Next Article in Journal
A Multistep Method for Integration of Perturbed and Damped Second-Order ODE Systems
Previous Article in Journal
Convergence and Almost Sure Polynomial Stability of Partially Truncated Split-Step Theta Method for Stochastic Pantograph Models with Lévy Jumps
Previous Article in Special Issue
Matrix Pencil Optimal Iterative Algorithms and Restarted Versions for Linear Matrix Equation and Pseudoinverse
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Nash’s Existence Theorem for Non-Compact Strategy Sets †

1
Beijing Normal University-Hong Kong Baptist University United International College, Zhuhai 519087, China
2
Division of Mathematics, Sichuan University Jinjiang College, Pengshan 620860, China
3
School of Economics, Chongqing Technology and Business University, Chongqing 400067, China
4
School of Mathematics, Sichuan University, Chengdu 610065, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
In Memory of the Big Mathematician Professor Ky Fan for His 110th Birthday.
Mathematics 2024, 12(13), 2017; https://doi.org/10.3390/math12132017
Submission received: 6 May 2024 / Revised: 23 June 2024 / Accepted: 26 June 2024 / Published: 28 June 2024
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Nonlinear Functional Analysis: Theory, Methods, and Applications)

Abstract

:
In this paper, we apply the classical FKKM lemma to obtain the Ky Fan minimax inequality defined on nonempty non-compact convex subsets in reflexive Banach spaces, and then we apply it to game theory and obtain Nash’s existence theorem for non-compact strategy sets, which can be regarded as a new, simple but interesting application of the FKKM lemma and the Ky Fan minimax inequality, and we can also present another proof about the famous John von Neumann’s existence theorem in two-player zero-sum games. Due to the results of Li, Shi and Chang, the coerciveness in the conclusion can be replaced with the P.S. or G.P.S. conditions.
MSC:
54C40; 14E20; 46E25; 20C20

1. Introduction

In a non-cooperative game, consider n players named P 1 , P 2 , , P n , and each P i has a set of strategies K i , where i = 1 , 2 , , n and K i satisfy the following condition:
(O)
Each K i is a nonempty convex compact subset of a topological vector space E i .
If each player P i has chosen a strategy from K i , let
f i : K 1 × × K n = : X R
be the loss of player P i . Equivalently, f i gives P i ’s payoff.
John Forbes Nash Jr., an American mathematician, introduced the following concept and proved its existence with a 28-page Ph.D. dissertation [1] in 1950.
Definition 1 (Nash).
The equilibrium is a point
q ˜ : = ( q ˜ 1 , q ˜ 2 , , q ˜ n ) X
satisfying that
f i ( q ˜ ) = min p i K i f i ( q ˜ 1 , , q ˜ i 1 , p i , q ˜ i + 1 , q ˜ n ) .
In other words, the Nash equilibrium is a state of a non-cooperative game such that no one can increase their expected return by changing their strategy while the others keep theirs unchanged.
Using Brouwer fixed point theorem, John Nash proved the following.
Theorem 1.
Assume that
K i = { p i = ( p i 1 , p i 2 , , p i n i ) E i = R n i , 0 p i k 1 , k = 1 , , n i , k = 1 n i p i k = 1 }
and the following:
(I) 
f i : K 1 × × K n R is continuous for every i { 1 , , n } .
(II) 
Let p = ( p 1 , , p n ) . For i = 1 , , n , fix all p j when j i , and assume p i f i ( p ) is convex on K i .
Then, Nash equilibrium does exist.
Nash’s work on game theory shocked the economics community and won the John von Neumann Theory Prize in 1978 and the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (with John Harsanyi and Reinhard Selten) in 1994.
In 1961, the Chinese-born American mathematician Ky Fan extended the classical Knaster–Kuratowski–Mazurkiewicz (KKM) lemma to an infinite-dimensional result [2]. Later, in 1972, Ky Fan applied the FKKM lemma and obtained the Ky Fan minimax inequality [3].
Theorem 2
([3]). It is
min y X sup x X f ( x , y ) sup x X f ( x , x )
if the following three assumptions are satisfied:
(1) 
The function f : X × X R is given where X is a compact, convex and nonempty set in a topological vector space.
(2) 
f is quasi-concave in the first argument, i.e., x f ( x , y ) is quasi-concave on X for every fixed y X .
(3) 
f is lower semicontinuous in the second argument, i.e., y f ( x , y ) is lower semicontinuous on X for every fixed x X .
The Ky Fan minimax inequality is equivalent to Brouwer’s fixed-point theorem [4]; it is a powerful tool and has many applications [5], especially in mathematical economics and game theory (see Chapter 9 in [4]). One of its applications is to show Nash’s existence theorem in a very concise way (see [6,7]). In this paper, we apply the classical FKKM lemma to obtain the Ky Fan minimax inequality defined on nonempty non-compact convex subsets in reflexive Banach spaces, and then we apply it to game theory and obtain Nash’s existence theorem for non-compact strategy sets, which can be regarded as a new, simple but interesting application of the FKKM lemma and the Ky Fan minimax inequality, and we can also give another proof of the famous John von Neumann’s existence theorem in two-player zero-sum games. Due to the results of Li [8], Shi and Chang [9], the coerciveness in the conclusion can be replaced with the P.S. or G.P.S. conditions.
The academic editor and the referee pointed out some important references on the FKKM lemma and the Ky Fan inequality [5,10,11,12,13]. Their generalizations are very complicated; our conditions and proofs are different from theirs.

2. Main Results and Proofs

We replace condition (O) with the following one:
(H)
Each K i is a nonempty convex subset of a reflexive Banach space E i .
And we maintain the original definition of the Nash equilibrium. Then, we denote the set of strategy profiles as follows:
X : = K 1 × K 2 × × K n E 1 × E 2 × × E n = : E .
For a vector p : = ( p 1 , p 2 , , p n ) E , define its norm
p E : = i = 1 n p i E i 2 .
Since each E i is a reflexive Banach space, it is not difficult to verify that E (equipped with its norm topology) is a reflexive Banach space either.
We cite the classical FKKM lemma as follows.
Lemma 1.
Let X be a nonempty subset of a topological vector space E and let the set-valued mapping
T : X 2 E
satisfy the following conditions:
(1) 
For any fixed x X , T ( x ) is a nonempty and closed subset of E.
(2) 
There exists a x 0 X such that T ( x 0 ) is compact in E.
(3) 
For any finite set { x 1 , x 2 , , x n } , the following holds
co { x 1 , x 2 , , x n } i = 1 n T ( x i ) .
Then,
x X T ( x ) T ( x 0 ) ,
and especially,
x X T ( x ) .
For the convenience of the reader, here, we provide the proof, which is slightly different from that in [2].
Proof. 
Case 1. X is a set with finite points in it. The proof is similar to the that of the classic KKM lemma [14].
Case 2. X is an infinite set. From hypotheses (1) and (2), we have that
T ˜ ( x ) : = T ( x ) T ( x 0 )
is compact for any x X .
Next, we will prove by contradiction. If the conclusion in this case is not true, we will show that there exists the finite set { x 1 , , x m } X such that
i = 1 m T ˜ ( x i ) = ,
which is contradictory to Case 1.
Assume that
x X T ˜ ( x ) = ,
Then, by taking the complement of both sides, we have
x X T ˜ c ( x ) = X .
For an arbitrary point x 1 X , the compact set is as follows:
T ˜ ( x 1 ) = X T ˜ c ( x 1 ) x x 1 T ˜ c ( x ) .
Notice that its right-hand side is an open covering of T ˜ ( x 1 ) , so we can pick only a finite number of open subsets to cover T ˜ ( x 1 ) , i.e., there exist some finite sets, which we denote as { x 2 , x 3 , , x m } , that satisfy
i = 2 m T ˜ c ( x m ) T ˜ ( x 1 ) .
So, their complements satisfy
i = 2 m T ˜ ( x ) T ˜ c ( x 1 ) .
Hence, we obtain that
i = 1 m T ˜ ( x ) T ˜ c ( x 1 ) T ˜ ( x 1 ) = ,
which contradicts Case 1. □
Applying Lemma 1, we have the following Ky Fan minimax inequality in the case that the topological vector space is especially a reflexive Banach space equipped with weak topology. Then, we can weaken the compactness assumption of the classical Ky Fan inequality.
Theorem 3.
Let X be a nonempty and convex subset of a reflexive Banach space E and let the functional
f : X × X R
satisfy the following conditions:
(i) 
For any fixed y X , the functional x f ( x , y ) is quasi-concave on X, i.e., for any l R , the set
{ x X | f ( x , y ) l }
is convex.
(ii) 
For any fixed x X , y f ( x , y ) is weakly lower semicontinuous on X, i.e., for any l R , the set
{ ( y , l ) X × R | f ( x , y ) l }
is weakly closed.
(iii) 
m : = sup x X f ( x , x ) < + .
(iv) 
There exists a x 0 X such that the set
T ( x 0 ) : = { y X | f ( x 0 , y ) m }
is bounded in X.
Then,
min y X sup x X f ( x , y ) sup x X f ( x , x ) .
Remark 1.
In particular, condition (iv) in Theorem 3 is satisfied, while the functional
y f ( x 0 , y )
is coercive on X, i.e., y n E + implies that f ( x 0 , y n ) + . In fact, if not, there must exist a sequence { y n } T ( x 0 ) satisfying y n E + so that f ( x 0 , y n ) + , which contradicts the definition of T ( x 0 ) .
