Next Article in Journal
Multivariate Student versus Multivariate Gaussian Regression Models with Application to Finance
Previous Article in Journal
Geometric No-Arbitrage Analysis in the Dynamic Financial Market with Transaction Costs
Previous Article in Special Issue
Forecasting Volatility: Evidence from the Saudi Stock Market
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Contribution to the Valuation of BRVM’s Assets: A Conditional CAPM Approach

by
Mamadou Cisse
1,*,†,
Mamadou Konte
2,†,
Mohamed Toure
1,† and
Smael Afolabi Assani
3,†
1
National School of Statistics and Economic Analysis of Dakar, CP 45512 Dakar, Senegal
2
Department of Economics, University Gaston Berger of Saint-Louis, Saint-Louis 00234, Senegal
3
Department of Statistics, University of Montreal, Montreal, QC H3T 1J4, Canada
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
These authors contributed equally to this work.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12(1), 27; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010027
Submission received: 29 July 2018 / Revised: 27 November 2018 / Accepted: 5 December 2018 / Published: 6 February 2019
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Stock Market Volatility Modelling and Forecasting)

Abstract

:
The conditional capital asset pricing model (CAPM) theory postulates that the systematic risk ( β ) of an asset or portfolio varies over time. Several dynamics are thus given to systematic risk in the literature. This article looks for the dynamic that seems to best explain the returns of the assets of the Regional Stock Exchange of West Africa (BRVM) by comparing two dynamics: one by the Kalman filter (assuming that the β follow a random walk) and the other by the Markov switching (MS) model (assuming that β varies according to regimes) for four portfolios of the BRVM. Having found a link between the beta of the market portfolio and the size criterion (measured by capitalization), the two previous models were re-estimated with the addition of the SMB (Small Minus Big) variable. The results show according to the RMSE criterion that the estimation by the Kalman filter fits better than MS, which suggests that investors cannot anticipate systematic risk because of its high volatility.

Graphical Abstract

1. Introduction

In the world of finance, the evaluation of the return of financial assets is governed by the well-known theory of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). This theory, introduced by Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Black (1972), states that the risk premium of an asset is equal to the product of the systematic asset risk (beta) and the market portfolio. The beta is approximately equal to the covariance between asset returns and market returns. However, there are several criticisms based on the CAPM hypothesis. The most important criticism is from Fama and French (1992)1, which stipulated that the beta of the portfolio market alone was not enough to explain the return of an asset. However, another criticism, and not the least, concerns the postulation of the CAPM, which considers one period. In other words, the beta obtained was based on only one period. This is how the conditional CAPM appeared.
The conditional CAPM postulates that the simple CAPM theory holds from period to period. Thus, agents review their beta (systematic risk) from period to period. Two branches of conditional CAPM currently exist. The first takes into account the addition of a new factor (implying another beta), while the second models the beta of the market portfolio as a system evolving over time. For the last one, several formulations exist regarding the dynamics of the beta. Some authors model it as a random walk, others as a random coefficient, and others as a learning process of an investor. All these forms of modeling are based on precise assumptions about investor behavior. However, among all the formulations of systematic beta risk, which one is more suitable?
The aim of this work is first to investigate the formulation of the beta and thus the behavior of the investors who best explain the return of Regional Stock Exchange (BRVM) assets2. Two main hypotheses are evaluated in this work:
  • Investors cannot predict the systematic risk of assets because it is highly volatile.
  • Investors change their behaviors over a given period, so the asset’s beta takes different values according to these periods.
The first hypothesis is based on the conditional CAPM’s formulation postulating the non-stability of the beta of the assets over time. It is therefore assumed a non-stationarity of the betas. The second hypothesis comes from a large list of works3 in the literature of Markov switching (MS) models regarding the beta estimate.
To our knowledge, no study of the BRVM has focused on such a subject.
The results suggest that Hypothesis 1 is more plausible when considering the RMSE criterion.

2. Materials and Methods

The idea of conditional models is to generalize the CAPM to more than two periods making them more in line with reality. They thus raise the hypothesis of a simple periodicity of the CAPM. Indeed, in the CAPM as established, the investor makes a decision at a period following the observed beta. When changing periods, he can revise his behavior. The example given by Jagannathan and Wang (1996) is that in a recession, the leverage effect of low-performing firms is expected to increase sharply relative to other firms, resulting in an increase in their systematic risk (beta). Thus, the beta obtained from the simple CAPM is a conditional beta as shown by the following equation:
E ( R i t / I t 1 ) = r f + β t 1 E ( R m t r f / I t 1 )
where R i t represents the returns, r f the risk-free interest rate, R m t the returns of market portofolio and I t 1 the information available up to t-1. Several approaches are used in conditional models: those with several factors (Jagannathan and Wang (1996); Lettau and Ludvigson (2001)), those with covariances varying over time (Harvey et al. (1992); Bollerslev et al. (1988)), and those with beta4 varying in time. Although the first two approaches are widely used, the approach allowing a variation of beta over time is regaining interest, particularly with the work of Adrian and Franzoni (2009) and Caia and Renb (2012). Prior to this work, the most commonly used methods for estimating time-varying beta are mainly state space models (Kalman filter estimation), recursive least squares, window regressions, etc. In this vast literature, we distinguish the works of Groenewold and Fraser (1999), Park (2004), and Abdymomunov and Morley (2011).
Groenewold and Fraser (1999) investigated the beta estimate of conditional CAPM with time-varying beta on monthly assets in Australia for 23 sectors over the period 1979–1994. After estimating the betas by the recursive least squares, and by the Kalman filter, they tested the stationarity of the estimated beta and found it to be non-stationary, which reinforces the idea of using such models. Park (2004) examined the relationship between returns and systematic beta risks on US assets. He first estimated the simple CAPM (simple computation of the betas by the covariance between returns and market portfolio) and showed by means of a Cusum test that betas were not stable over time. Based on the fact that the betas are not stable over time, they evaluated the relationship between return and beta using the Kalman filter for 10 portfolios classified by size (capitalization) and 12 others constructed using the classification of Breeden et al. (1989) and Ferson and Harvey (1991), and the results show that the small portfolios have higher beta and reciprocally. They explain it by the fact that these portfolios are generally less diversified. The author has also estimated a conditional CAPM, where it distinguishes two types of beta according to the sign of the risk premium of the market portfolio beta and the return on portfolios. This result is consistent with the implication that beta is a useful measure of systematic risk in time. Abdymomunov and Morley (2011) have proposed a beta estimate using the Markov change regime method. Their results suggest that the use of the MS model improves the explanation of asset return at the moment when the simple CAPM is invalid.
The previous models do not take investor learning into account. Indeed, it would not be wrong to think that investors do not know the long-term level of systematic risk and therefore learn rationally from observations of expected returns. It is on this base that Adrian and Franzoni (2009) modeled the returns on US assets. To take investors knowledge of systematic risk into account, they introduced variables such as “the term spread,” representing the difference between the yields of US 10-year and 3-month treasury bills, “the value spread” and the CAY variable of Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), capturing innovations in the cointegration relationships between consumption, market portfolio, and labor income. The results suggest that the insertion of learning and estimation by Kalman filters reduce pricing errors.
Recently, Caia and Renb (2012) proposed a new approach for estimating the CAPM with time-varying beta. Namely, they used a regression model with a functional coefficient with beta varying over time. The innovation here is certainly due to the consideration of different windows in the estimation of beta (nonparametric estimation) but also of a different learning in each window. The results show that this model better explains the return of assets than the simple CAPM.

2.1. Conditional Estimation of Systematic Risk ( β )

The previous section helps one to understand the necessity of using conditional CAPM and mainly those that vary the beta over time. From Equation (1), it will be necessary to give a specification to the form of beta. It should be specified that a small modification is made to the specification of Equation (1) to retain the following equation:
E ( R i t ) = r f + β t 1 E ( R m t r f ) 5 .
Two specifications are used for this study. For each specification, two variants will be estimated depending on whether SMB (Small Minus Big) is introduced as a factor from the Fama and French three-factor model.

2.1.1. Specification 1: β Varies According to a Random Walk

Variant 1: The β of Market Portfolio Follows a Random Walk

The first variant of Specification 1 relating to Equation (2) is to consider that the beta of the market portfolio follows a random walk. The equation can then be written as
β t m = β t 1 m + η t
where η t N ( 0 , σ η 2 ) , and β t m refers to the beta associated with the market portfolio. The idea underlying this choice is that the beta variance of the market portfolio varies over time. In other words, it is not stationary. Thus, we make the assumption, unlike Adrian and Franzoni (2009), that agents do not know the long-term level of beta risk associated with the market portfolio. The beta cannot be predicted by its past value and varies randomly from period to period. This specification has been retained in several studies (Marti (2006) and Park (2004)). The general model can therefore be written as follows:
R i t = r f + β t 1 m ( R m t r f ) + ϵ i t β t m = β t 1 m + η t .

Variant 2

The second variant consists in introducing an additional variable into the estimation of the returns of the assets. This is the SMB variable6. The latter represents the difference (Minus) of profitability between small (Small) and large (Big) assets sorted by capitalization. We assume that the beta associated with SMB is not stable. The latter is also assumed to follow a random walk. This choice is justified by the work of Huang and Hueng (2009). They have shown that taking into account a change in the coefficients of the additional factors of the simple CAPM could significantly reduce the price error. The general model is thus written as follows:
R i t = r f + β t 1 m ( R m t r f ) + β t 1 S M B S M B t + ϵ i t β t m = β t 1 m + η t 1 β t S M B = β t 1 S M B + η t 2 .
Equations (4) and (5) are estimated by the Kalman filter. Indeed, these equations are special cases of Equation (A1) (see Appendix A), presenting the general form of the state space model estimated by the Kalman filter. Equation (4) is obtained by setting Z t = ( 1 R m t ) , α t = ( r f β i t m ) , T t = I 2 , where I 2 denotes the identity matrix of order 2 and R t = ( 0 1 ) . Equation (5) is obtained by setting Z t = ( 1 R m t S M B t ) , α t = ( r f β i t m β i t S M B ) , T t = I 3 , where I 3 denotes the identity matrix of order 3 and R t = ( 0 1 1 ) .

Choosing the Initialization Parameters for the Kalman Filter

The state space model estimated by the Kalman filter distinguishes four initialization parameters. This is a 1 , P 1 , H t , and Q t (see Appendix A). Although the parameters a 1 and P 1 are important in the initialization, they are not determinative since, whatever the value of these parameters, the filter will always tend to find its equilibrium value around the series by error correction (Durbin and Koopman (2012)), “Time Series Analysis by State Space Methods”, pp. 32–33). The most important parameters are H t and Q t since they can drastically change the estimates obtained. Durbin and Koopman propose an estimate of these parameters by the maximum likelihood.
The parameter Q t is the one that acts on the beta estimated by the Kalman filter. Although it is estimated by the maximum likelihood, the obtained value may not minimize other criteria concerning the quality of the model, in particular the RMSE (root mean squared error). Thus, unlike the Durbin and Koopman approach, we propose the determination of the Q t minimizing the RMSE criterion.

2.1.2. Specification 2: The β Varies According to Regime

Variant 1: Only the Market Portfolio Is Included as an Explanatory Variable

This variant takes into account the returns of the market portfolio as the only explanatory variable. The specification for the beta of the market portfolio is allowed to take different values according to regime. This type of model has already been used in the literature to estimate the beta of the market portfolio in Guidolin and Timmermann (2005) and Abdymomunov and Morley (2011). The number of regimes (states) is a priori unknown. For the case of two states, the model can be written as follows:
R i t = r f + β S t m ( R m t r f ) + σ S t ϵ i t β S t m = β 1 m si S t = 1 β 2 m si S t = 2 σ S t = σ 1 si S t = 1 σ 2 si S t = 2
where S t denotes a discrete random variable taking the value 1 when in the first state and 2 in the second state; β 1 m and β 2 m are the beta values corresponding to the different states. We also assume that the standard error deviation σ S t (associated to the white noise ϵ i t in Equation (6)) varies from one regime to another. Thus, σ 1 and σ 2 designate the values of the standard deviation according to the two states.

Variant 2: Adding the SMB Factor

This variant is obtained by adding the SMB in Equation (6) and by varying its coefficient according to different states. The general model is thus written:
R i t = r f + β S t m ( R m t r f ) + β S t S M B S M B t + σ S t ϵ i t β S t m = β 1 m if S t = 1 β 2 m if S t = 2 β S t S M B = β 1 S M B if S t = 1 β 2 S M B if S t = 2 σ S t = σ 1 if S t = 1 σ 2 if S t = 2 .
Equations (6) and (7) are placed in the Goldfield and Quandt (1973) (see Appendix B) model of the Markovian switching (MS) model. These models will therefore be estimated by the MS.

2.2. Bootstrap Analysis of the Comparison

In order to strengthen the results of our comparison, we provide an additional bootstrap analysis. Thus, we will make a bootstrap with a replacement obtained after 1000 RMSE replications of the Kalman filter models and MS according to the one-factor or the two-factor model. Thus, the distributions of these RMSE will be compared.

2.3. Data Source

The data used comes from the Regional Stock Exchange (BRVM). The disposable variables are the daily prices of 45 assets and their capitalization, market portfolio values (composite BRVM), and sector portfolios covering the period 1999 to 2017. Since the number of observations per asset was different, the data were aggregated at the monthly level, and the returns on the different assets were calculated.
On the basis of these 45 assets, four portfolios were constructed according to the size of the capitalizations7. They are named, respectively, portfolios 1, 2, 3, and 4 in ascending order of capitalization. The SMB (Small Minus Big) variable was obtained by differentiating the returns of small-cap portfolios from large-cap portfolios. For the risk-free asset rate, the rate at which AFD issued a good AAA rated bond for the period 2008–2016 was taken as a proxy. This annual rate is 5.25%. Having monthly data, this rate has been converted to a monthly rate.

3. Results

In this section, we first present the result of the one-factor model and then the two-factor model.

3.1. Estimation of Unconditional and Conditional CAPM with One Factor

The unconditional CAPM estimate on the different portfolios yields poor results. Indeed, after estimates, the residuals of all the portfolios were not normal, so we carried out the Wald test to check the significance of the coefficients. More importantly, the Wald test results show that beta is not significant for any portfolio. In such a situation, Jagannathan and Wang (1996) suggest moving directly to the conditional CAPM estimate.

3.1.1. Portfolios Description

Table 1 presents the summary statistics of the four portfolios. Thus, over the entire period, Portfolio 2 has the highest average monthly return. Indeed, it stood at 4.38% with a dispersion of 26.11% around this average. This portfolio is followed by Portfolios 1, 3, and 4 with average monthly returns of 4.02, 2.52, and 0.32%, respectively. In addition, it should be noted that large-cap portfolios are the least risky in terms of variance.

3.1.2. β Estimation with Kalman Filter

Table 2 presents the results of the beta estimate with the Kalman filter and the MS model using the one-factor model. The results of the Kalman filter show that the average systematic risk (beta) of the portfolio increases with the size of the portfolio, except for Portfolio 4. Thus, the average beta of Portfolio 1 is 22.47% with a variability of 21.42%, while Portfolio 3 is 98.36% with a variability of 40.65%. In addition, it should be noted that the risk-free asset ratio is negative for the two smaller portfolios. The Figure 1 shows the adequacy of the yields predicted by the Kalman filter to the true yields.

3.1.3. β Estimation with the Markov Switching Model

The MS model reveals that the behavior of portfolio returns is governed by two states. The results of the beta estimate by the MS model yield negative and significant risk-free interest rates for the two smaller-sized portfolios like with the Kalman filter. However, the risk-free interest rateof Portfolio 3 is also negative. The states governing the performance of the portfolios differ in terms of volatility (low and high volatility states can be identified). In periods of low volatility (State 1), systematic portfolio risks increase with portfolio size and the change in rating has a significant positive impact on portfolio’s performance. The systematic risk of the market increases from 16.93 for Portfolio 1 to 102.42% for the 4. Finally, during periods of high volatility (State 2), the performance of the market portfolio have no significant effect on the returns, regardless of the portfolios.

3.2. Integration of the SMB Factor of Fama and French

The summary of results from the estimation of the two-factor models are shown in the Table 3.

3.2.1. Estimation by the Kalman Filter

The introduction of the size factor has increased the systematic risk of all portfolios in absolute value, except for 3 and 4. However, the growth of this risk with the size of the portfolios is, respectively, observed firstly for Portfolios 1 and 2 and secondly for 3 and 4. It should be noted that the systematic risk of Portfolio 1 is negative. As a result, the market beta stood at −45.38% with a variability of 30.78% for Portfolio 1, 631.80% with a variability of 99.52% for Portfolio 2, 74.38% with a variability of 4.04% for Portfolio 3, and 80.40% with a variability of 34.70% for Portfolio 4.
On the other hand, the average risk linked to the size factor (SMB) decreases with the size of the portfolios, except for Portfolio 1. It went from 104.08% for Portfolio 2 to 1.09% for Portfolio 4, with respective variabilities of 490.47 and 26.39%. The Figure 2 shows the predicted returns with the model with the size factor and actual returns.

3.2.2. The Markov Switching Model Estimation

The MS model yields different results according to the states. Indeed, during periods of low volatility, portfolio returns are both explained by the market portfolio and the size factor, except for Portfolio 3. For the latter, the SMB factor is not significant. The SMB factor introduction hardly changes the systematic risk of Portfolios 3 and 4 during periods of low volatility, whereas those of Portfolios 1 and 2 vary significantly by 40.87 and 40.10 percentage points, respectively, compared to the model without the SMB factor.

4. Discussion

After estimation of the different models, we proceed in this section to their comparison according to the RMSE criterion. Table 4 presents the RMSE of the different models according to the portfolios. The results show that, generally, the Kalman filter is better. Indeed, when considering the one-factor model, the Kalman filter has the smallest RMSE compared to the MCRM for all portfolios. It should be noted, however, that the gap remains small. For the two-factor model, the Kalman filter performs better than the MS model for Portfolios 1, 2, and 4. The beta of Portfolio 3 seems to be more governed by states than by a random work.
To reinforce these results, according to our methodology, we compare below the bootstrap distributions of the RMSE of Kalman filter and MS models after 1000 replications. Figure 3 gives the bootstrap distributions of the RMSE following the one-factor model. The results show, with the exception of Portfolio 1, that the RMSE distribution obtained by the MS model dominates that of the Kalman filter. This means that the model obtained by the Kalman filter outperforms the MS model. For Portfolio 1, we cannot draw conclusions because distributions are crossing.
Figure 4 shows the bootstrap distributions of the RMSE following the one-factor model. At this level, the conclusions are similar to the case of the one-factor model for Portfolios 1 and 4. For Portfolios 2 and 3, we cannot draw conclusions.
Thus, our results converge more toward the fact that the systematic risk beta follows a random walk, since the model obtained by the Kalman filter generally dominates that with a change in regime.

5. Conclusions

The literature on conditional CAPM has seen much development. As such, a multitude of models exist today for systematic risk modeling ( β ). Based on two assumptions, we estimated the systematic risk according to two models: the Kalman filter and the MS model for four BRVM portfolios, constructed by sorting the assets according to their capitalization and considering the quartiles. Two types of models were evaluated: the first with a market beta as an explanatory variable (a one-factor model) and the second when adding the SMB (Small Minus Big) factor.
The results show that, according to the RMSE criterion, the Kalman filter model is more efficient for both the one- and two-factor estimation.
Following these results, conjectures can be made regarding the behavior of investors in the BRVM market. These conjectures stem directly from the study assumptions. The Kalman filter model provides better predictions than MS. This means that when choosing a portfolio, managers are more likely to expect an uncontrolled risk than a risk varying according to periods.
It is important to remember that our results only apply to the assets of the BRVM and in the context of portfolios built according to criteria concerning the size of capitalizations.
Some of the hypotheses in this study can be released to provide a basis for future research. In this study, only one additional factor was taken into account due to a lack of data. Additional analysis that could be an extension of this study would be to integrate other factors such as HML or B/M. Another extension is the choice of the risk-free asset rate. The rate chosen for our study is only a proxy. An approach that models the risk-free asset would be appropriate.

Author Contributions

M.T. and I.A.A. provided the methodology, analyzed the data, and wrote the paper; M.K. and M.C. supervised all work.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Abbreviations

The following abbreviations are used in this manuscript:
BRVMRegional Stock Exchange
MSMarkov switching
RMSEroot mean squared error

Appendix A. Kalman Filter

As introduced in Durbin and Koopman (2012) in their book, “Time Series Analysis by State Space Methods”, state space modeling provides a global methodology for dealing with several kinds of problems encountered in time series estimation. In this model, it is assumed that the evolution in time of the system studied is determined by a series α 1 , , α n , which is associated with a series of observations y 1 , , y n ; the relationship between α t and y t being specified by a state space model. The main purpose of the state space model is to dynamically determine the unknown vector α t through the knowledge of y t .
The Gaussian general state space model can be written as follows:
y t = Z t α t + ϵ t , ϵ t N ( 0 , H t ) α t + 1 = T t α t + R t η t , η t N ( 0 , Q t ) , t = 1 , , n
where y t is an observations vector, and α t the unobservable component called the state vector. The first equation, Equation (A1), is called the equation of the observations, and the second is called the equation of state. Z t , T t , R t , H t , and Q t are matrices whose initial values are assumed to be known. Errors ϵ t and η t are assumed to be iid and not correlated.
The estimation of the Equation (A1) model is done recursively. Everything starts from the assumption that α 1 N ( a 1 , P 1 ) , with a 1 and P 1 known. Parameters Q t and H t are also assumed to be known. On this basis, we sought for distributions of α t and α t + 1 knowing Y t , where Y t = ( y 1 , , y t ) , the distribution of α t conditionally to Y t 1 being N ( a t , P t ) . By setting a t | t = E ( α t | Y t ) , a t + 1 = E ( α t + 1 | Y t ) , P t | t = V a r ( α t | Y t ) and P t + 1 = V a r ( α t + 1 | Y t ) , the respective conditional distributions of α t and α t + 1 are given by N ( a t | t , P t | T ) and N ( a t + 1 , P t + 1 ) . By setting v t = y t E ( y t | Y t 1 ) , we obtain v t = y t Z t a t because
E ( y t | Y t 1 ) = E ( Z t α t + ϵ t | Y t 1 ) = Z t a t .
E ( ϵ t | Y t 1 ) = 0 and E ( α t | Y t 1 ) = a t . By setting F t = V a r ( v t | Y t 1 ) , we obtain, by a few computations, the following recursive algorithm:
v t = y t Z t a t , F t = Z t P t Z t + H t a t | t = a t + P t Z t F t 1 v t , P t | t = P t P t Z t F t 1 Z t P t a t + 1 = T t a t + K t v t , P t + 1 = T t P t ( T t + K t Z t ) + R t Q t R t
for t = 1 , , n and K t = T t P t Z t F t 1 with a 1 and P 1 the mean and the variance of the initial parameter α 1 . This recursive algorithm is called the Kalman filter.

Appendix B. The Markov Switching Model

The Markov switching model (MS) is widely used for the estimation of cyclical phenomena subject to different phases (e.g., periods of expansion and recession) but also in the stock markets where lot of volatility are observed. MS thus suggests a different estimation of states guided by a process S t . The formulation of Goldfield and Quant is as follows:
y t = β S t x t + ϵ t o ù ϵ t N ( 0 , σ S t )
with β S t = ( β 1 S t , , β k S t ) and x t = ( x 1 t , , x k t ) , a vector of k exogenous variables.
The following notations are retained:
  • S = ( S t ) t = 0 , , n is a Markov process with N states;
  • Y = ( Y t ) t = 0 , , n is a random variable;
  • The observed values of Y are noted y = ( y 1 , , y n ) ;
  • y t 1 = ( y 1 , , y t 1 ) refers to a lagged value of Y t ;
  • p ( y , S | θ ) denotes the joint density of y and S and θ the parameters of Equation (A3) that have to be estimated;
  • p ( y t | y t 1 , S t , θ ) denotes the density function of the distribution of Y t conditioned on past realizations y t 1 and knowing S t ;
  • p ( S t | S t 1 , y t 1 , θ ) denotes the density function of the distribution of S t conditioned on past realizations y t 1 and knowing S t 1 .
Three cases are distinguished: to infer S if θ is known, to estimate θ if S is known, and to estimate simultaneously θ and S. Not knowing S, the method of estimating the third case will be performed. In this case, only y is observed. The idea is to estimate θ by going through all possible values of S. We suppose that S S n + 1 = { 1 , , N } . The likelihood to maximize is written as follows:
p ( y | θ ) = S S n + 1 p ( y | S , θ 1 , , θ N ) p ( S | θ ) .
The numerical solutions of the previous maximization of the likelihood is not viable because S n + 1 is gigantic. Quandt (1972) proposed an approximation of the previous likelihood by the following:
p ( y | θ ) = t = p + 1 n ( k = 1 n p ( y t | S t = k , y t 1 , θ ) p ( S t = k | y t 1 , θ ) ) .
where θ is estimated by the quasi-maximum likelihood (QML)8. For the choice of the state number, several estimates are made by increasing the number of states of S. The best state being that which minimizes the AIC criterion.

Appendix C. Diagnostic Tests of the Two Models

Appendix C.1. Diagnostic Tests of the Kalman Filter

Table A1. Diagnosis of one-factor residuals models.
Table A1. Diagnosis of one-factor residuals models.
Normality TestLjung-Box Test
wp-Value χ 2 dfp-Value
Portfolio 10.39<0.0119.2215.000.20
Portfolio 20.39<0.0150.8715.000.00
Portfolio 30.66<0.0127.1715.000.03
Portfolio 40.71<0.0115.6215.000.41
Table A2. Diagnosis of two-factor residuals models.
Table A2. Diagnosis of two-factor residuals models.
Normality TestLjung-Box Test
wp-Value χ 2 dfp-Value
Portfolio 10.39<0.0119.2215.000.200
Portfolio 20.39<0.0150.8715.000.00
Portfolio 30.66<0.0127.1715.000.03
Portfolio 40.71<0.0115.6215.000.41

Appendix C.2. Diagnostic Tests of Markov Switching Models

Table A3. P-value of structure change tests.
Table A3. P-value of structure change tests.
One Factor ModelTwo Factors Models
β M σ β M β SMB σ
Portfolio 1 0.00000.00000.00000.3995
Portfolio 20.07910.00000.10160.91640.000
Portfolio 30.07680.00000.18430.00010.000
Portfolio 40.53460.00000.16920.0000.0249

Appendix D. Graphics of β

Appendix D.1. β Estimated in the One-Factor Model by the Kalman Filter

Figure A1. Beta estimated from the Kalman filter after the one-factor model. Source: author’s computation.
Figure A1. Beta estimated from the Kalman filter after the one-factor model. Source: author’s computation.
Jrfm 12 00027 g0a1

Appendix E. β Estimated in the Two-Factor Model by the Kalman Filter

Figure A2. Beta estimated from the Kalman filter after the two-factor model. Source: author’s computation.
Figure A2. Beta estimated from the Kalman filter after the two-factor model. Source: author’s computation.
Jrfm 12 00027 g0a2

References

  1. Abdymomunov, Azamat, and James Morley. 2011. Time variation of CAPM betas across market volatility regimes. Applied Financial Economics 21: 1463–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Adrian, Tobias, and Francesco Franzoni. 2009. Learning about beta: Time-varying factor loadings, expected returns, and the conditional CAPM. Journal of Empirical Finance 16: 537–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Black, Fisher, Michael Jensen, and Myron Scholes. 1972. The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Some Empirical Tests. In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets. New York: Praeger Publishers, pp. 79–121. [Google Scholar]
  4. Bollerslev, Tim, Robert Engle, and Jeffrey Wooldridge. 1988. A capital asset pricing model with time-varying covariances. Journal of Political Economy 96: 116–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Breeden, Douglas, Gibbons Michael, and Litzenberger Robert. 1989. Empirical tests of the consumption-oriented CAPM. The Journal of Finance 44: 231–62. [Google Scholar]
  6. Caia, Zongwu, and Yu Renb. 2012. A New Estimation on Time-Varying Betas in Conditional CAPM. Available online: https://bbs.pku.edu.cn/attach/7e/08/7e087592032982c7/cai-ren_v1.pdf (accessed on 5 May 2017).
  7. Durbin, James, and Jan Koopman. 2012. Time Series Analysis by State Space Methods, 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press, vol. 38. [Google Scholar]
  8. Fama, Eugene, and Kenneth French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. The Journal of Finance 47: 427–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Ferson, Wayne, and Campbell Harvey. 1991. The variation of economic risk premiums. Journal of Political Economy 99: 385–415. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Goldfield, Stephen, and Richard Quandt. 1973. A markov model for switching regressions. Journal Econometrics 1: 3–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Groenewold, Nicholaas, and Patricia Fraser. 1999. Time-varying estimates of CAPM betas. Mathematics and Computers in Simulation 48: 531–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Guidolin, Massimo, and Allan Timmermann. 2005. Economic implications of bull and bear regimes in UK stock and bond returns. The Economic Journal 115: 111–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Harvey, Andrew, Esther Ruiz, and Enrique Sentana. 1992. Unobserved component time series models with ARCH disturbances. Journal of Econometrics 52: 129–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Huang, Peng, and James Hueng. 2009. Interest-rate risk factor and stock returns: A time-varying factor-loadings model. Applied Financial Economics 19: 1813–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Jagannathan, Ravi, and Zhenyu Wang. 1996. The conditional CAPM and the cross-section of expected returns. The Journal of Finance 51: 3–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Lettau, Martin, and Sydney Ludvigson. 2001. Resurrecting the (C) CAPM: A cross-sectional test when risk premia are time-varying. Journal of Political Economy 109: 1238–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Lintner, John. 1965. Security prices, risk, and maximal gains from diversification. The journal of finance 20: 587–615. [Google Scholar]
  18. Marti, Didier. 2006. The accuracy of time-varying betas and the cross-section of stock returns. In Proceedings of the European Financial Management Association Meeting, Madrid, Spain, June 28–July 1. [Google Scholar]
  19. Park, Kwang Woo. 2004. Time-Series Analysis of Return and Beta in US. Journal of Academy of Business and Economics 3: 43–54. [Google Scholar]
  20. Quandt, Richard. 1972. A new approach to estimating switching regressions. Journal of the American statistical association 67: 306–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Sharpe, William. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The Journal of Finance 19: 425–42. [Google Scholar]
1
They added two other factors: SMB (Small Minus Big) and HML (High Minus Low).
2
The BRVM, created on 18 December 1996, is a specialized financial institution whose capital is subscribed by regional economic actors in West Africa.
3
4
This is the beta related to the market portfolio.
5
The return of the market portfolio and the asset are assumed to be independent of the information held in t − 1.
6
The main idea was to add the factors used by Fama and French in their three-factor model. However, due to data availability, only the SMB is used here.
7
The weights used for their computation are expressed in terms of capitalization as the simple CAPM assumes.
8
We speak of quasi-maximum likelihood because it is an approximation of the true likelihood.
Figure 1. Actual and predicted returns after the one-factor model. Source: author’s computation.
Figure 1. Actual and predicted returns after the one-factor model. Source: author’s computation.
Jrfm 12 00027 g001
Figure 2. Actual and predicted returns after the two-factor model. Source: author’s computation.
Figure 2. Actual and predicted returns after the two-factor model. Source: author’s computation.
Jrfm 12 00027 g002
Figure 3. RMSE distribution for the one-factor model.
Figure 3. RMSE distribution for the one-factor model.
Jrfm 12 00027 g003
Figure 4. RMSE distribution for the two-factor model.
Figure 4. RMSE distribution for the two-factor model.
Jrfm 12 00027 g004
Table 1. Descriptive statistics of portfolios.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics of portfolios.
ObsMinMeanStandard-devMax
Portfolio 1219−39.574.0231.30294.24
Portfolio 2219−27.454.3826.11208.88
Portfolio 3219−18.042.5219.86169.50
Portfolio 4219−140.200.3211.3330.99
Source: author’s computations.
Table 2. The one-factor model estimated by the Kalman filter and Markov switching (MS).
Table 2. The one-factor model estimated by the Kalman filter and Markov switching (MS).
Kalman FilterMarkov Switching
rf β M σ β M rfState 1State 2
β M β M
P1−0.9322.4721.42−1.70 ***16.93 **55.16
P2−0.3332.1017.13−0.65 *39.40 ***−46.19 **
P30.6098.3640.65−0.1548.23 ***55.09
P41.3793.2643.940.91 ***102.42 ***71.07 ***
Source: author’s computation. * p < 0.1; ** p < 0.05; *** p < 0.01.
Table 3. β estimation with the SMB factor.
Table 3. β estimation with the SMB factor.
Kalman FilterMarkov Switching
rf β M σ β M β SMB σ β SMB rfState 1State 2
β M β SMB β M β SMB
P10.13−45.3830.7892.3726.840.2557.80 ***69.15 ***−44.1173.63 ***
P2−1.20631.8099.52104.08490.47−0.70 **39.10 ***3.81 **−65.49−8.21
P35.0774.384.0474.374.04−0.2248.52 ***1.4063.71 **−7.96
P40.1380.4034.701.0926.390.98 ***105.07 ***−3.35 ***70.37 ***−1.82
Source: author’s computation. p < 0.1; ** p < 0.05; *** p < 0.01.
Table 4. RMSE of different estimation.
Table 4. RMSE of different estimation.
RMSE
One Factor ModelModel with SMB Factor
FKMSFKMS
Portfolio 10.14920.14980.02130.0882
Portfolio 20.12000.12050.00000.1213
Portfolio 30.05950.06460.30620.0646
Portfolio 40.03600.04530.01520.0689
Source: author’s computation.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Cisse, M.; Konte, M.; Toure, M.; Assani, S.A. Contribution to the Valuation of BRVM’s Assets: A Conditional CAPM Approach. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12, 27. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010027

AMA Style

Cisse M, Konte M, Toure M, Assani SA. Contribution to the Valuation of BRVM’s Assets: A Conditional CAPM Approach. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2019; 12(1):27. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010027

Chicago/Turabian Style

Cisse, Mamadou, Mamadou Konte, Mohamed Toure, and Smael Afolabi Assani. 2019. "Contribution to the Valuation of BRVM’s Assets: A Conditional CAPM Approach" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12, no. 1: 27. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010027

APA Style

Cisse, M., Konte, M., Toure, M., & Assani, S. A. (2019). Contribution to the Valuation of BRVM’s Assets: A Conditional CAPM Approach. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 12(1), 27. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010027

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop