be adopted to avoid the asset bubble risks caused by excessive stimulus. This policy recommendation is based on financial stability theory, emphasizing the flexibility and targeting of financial policies in uncertain environments.
Second, fiscal policy should focus more on spatial coordination. The model shows that uniform fiscal stimulus policies may have different effects across regions, requiring policymakers to fully consider regional heterogeneity and design more targeted support measures. For example, in regions severely affected by the pandemic, targeted support can be provided through special bonds to quickly alleviate local economic pressure; whereas in regions that have recovered economically, fiscal policies can be moderately tightened to prevent potential risks and overheating. This recommendation draws on spatial imbalance theory in regional economics and emphasizes the important role of fiscal policy in promoting regional coordinated development.
In real estate regulation policy, the model emphasizes the importance of expectations management. From the expression of , it is clear that market expectations directly influence the current equilibrium state. This means that policymakers need to guide market expectations through clear and consistent policy signals to avoid market volatility caused by expectation deviations. Especially in the context of repeated pandemics, it is essential to pay attention to policy continuity and predictability to enhance market confidence and stability. Furthermore, considering the heterogeneity of developers, real estate relief policies should distinguish between the actual situations of different enterprises, offering targeted support to firms facing temporary difficulties but with growth prospects, rather than applying blanket rescue measures. This aligns with the principle of the differentiated treatment of heterogeneous firms in corporate behavior theory.
In addition, the model also reveals new ideas for urban planning policies. The equilibrium expression of remote work ratio shows that technological progress is reshaping the relationship between work and housing, which requires urban planning to focus more on functional mixing and flexible adaptation. Specifically, in new infrastructure investment, the impact of new work patterns such as remote work on infrastructure needs should be fully considered. For example, enhancing digital upgrades to community facilities, improving connections between urban clusters, and providing residents with more diverse housing options not only improves the livability of cities but also promotes diversified economic development, aligning with the demand for multi-functional urban areas in modern urban economics.
The proliferation of remote work necessitates a fundamental recalibration of urban planning frameworks. We develop a spatio-temporal optimization model that captures the evolving relationship between work arrangements and urban morphology. Let us define the spatial planning efficiency function
where
represents the vector of zoning designations across locations and
captures the spatial distribution of remote work ratios:
where
represents the local utility derived from zoning designation
given remote work ratio
, while the second term captures spatial coherence costs with
measuring the connectivity between locations
and
, and
controlling the strength of spatial consistency preferences.
The optimal zoning configuration
must satisfy the first-order condition:
This equilibrium condition reveals a critical insight: as increases, the optimal zoning designation shifts from strict segregation toward mixed-use developments. Specifically, when exceeds a threshold , the solution bifurcates from the traditional monocentric configuration to a polycentric arrangement with multiple functional nodes.
For infrastructure planning, we propose a dynamic network investment model that accommodates the shifting mobility patterns under remote work. The objective function for infrastructure planners becomes
subject to budget constraint
, where
represents infrastructure investment between locations
and
is the social benefit function, and
is the cost function. Critically,
depends on remote work ratios in both origin and destination locations, with
, indicating diminishing marginal returns to traditional commuting infrastructure as remote work increases.
For housing policy evolution, we characterize the optimal inclusionary zoning requirement
as
where
is the baseline requirement,
captures how remote work reduces affordability pressures, and the integral term represents policy diffusion across jurisdictions with spatial weights
.
These analytical frameworks collectively demonstrate that optimal urban policy in the post-pandemic era must transition from rigid Euclidean zoning toward form-based codes accommodating functional hybridization, redirect infrastructure investments from radial commuting networks toward distributed digital connectivity nodes, and evolve housing policies to address the spatial redistribution of affordability pressures catalyzed by remote work flexibility. Finally, from the perspective of risk management, the model suggests that preventing systemic risks requires multi-level policy coordination. The spatial transmission equation of health risks reveals that risks have significant externalities, which necessitate a full consideration of cross-regional coordination when formulating policies. For example, in real estate financial risk prevention, differentiated risk management measures should be formulated based on health risk levels in different regions, and a cross-regional risk coordination mechanism should be established, which emphasizes diversification and synergy in systemic risk management theory. Additionally, by establishing cross-regional risk-sharing mechanisms and emergency response systems, the risk of regional risk spillover can be effectively reduced, enhancing the resilience and stability of the overall economic system.
In conclusion, through the multi-dimensional extension of the model, we have not only enriched the theoretical framework but also provided more detailed and targeted policy recommendations. The introduction of credit market constraints reveals the important role of financial policies in the real estate market, the consideration of developer heterogeneity emphasizes the diversity and dynamics of the market supply side, and the analysis of expectations in the multi-period framework highlights the time dependency and dynamic adjustment processes of market behavior. These extensions not only enhance the model’s practical applicability but also provide a more comprehensive and in-depth theoretical basis for understanding the impact of the pandemic on the real estate market and related economic sectors. In terms of policy implications, the recommendations on monetary policy, fiscal policy, real estate regulation, and urban planning are all based on the model’s theoretical derivation and empirical analysis, aiming to help policymakers adopt more scientific and effective responses in the face of a pandemic and other uncertain shocks, achieving the dual goals of economic stability and social welfare.
6. Conclusions and Future Directions
The theoretical framework constructed in this study clearly defines its application scope: on the one hand, it provides tools for analyzing the microeconomic mechanisms of real estate markets under pandemic shocks, elucidating how health risks, remote work proportions, and housing preferences collectively shape market equilibrium, and on the other hand, it also provides theoretical support for macroeconomic policy formulation, particularly explaining the heterogeneous transmission effects of monetary and fiscal policies across different spatial regions. The innovative aspect of this theoretical scope lies in combining traditional spatial economics with epidemiological models, revealing the endogenous impact mechanisms of health risk distribution on asset pricing.
This study builds a theoretical framework that integrates health risks, remote work, and spatial equilibrium to deeply analyze the operational mechanisms of the real estate market under the impact of significant public health events and the corresponding policy implications. Our research shows that the pandemic influences real estate market equilibrium through multiple channels, including changes in household utility functions, the restructuring of the labor market, and adjustments in location choices. In the baseline model, we demonstrate the existence and uniqueness of equilibrium solutions and, by introducing the spatial transmission equation for health risks, reveal the endogenous evolution process of risks. Furthermore, by constructing a two-sector equilibrium model that includes the remote work sector, we analyze the impact of changes in the labor market structure on real estate spatial equilibrium. The model’s extension analysis shows that factors such as credit constraints, developer heterogeneity, and the dynamic evolution of expectations all significantly affect the path to achieving market equilibrium.
Comparative static analysis reveals the mechanisms through which key parameters influence equilibrium. Specifically, the increase in the local transmission coefficient affects housing prices through two channels: the direct channel, which lowers the willingness to pay due to the rise in risks, and the indirect channel, which influences housing prices by altering the spatial distribution of population density. At the same time, advancements in remote work technology change the work–housing relationship and, in turn, reshape the spatial equilibrium. Dynamic analysis shows that under certain parameter conditions, the market equilibrium exhibits asymptotic stability, providing a theoretical foundation for understanding the market’s self-adjustment mechanism. Policy effect analysis points out that the transmission effects of monetary and fiscal policies exhibit significant spatial heterogeneity, requiring more attention to regional differences and the adoption of more targeted regulatory measures in policy formulation.
This study’s theoretical innovations are mainly reflected in three aspects: First, by combining the SIR model from epidemiology with location theory in spatial economics, it depicts for the first time the endogenous decision-making mechanism of health risks at the theoretical level. Second, by constructing a general equilibrium framework that includes remote work, it reveals the impact of technological change on the spatial structure of the real estate market. Third, based on a multi-period dynamic model, this study analyzes the crucial role of expectations in the market adjustment process. These theoretical breakthroughs not only enrich the analytical tools in real estate economics but also provide a theoretical basis for the development of related policies.
Looking ahead, several areas deserve further exploration. First, in terms of theory, it would be beneficial to introduce behavioral economics paradigms into the existing framework to analyze the impact of bounded rationality and cognitive biases on market equilibrium. Particularly, in the perception of health risks, individuals’ overreaction or underreaction may lead to irrational market fluctuations. Second, the model could be expanded to incorporate more complex spatial structures, such as considering equilibrium characteristics in multi-center urban systems or using network theory to analyze the spatial transmission patterns of risks. Third, in policy research, it would be useful to explore the synergies between different policy tools and construct a more complete framework for policy combination optimization. Lastly, with the development of digital technologies, new work modes like remote work may further alter the spatial economic landscape, and the long-term structural changes brought about by this should continue to be studied in terms of their impact on the real estate market.
This study also has some limitations that need to be addressed: First, the model assumes completely rational economic agents, which may deviate from reality under major shocks. Second, due to limitations in data availability, some theoretical predictions have not been fully tested empirically. Third, the model mainly focuses on short-term equilibrium characteristics, and its analysis of long-term structural changes requires further strengthening. Addressing these issues will require further deepening the theoretical framework, enriching analytical tools, and enhancing the integration with empirical research in future studies.
Overall, this study provides a systematic theoretical framework for understanding the impact of major public health events on the real estate market, and its conclusions have significant implications for improving related policies. This study suggests that, in the face of sudden public health events, policymakers need to focus more on spatial heterogeneity, balance short-term stability with long-term development, and fully consider the synergies between policy tools. At the same time, as the economic and social landscape continues to evolve, the external environment faced by the real estate market is becoming increasingly complex. This necessitates continuous innovation in theoretical research to provide stronger support for policy practice.