Proof. 
Set
T ( x ) = { y X | f ( x , y ) m } .
(1) From hypotheses (ii) and (iii), we have that for any x X , T ( x ) is nonempty (since x must belong to T ( x ) ) and weakly closed (by the definition of weak lower semicontinuity).
(2) By hypothesis (iv), we obtain the boundedness of T ( x 0 ) . Using the Eberlein–Šmulian theorem (see Page 144 in [15]), T ( x 0 ) becomes weakly relatively compact. Then, combined with conclusion (1) above, T ( x 0 ) is weakly compact.
(3) We claim that
co { x 1 , x 2 , , x n } i = 1 n T ( x i )
for any finite set { x 1 , x 2 , , x n } . Otherwise, there has to be a y ¯ co { x 1 , x 2 , , x n } , but y ¯ i = 1 n T ( x i ) . Then,
f ( x i , y ¯ ) > m , i = 1 , 2 , , n .
That is, ε > 0 such that
f ( x i , y ¯ ) m + ε .
From hypothesis (i), we have that the set { x X | f ( x , y ¯ ) m + ε } is convex since for each x i that belongs to it, y ¯ is also in it. Then,
f ( y ¯ , y ¯ ) m + ε > m ,
which is contradictory to the definition of m.
Using Lemma 1, we have that
x X T ( x ) ,
i.e., there exists y ˜ T ( x ) such that
f ( x , y ˜ ) m , x X .
Hence,
inf y X sup x X f ( x , y ) sup x X f ( x , y ˜ ) sup x X f ( x , x ) .
Next, we will show that the notation “inf” above can be replaced with “min”. Notice hypothesis (ii): for any real number l, the set { ( y , l ) X × R | f ( x , y ) l } is weakly closed in E. Then, the set
x X { ( y , l ) X × R | f ( x , y ) l }
is also weakly closed, which implies that the functional
y sup x X f ( x , y )
is weakly lower semicontinuous on X. Moreover, the set
{ y X | sup x X f ( x , y ) m } = x X T ( x )
is weakly closed in E since
M : = x X T ( x ) T ( x 0 ) = { y X | f ( x 0 , y ) m } ,
which implies that the set M is a weakly compact subset of T ( x 0 ) . Since weakly lower semicontinuous functionals always have the minimum on weakly compact sets, the functional
y sup x X f ( x , y )
is able to reach its infimum in M. Then, we clearly have that
inf y X sup x X f ( x , y ) = min y M sup x X f ( x , y ) = min y X sup x X f ( x , y ) .
Hence, we have
min y X sup x X f ( x , y ) sup x X f ( x , x ) ,
which completes the proof. □
Now, we can prove Nash’s existence theorem for non-compact strategy sets in the following.
Theorem 4.
Assume the hypothesis
(H) 
Each K i is a nonempty convex closed subset of a reflexive Banach space E i .
and the following assumptions:
(I) 
Let p = ( p 1 , , p n ) . For each i = 1 , , n , fix all the components p j when j i and the functional
p i f i ( p )
is convex on K i .
(II) 
Each f i is weakly continuous on X : = K 1 × × K n .
(III) 
There exists a p 0 = ( p 10 , , p n 0 ) X such that i { 1 , , n } , the set
T ( p 0 ) : = q X | i = 1 n f i ( q ) f i ( q 1 , , q i 1 , p i 0 , q i + 1 , , q n ) 0
is bounded in E.
Then, there is at least one Nash equilibrium in X.
Proof. 
We set
f : X × X R ( p , q ) i = 1 n f i ( q ) f i ( q 1 , , q i 1 , p i , q i + 1 , , q n ) .
and
T : X 2 X p { q X | f ( p , q ) 0 } .
(i) From hypothesis (I), we obtain that for any fixed q X , the functional
p f ( p , q )
is concave on X.
(ii) By hypothesis (II), we obtain the weak continuity of f.
(iii) It is obvious that f ( p , p ) = 0 for all p X .
(iv) Observing hypothesis (III), we have that T ( p 0 ) is bounded in E since for each q T ( p 0 ) , we have that
q E = i = 1 n q i E i 2 i = 1 n q i E i < + .
Using Theorem 3, there exists a q ˜ X such that
f ( p , q ˜ ) 0 , p X .
In particular, for any i = 1 , 2 , , n , we choose
p i = ( q ˜ 1 , , q ˜ i 1 , p i i , q ˜ i + 1 , q ˜ n ) X .
Then,
f i ( q ˜ ) f i ( p i ) 0 , i { 1 , , n } ,
that is,
f i ( q ˜ ) f i ( p i ) = f i ( q ˜ 1 , , q ˜ i 1 , p i i , q ˜ i + 1 , q ˜ n ) , p i i K i and i { 1 , , n } .
This means that q ˜ is exactly the Nash equilibrium and that the proof is complete. □
Remark 2.
In Theorem 4, condition (III) is usually difficult to satisfy for n 3 ; however, it holds for the following practical and concise situation for John von Neumann’s two-person zero-sum game in unbounded strategy sets. Compared with the result of Zeidler (see Theorem 2.G. on Page 76 and Proposition 1 on Page 80 of [6]), our assumptions are weaker; in particular, here, we do not need the strict convexity of the space X.
Theorem 5.
In a two-player zero-sum game, we denote the loss functional for player P i as
f i : K 1 × K 2 = : X R ,
where K i (i.e., the strategies of P i ) is a nonempty convex set in a suitable reflexive Banach space E i . Then, it is clear that f 2 = f 1 . Assume the following:
(S1) 
For any fixed p 2 K 2 , the functional p 1 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) is convex and lower semicontinuous on K 1 .
(S2) 
For any fixed p 1 K 1 , the functional p 2 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) is concave and upper semicontinuous on K 2 .
(S3) 
There exists a p 0 : = ( p 10 , p 20 ) X such that the functional · f 1 ( · , p 20 ) is coercive on K 1 and · f 1 ( p 10 , · ) is coercive on K 2 .
Then, there is at least one Nash equilibrium in X and
min p 1 K 1 max p 2 K 2 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) = max p 2 K 2 min p 1 K 1 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) .
Proof. 
We set
f : X × X R ( p , q ) f 1 ( p 1 , q 2 ) + f 1 ( q 1 , p 2 ) .
(i) For any fixed q X , p f 1 ( q 1 , q 2 ) f 1 ( p 1 , q 2 ) + f 2 ( q 1 , q 2 ) f 2 ( q 1 , p 2 ) = f ( p , q ) is concave on X since x = ( x 1 , x 2 ) , y = ( y 1 , y 2 ) X = K 1 × K 2 and λ [ 0 , 1 ] , in applying conditions (S1) and (S2), the following holds:
f λ x + ( 1 λ ) y , q = f 1 λ x 1 + ( 1 λ ) y 1 , q 2 + f 1 q 1 , λ x 2 + ( 1 λ ) y 2 [ λ f 1 ( x 1 , q 2 ) + ( 1 λ ) f 1 ( y 1 , q 2 ) ] + [ λ f 1 ( q 1 , x 2 ) + ( 1 λ ) f 1 ( q 1 , y 2 ) ] = λ [ f 1 ( x 1 , q 2 ) + f 1 ( q 1 , x 2 ) ] + ( 1 λ ) [ f 1 ( y 1 , q 2 ) + f 1 ( q 1 , y 2 ) ] = λ f ( x , q ) + ( 1 λ ) f ( y , q ) .
(ii) Similar to conclusion (i) above, the function q f ( p , q ) is convex on X (and of course quasi-convex). Then, we have that the set T ( p ) : = q X | f ( p , q ) m is convex for every m R and for any p X . And clearly, both q f 1 ( q 1 , p 2 ) and q f 1 ( p 1 , q 2 ) are lower semicontinuous on X; we have that T ( p ) is closed on X. Since T ( p ) is both closed and convex, using Mazur’s lemma (see Page 6 in [16]), we obtain that T ( p ) is weakly closed. Hence, the functional q f ( p , q ) is weakly lower semicontinuous on X for any fixed p by definition.
(iii) It is obvious that f ( p , p ) = 0 for all p X .
(iv) By applying condition (S3), we have that the functional
q f ( p 0 , q ) = f 1 ( p 10 , q 2 ) + f 1 ( q 1 , p 20 )
is coercive on X and the set q X | f ( p 0 , q ) 0 is bounded in X directly from Remark 1.
Hence, using Theorem 3, we have that there exists a q ˜ X such that
f ( p , q ˜ ) 0 , p X .
Similar to Theorem 4, this q ˜ is exactly the Nash equilibrium and
min p 1 K 1 f 1 ( p 1 , q ˜ 2 ) = f 1 ( q ˜ 1 , q ˜ 2 ) = max p 2 K 2 f 1 ( q ˜ 1 , p 2 ) ,
that is,
max p 2 K 2 min p 1 K 1 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) = f 1 ( q ˜ 1 , q ˜ 2 ) = min p 1 K 1 max p 2 K 2 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) .
For the two-player zero-sum game, Shu-Zhong Shi and Kung-Chin Chang [9] proved the following theorem.
Theorem 6
(Theorem 3.1 of [9]). Assume that the loss functional for the i-th player P i is denoted as
f i : K 1 × K 2 = : X R ,
where K i is not only nonempty and convex in some reflexive Banach space, but also weakly closed. Since the payoffs are zero-sum, f 1 + f 2 = 0 , that is, f 2 = f 1 . Assume the following:
(S1)’ 
For any fixed p 2 K 2 , the functional p 1 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) is quasi-convex and weakly lower semicontinuous on K 1 .
(S2)’ 
For any fixed p 1 K 1 , the functional p 2 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) is quasi-concave and weakly upper semicontinuous on K 2 .
(S3)’ 
There exists a p 0 : = ( p 10 , p 20 ) X such that the functional · f 1 ( · , p 20 ) is bounded below and coercive on K 1 and · f 1 ( p 10 , · ) is bounded below and coercive on K 2 .
Then, there is at least one Nash equilibrium in X and
min p 1 K 1 max p 2 K 2 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) = max p 2 K 2 min p 1 K 1 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) .
The proof is directly from the Lop-sided Maximum Theorem (Page 213 of [9]). It only requires the quasi-convexity of p 1 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) and p 2 f 1 ( p 1 , p 2 ) . But the cost is that K 1 and K 2 must be weakly closed, and it is also necessary that · f 1 ( · , p 20 ) and · f 1 ( p 10 , · ) have lower bounds. Due to the different proof methods, this theorem is difficult to generalize to the case of multiple people like Theorem 4.
Shi and Chang also noticed a result due to Li [8]: a function f must be coercive if it has a lower bound and satisfies the following Palais–Smale (P.S. in short) condition:
Definition 2
(Definition 5.3.1 in [7]). For a closed set X in a Banach space and a functional f C 1 ( X , R ) , f satisfies that
{ x n } X satisfying that M ( 0 , + ) s . t . | f ( x n ) | M and f ( x n ) 0 x 0 X and { x k } { x n } s . t . x k x 0 .
Thus, the coerciveness aspects in Theorem 5 and Theorem 6 can both be replaced with the P.S. condition.
Furthermore, Shi and Chang extended the P.S. condition to the G.P.S.’ condition (“G” stands for “generalized”) and Li’s theorem for nonsmooth functionals; they then obtained the following theorem.
Theorem 7
(Theorem 3.2 in [9]). Let X be a nonempty closed set in a Banach space. Assume that f : X R is lower semicontinuous and bounded below and satisfies the following G.P.S.’ condition:
{ x n } X satisfying that a R and b [ 0 , + ) s . t . f ( x n ) a and inf γ T X ( x n ) f + X ( x n , γ γ ) b x 0 X and { x k } { x n } s . t . x k x 0 .
Then, f is coercive. Here, the notation T X ( · ) is the contingent cone of a nonempty subset X of a Banach space E; that is,
T X ( · ) : = { γ E | t n 0 and γ n γ s . t . · + t n γ n X } .
And the notation f + X ( · , γ ) is the contingent derivative of f at ·, i.e.,
f + X ( · , γ ) : = lim inf γ γ · + t γ X t 0 f ( · + t γ ) f ( · ) t .
In the same way, we can also replace the coerciveness in Theorem 5 with the G.P.S. condition to make it more applicable.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization and original analysis, X.Z.; Formal analysis, R.H.; Writing—original draft, C.Y.; Supervision, S.Z. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported partially by the NSF of China, No. 12071316.

Data Availability Statement

All data required for this research are included within the paper.

Acknowledgments

The authors sincerely thank the academic editor and the referees for their many valuable comments, which help them to improve the paper. We would also like to thank Cheng Chen and Liu Luchuan and Ma Jinpeng for their effective discussions.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors do not have any competing interest.

References

  1. Nash, J.F., Jr. Non-Cooperative Games. Ph.D. Thesis, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, USA, 1950. [Google Scholar]
  2. Fan, K. A Generalization of Tychonoff’s Fixed Point Theorem. Math. Ann. 1961, 142, 305–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Fan, K. A Minimax Inequality and Applications. In Inequalities; Shisha, O., Ed.; Academic Press: San Diego, CA, USA, 1972; Volume III, pp. 103–113. [Google Scholar]
  4. Aubin, J.P. Optima and Equilibria; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 1998. [Google Scholar]
  5. Bigi, G.; Castellani, M.; Pappalardo, M.; Passacantando, M. Nonlinear Programming Techniques for Equilibria; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  6. Zeidler, E. Applied Functional Analysis; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  7. Zhang, S. Functional Analysis with Applications; Science Press: Beijing, China, 2018. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  8. Li, S. A Multiple Critical Point Theorem and Its Application in Nonlinear Partial Differential Equations. Acta Math. Sci. 1984, 4, 335–340. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  9. Shi, S.Z.; Chang, K.C. A Local Minimax Theorem without Compactness. In Nonlinear and Convex Analysis (Santa Barbara, Calif., 1985); Lin, B.L., Simons, S., Eds.; Dekker: New York, NY, USA, 1987; pp. 211–233. [Google Scholar]
  10. Castellani, M.; Giuli, M. A Generalized Ky Fan Minimax Inequality on Finite-dimensional Spaces. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 2021, 190, 343–357. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Fakhar, F.; Hajisharifi, H.R.; Soltani, Z. Noncoercive and Noncontinuous Equilibrium Problems: Existence Theorem in Infinite-dimensional Spaces. J. Glob. Optim. 2023, 86, 989–1003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Lignola, M.B. Ky Fan Inequalities and Nash Equilibrium Points without Semicontinuity and Compactness. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 1997, 94, 137–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Scheimberg, S.; Jacinto, F.M. An extension of FKKM lemma with an application to generalized equilibrium problems. Pac. J. Optim. Int. J. 2010, 6, 243–253. [Google Scholar]
  14. Knaster, B.; Kuratowski, K.; Mazurkiewicz, S. Ein Beweis des Fixpunktsatzes für n-dimensionale Simplexe. Fundam. Math. 1929, 14, 132–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Yosida, K. Functional Analysis; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  16. Ekeland, I.; Témam, R. Convex Analysis and Variational Problems; Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics (SIAM): Philadelphia, PA, USA, 1999. [Google Scholar]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhang, X.; Yang, C.; Han, R.; Zhang, S. Nash’s Existence Theorem for Non-Compact Strategy Sets. Mathematics 2024, 12, 2017. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12132017

AMA Style

Zhang X, Yang C, Han R, Zhang S. Nash’s Existence Theorem for Non-Compact Strategy Sets. Mathematics. 2024; 12(13):2017. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12132017

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhang, Xinyu, Chunyan Yang, Renjie Han, and Shiqing Zhang. 2024. "Nash’s Existence Theorem for Non-Compact Strategy Sets" Mathematics 12, no. 13: 2017. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12132017

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop