Next Article in Journal
Ecoenzymatic Stoichiometry Reveals Microbial Carbon and Phosphorus Limitations under Elevated CO2, Warming and Drought at Different Winter Wheat Growth Stages
Next Article in Special Issue
Does Trust Affect Antecedents of Inter-Organizational Governance Mechanisms and Elicit Successful Collaboration via Innovation? An Empirical Study from a Market-Oriented Economy in Vietnam
Previous Article in Journal
Life Cycle Assessment of a Domestic Wastewater Treatment Plant Simulated with Alternative Operational Designs
Previous Article in Special Issue
Trajectories of Teleworking via Work Organization Conditions: Unraveling the Effect on Work Engagement and Intention to Quit with Path Analyses
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Catching Up of Latecomer Economies in ICT for Sustainable Development: An Analysis Based on Technology Life Cycle Using Patent Data

School of Maritime Economics and Management, Dalian Maritime University, Dalian 116026, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(11), 9038; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15119038
Submission received: 24 April 2023 / Revised: 27 May 2023 / Accepted: 31 May 2023 / Published: 2 June 2023

Abstract

:
In the digital economy era, ICT plays a vital role in supporting the sustainable and high-quality development of latecomer economies. Using technology life cycle analysis and patent data from the United States Patent and Trademark Office (1960–2014), this study analyzed the catching-up characteristics of latecomer economies (with the US as the first mover), including take-off time, growth time, growth rate, and ceiling values in nine sub-fields of information and communication technology (ICT). We applied the logistic and bi-logistic model to reveal the sequence of technological development and growth speed of different economies in different ICT sub-fields. The results show that European economies (Great Britain, France, and Germany) and the US developed first, followed by Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, with China (Mainland) coming later; Asian economies (Japan, Korea, Taiwan, and China (Mainland)) displayed synchronous development strategies, while European economies displayed non-synchronous development strategies. Asian economies are catching up with the US, whereas European economies are standing still both in imitation and indigenous processes. Korea and Taiwan prioritized catching up with a few sub-fields in the indigenous process. Finally, we analyzed the technological convergence among economies in their catching-up processes and proposed policy implications for the sustainable development of ICT latecomers.

1. Introduction

Driven by the new round of scientific and industrial revolution, economies worldwide are accelerating into the digital economy era. Technological iteration and upgrades in ICT play vital roles in supporting the development of the digital economy in various economies [1,2,3,4]. Governments have always aimed to be at the leading edge of ICT development and innovation. However, few studies have focused on the development process and trajectory of ICT in various economies to analyze the development stages and strategies of different economies. Therefore, from the perspective of the technology life cycle, this study applies an S-curve model to compare and analyze the technology life cycle characteristics and catching-up strategies of latecomer economies in nine sub-fields of ICT, in order to provide theoretical support and policy implications for the sustainable development of various economies.
Many economists have constructed macro- and microeconomic models to discuss the economic growth and catching up of latecomer economies. The earliest studies originated with the economic growth model proposed by Solow in the late 1950s and the early 1960s, which was used to explain the long-term stable growth mechanism of an economy [5]. The study found that technological progress was the main driving force of economic growth. The Solow residual provides a method for measuring the contribution of technological progress to economic growth and lays the foundation for the study of total factor productivity (TFP). Based on Solow’s model, Romer and Lucas proposed endogenous growth theory models in the late 1980s and the early 1990s, respectively. Romer [6] introduced knowledge as an endogenous factor in economic growth and emphasized the internal generation of technological progress and the driving role of innovation. Lucas [7] proposed the role of human capital accumulation in economic growth. On this basis, Aghion and Howitt [8] proposed a creative destruction model that emphasized the driving effect of technological progress on economic growth and explained how technological catching up can be achieved through the innovation and destruction of existing technologies. Similarly, Jones [9] discussed an endogenous growth model based on R&D, emphasized the role of technological innovation in economic growth, and analyzed the relationship between technological catching up and R&D investment.
Based on the above theoretical research, some scholars have tested the convergence of economic growth rates among different regions or countries and the factors influencing economic catching up through empirical research. The economist Robert Barro proposed the Barro Convergence Model [10,11]. The model suggests that the economic growth rate of rich regions may slow, while that of poor regions may accelerate, thus achieving economic convergence. Despite the trend towards convergence, the actual rate of convergence may be influenced by political stability, the level of education, and market openness. Comin and Hobijin’s [12] empirical study showed that the most important determinants of a country’s rate of technology adoption are the country’s human capital endowment, type of government, openness to trade, and adoption of the previous generation of technology. As these variables converge across countries, the overall rate of diffusion increases significantly. Aghion and Howitt [13] tested the important issues of Schumpeterian growth theory using micro-data, including innovation policies, intellectual property protection, education, and R&D incentives, to reveal the driving factors and policy impacts of technological innovation and catching up.
These studies mention the importance of technological progress, technological innovation, R&D investment, and the absorption of advanced technology in economic growth and economic convergence. In recent years, several studies have investigated technological capability gaps and catching-up characteristics among different economies from the perspectives of technology and innovation management. Lee and Lim [14] built a model of technology and market catching up to explain the different technological evolutions of selected industries in Korea. They determined the conditions for catching up to occur. Hu [15] demonstrated that producers in Korea and Taiwan built innovation capabilities by creating complementary knowledge for Japanese firms in thin film transistor liquid crystal displays, and latecomers sought to expand production by selecting certain technological fields. Lee and Malerba [16], Shin [17], Kang and Song [18], and Li et al. [19] adopted a catching-up cycle framework and identified windows of opportunity (technology, demand, or policy) that may emerge during successive changes in a sector. Szczygielski et al. [20] found that government aid for R&D activities contributed to the catching up of technology followers. Cimoli et al. [21] presented a North–South technology gap model that combines the Schumpeterian approach to technical and structural change with the Keynesian perspective on effective demand and the Balance-of-Payments (BOP) constraint as drivers of growth.
However, there are three limitations to the current studies on latecomers’ catching up among economies. First, most studies examine technological catching up by building theoretical frameworks or case studies, and few long-term studies have examined latecomers’ technological catching up in ICT from a longitudinal perspective based on technological life cycle analysis. Existing studies on technological catching up in ICT are conducted using short-term analysis and lack dynamic time-series analysis, especially comparing timeline differences and technological growth speed.
Second, most studies have focused on a single specific sub-field of ICT in which latecomers have been successful in catching up. Although latecomers—particularly Korea and Taiwan—have achieved remarkable technological development (such as semiconductor and consumer electronics), this fact does not hold, nor does it have the same meaning in all technological sectors. Thus, a broad comparative perspective is required across sub-fields and economies to assess ICT technology trajectories.
Third, some studies have discussed the convergence or divergence of economic growth rates among economies and analyzed their driving factors. However, few studies have analyzed the convergence of technological growth rates among latecomers and first movers in different ICT sub-fields. This limits the possibility of revealing the technological gaps and driving factors of technological convergence.
Technological development is a dynamic and cumulative process by which latecomers expand their knowledge base in both scope and depth [22,23,24,25,26]. Latecomers’ catching up is a learning process that includes imitations, adoption, and assimilation of mature technologies from first movers [27,28]. Technology life cycle (TLC) analysis is an important method for analyzing the technology levels of different economies from long-term and dynamic perspectives [29,30]. TLC analysis can map the entire process along the technology development trajectory, including the key time points of each stage and growth rate, which helps reveal the entire process of the technological catching-up cycle from a dynamic perspective. As the catching up of latecomers includes two processes—imitation and indigenous innovation—we depict catching up using two TLC curves.
Thus, this study conducts a longitudinal study on ICT using double TLC curves to examine the catching-up characteristics of latecomer economies, including the take-off time, growth time, growth rate, and ceiling values, using the US as the first mover (benchmark). Furthermore, we examine technological convergence in different ICT sub-fields among different economies and driving factors. We used USPTO-granted patent data from 1960 to 2014 and applied logistic and bi-logistic models to reveal the sequence of technological developments of different economies in different ICT sub-fields and the length of the period during which such sub-fields are sustained and found out the driving forces of technological convergence among latecomers and the first mover for the sustainable development of catching-up economies in ICT.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 defines technological catching up and ICT development background in terms of catching up. Section 3 presents the methodology and data (i.e., the S-curve model, data sources, and ICT sub-fields). Section 4 demonstrates the overall characteristics of the TLCs of economies, including the take-off time, growth rate, and growth time. Section 5 presents the technological convergence analysis, and Section 6 concludes the paper.

2. Catching Up and ICT Development Background

2.1. Conceptualizing Catching Up

The term catching up has been used in macroeconomics to analyze the extent to which the growth of income or productivity of different economies (significantly behind the frontier at the start of the period) enables them to catch up with leading economies (first movers) by the end of the period [31]. Thus, there is a narrowing gap in productivity or income between the first mover and the latecomer. This study also describes this as the process by which a latecomer increases its technological capability (technological catching up) vis-à-vis the first mover. We propose that if knowledge is codified and freely available, latecomer economies will grow faster than first movers because the former will benefit from existing technologies developed by the latter at a lower cost and more rapid pace, thereby reducing the gap between the two [32]. In this regard, we define catching-up economies as those that generate more rapid technological innovation than first movers [33].
Many late-industrializing economies have attempted to create technological innovation to achieve technological growth, despite the unfavorable innovation environment. While most have not progressed much, a few latecomers have shown rapid technological catch-up. In other words, there are falling-behind and standing-still economies. Based on the definition of catching up and the growth rate, falling behind denotes economies with a lower technology growth rate than the first movers, whereas standing still denotes economies with the same growth rate as the first movers. Catching-up economies tend to achieve higher productivity in technological sectors with shorter cycle times and easier access to knowledge, whereas first movers show the opposite.
One common observation from previous research is that catching up is a long process that passes through multiple stages. Some studies proposed that latecomers’ learning processes start with the accumulation of technological capabilities from reverse engineering (i.e., imitation) of foreign technologies to indigenous innovation [34,35]. The paradigm shift from imitation to indigenous innovation necessitates the separation of production into two development cycles to capture two different growth processes [14,19,36]. In the imitation process, latecomers emphasize technological accumulation, during which they develop basic technological capabilities by improving technologies acquired through technology transfers or spillovers from inward FDI [14,22]. In the indigenous innovation process, latecomers can achieve sustained catching up globally when they consider the global market a springboard for acquiring further strategic assets, especially critical technologies, brands, and human resources [14]. With indigenous technological capability building, latecomers can narrow the gap with the first movers in technological innovation and market share in the global market and sustain their initial catching up, as the technology frontier is a moving target that can be easily moved away from latecomers, leading their early catching up to no avail [14,22].

2.2. Catching Up in ICT

ICT has become an important technological and strategic field for governments and has attracted significant attention from policy makers, managers, and researchers [37]. This study focuses on ICT for several reasons. First, ICT is an important driver of economic growth. Research on G20, G7, and the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) member countries has shown that ICT has become a new engine of economic growth in developed economies [1,38,39] and created opportunities for emerging Asian economies, including Korea, China, and Singapore [40].
Second, ICT has attracted considerable attention. In recent decades, emerging Asian economies have implemented policies to promote ICT development during their catching-up periods. For instance, Japan introduced successive national strategies, including the e-Japan Strategy I in 2001, the e-Japan Strategy II in 2003, the u-Japan Initiative in 2004, i-Japan 2015 in 2009, and the Fifth and Sixth Basic Plans for Science and Technology (2016–2020) in 2016. Korea released “IT839” in 2006 to emphasize the development of eight services, three infrastructures, and nine growth engines, which was followed by the “IT future strategy in Korea 2009” (focusing on software, broadcast communication, and broadband network) and “RFID Promotion strategy” in 2011. China took information technology (IT) as one of seven strategic emerging industries in its “Twelfth Five-year Plan” in 2010 and included the digital economy in government reports for five consecutive years since 2017.
Third, ICT has become enabling technology. ICT has boomed in the information age. ICT-based technologies have also enabled the research, development, and growth of technologies in many other fields, such as applied science, engineering, energy, health, and transport. Economies that do not catch up in ICT also fall behind in other ICT-related technologies. As such, findings in the ICT field might translate into other ICT-enabled technologies as well.
In the history of ICT development, the US first introduced numerous radical innovations (including computing, mobile telecommunications, robots, and computer software). Catching up began in the 1970s when some European countries followed the US in some sub-fields. Subsequently, Japan dominated (especially in the field of semiconductors and consumer electronics), followed by Korea and Taiwan. Since then, China, India, and Brazil have grown rapidly.

3. Methodology and Data

3.1. Technology Life Cycle and S-Curve

The notion of the TLC was first introduced by Little [41]. Since then, most studies on TLC analysis have been based on the assumption that a technology or a group of technologies has a cycle from emerging and growth to maturity and recession [42]. Following this assumption, many scholars and practitioners have attempted to predict the future course of a technology using past and present information to chart S-curved or double S-curved progressions [43,44]. Figure 1 shows the S-curve of the TLC in four stages. As stated above, the catching-up processes of latecomers can be reflected as two cycles of trajectories: the imitation process and the indigenous process. Thus, we used a double S-curve to depict the TLC characteristics.
The horizontal axis of the S-curve represents time, and the vertical axis shows the cumulative performance, as shown in Figure 1. In this study, cumulative performance is defined as cumulative technological capability. Based on Schumpeter’s theory of innovation, technological capability can serve as a cause for catching up. Technological capability is the ability of a firm (economy) to transform an idea into a new one with economic value, which is determined as a function of both technological effort and the existing knowledge base [14]. Different from technical efficiency, which is defined as the effectiveness with which a given set of inputs is used to produce an output, technological capability can reflect technological catching-up characteristics more directly.

3.2. Logistic and Bi-Logistic Model

Various growth curves have been used to represent technology life cycles, such as logistics, Gompertz, and Lotka–Volterra competition models, to obtain estimates of the technology’s prospects [25,45,46,47]. The logistic model is representative of a symmetrical S-curve, whereas the Gompertz model produces an S-curve that increases more sharply but begins to taper earlier than the logistic model [48]. The Lotka–Volterra competition model explains multigenerational technology advancement, in which multiple new technologies continue to develop in a particular technology area and then spread. The logistic model originates in the biological realm and is often applied to model the production of technology, given its effectiveness in capturing the changing nature of technological growth [49]. Therefore, we chose the following simple logistic model:
Y t = K 1 + exp b t + c
where Y(t) is the cumulative stock at time t, K is the ceiling value, b is a coefficient depicting the growth rate, and c is a constant that positions the curve on a timescale.
The breakpoints of four stages are indicated by 0K, 0.1K, 0.5K, and 0.9K (emergence, growth, maturity, and recession). T0.1 is the starting time of the growth stage, and T0.9 is the starting time of the recession stage [45]. The equations for T0.1 and T0.9 are as follows:
T 0.1 = c ln 9 b
T 0.9 = c + ln 9 b
The growth time (T0.1–0.9) is defined as the time of the growth and maturity stages, where the ceiling value starts from 0.1K and reaches 0.9K. The formula for T0.1–0.9 is as follows:
T 0.1 0.9 = T 0.9 T 0.1 = ln 81 b
To describe the overall characteristics of the TLC, we used three indicators: ceiling value (K), growth rate (b), and starting time of the growth stage. The ceiling value represents the carrying capacity, the growth rate represents the maximum development speed, and the starting time of the growth stage represents the take-off time of the technology [43,50].
Assuming that catching up includes a shift from imitation to indigenous innovation, each process can be modeled using a simple logistic model. Thus, the bi-logistic model is suitable for modeling catching-up processes. The bi-logistic model is as follows [36]:
Y t = Y 1 t + Y 2 t = K 1 1 + exp d T + e + K 2 1 + exp f T + g
where K1 and K2 are the ceiling values for the first and second processes, respectively; d and f are the growth rates; and e and g are constants.
In this study, we first used a simple logistic model to obtain the overall growth rate of the sample economies, compared it with the growth rate of first movers, and depicted their catching-up (or falling-behind) characteristics. After that, we used a bi-logistic model to compare the growth rate and growth time among latecomers in two catching-up processes to find out the specific sub-fields and processes in which each economy is catching up (or falling behind). Table 1 summarizes these indicators. The indicators of K, 0.9K, 0.5K, 0.1K, T0.1, T0.5, and T0.9 are labeled in Figure 1.
We used computer software called Loglet Lab 4 (https://phe.rockefeller.edu/LogletLab/, accessed on 1 July 2021) to calculate the parameters of the nonlinear logistic model. Comparing with Shazam, MATLAB, and SPSS to manipulate the logistic curve, Loglet Lab 4 operates the data with hundreds of iterations based on a Monte Carlo simulation, making the results highly reliable [45].

3.3. Data

Patent analysis is considered one of the most established, directly available, and historically reliable methods for quantifying the output of a technology system [51]. The advantages of using patent data are as follows. First, they are a direct outcome of the inventive process and, more specifically, of those inventions that are expected to have a commercial impact. Patent data are appropriate for capturing the proprietary and competitive dimensions of technological change. Second, because obtaining patent protection is time-consuming and costly, it is likely that applications are filed for inventions that, on average, are expected to provide benefits that outweigh these costs. Third, patents are broken down by technical field and thus provide information not only on the rate of inventive activity but also on its direction. Fourth, patent statistics are available in large numbers and for long time-series. Although patent-based indicators have limitations, ample research has demonstrated their validity as proxies for measuring technological capabilities.
Within the scope of the S-curve model, the most direct approach is to use the accumulated number of patents as technology develops to fit the growth curves [48,52,53]. It has been found that a cumulative stock of patents over time generally follows an S-shaped curve [53,54]. For example, Anderson [43] fitted logistic growth functions to US patent stocks during 1920–1990, and Liu and Wang [45] applied S-curve models (logistics and Gompertz) to predict the development trend of the biped robot walking technique. Hence, patent data can be used as an index for measuring technological capability [25,29,50].
However, patent counts from different patent offices are not always comparable because of the different patent policies, patenting costs, approval requirements, and enforcement rules for patenting in different economies. A common remedy is to use patent data from a single patent-granting country, such as the US, to standardize the differences between patent offices and the unit of innovation, making cross-country comparisons possible [36]. In this study, we considered only USPTO grant data.
The reasons for choosing the USPTO include the following. (1) As the US represents the largest and the most technologically advanced market in the world, any sufficiently large invention patented anywhere with a global market in mind is likely to be patented in the United States as well [25,33]. (2) A single patent-granting database is necessary to ensure that technological capability across different economies is comparable [25].
We examined catching-up processes over a long period (the past 50–60 years). Because there were two- or three-year time lags from patent publication to grants, we only measured granted patents with publication years between 1960 and 2014. Thus, the cumulative granted patent stock is the dependent variable (Y(t)), and the publication year (1960–2014) is the independent variable (t). We tagged the publication years from 1 to 55 to ensure a more accurate evaluation of the coefficients.
Among the many ICT-related technology classifications, we considered nine growth drivers defined in the IT839 Strategy of the Korean Ministry of Information and Communication [55]. These nine growth drivers are expected to lead to future industrial growth in the future. The nine sub-fields and their USPC concordances are presented in Table 2. This classification was commonly used by Lee, Kim, and Park [56] and certified by Lee, Lee, and Yoon [57]. Therefore, we used this technological classification.
We calculated the total number of ICT patents granted by the USPTO (1960–2014) in all economies worldwide. In the US (1,116,179), Japan (345,924), Korea (78,293), Germany (50,094), Great Britain (32,531), France (27,257), Taiwan (24,239), and China (Mainland) (15,935) the number of patents was greater than 15,000, whereas the number in other economies was less than 6000. As these eight economies have the highest ICT technological capacity, we considered them sample economies (the US, Japan, Korea, Germany, Great Britain, France, Taiwan, and China (Mainland)). The US is regarded as the first mover, and we analyzed the catching-up characteristics of three European economies (Great Britain, Germany, and France) and four Asian economies (Japan, Korea, Taiwan, and China (Mainland)).
Figure 2 shows the number of patents granted to the eight economies in the nine sub-fields. According to Figure 2, there are significant gaps in the number of patents among the economies. The US and Japan have more patents than other economies. The cumulative patent stock in the US is 1,116,179—three times larger than Japan’s (345,924); thus, they are dominant in ICT. Korea, Germany, Great Britain, and France are next, whereas Taiwan and China (Mainland) have the smallest numbers of patents. There are also large gaps in patent numbers among different sub-fields; COM and DTV are relatively larger than the other sub-fields, followed by MOB and SOC; ESW has the smallest patent number.

4. Results Analysis Based on Technology Life Cycle

We fitted a simple logistic model (Equation (1)) and bi-logistic model (Equation (5)) to all nine sub-fields of the eight economies. The t-values of all the coefficients in the logistic model were statistically significant.

4.1. Overall Catching Up Comparison Based on a Simple Logistic Model

We calculated the take-off time, growth rate and time, and ceiling value of the TLC using a simple logistic model (see Appendix A, Table A1, Table A2 and Table A3). Figure 3, Figure 4, Figure 5, Figure 6, Figure 7, Figure 8, Figure 9, Figure 10 and Figure 11 show the overall characteristics of the TLC for the eight economies in each sub-field. The horizontal coordinate denotes the take-off time of the economies, and the vertical coordinate denotes the growth rate. Cumulative patent numbers (1960–2014) and ceiling values are in parentheses.
As shown in Figure 3, Figure 4, Figure 5, Figure 6, Figure 7, Figure 8, Figure 9, Figure 10 and Figure 11 the take-off times in Great Britain, France, Germany, and the US are earlier than those in Asian economies (Japan, Korea, China (Mainland), and Taiwan) in all sub-fields. Among Asian economies, Japan was the earliest economy, taking off in the 1990s, followed by Korea and Taiwan in the 2000s, and China (Mainland) was the latest economy in 2010. The standard deviations of the take-off time of the nine sub-fields for each economy were also calculated (last column in Appendix A, Table A1), which denotes the time differences in the take-off time of different sub-fields. Great Britain (12.80) had the largest standard deviation, followed by the US (11.79), France (11.42), and Germany (9.57). The standard deviations of Western economies (i.e., the US, Great Britain, France, and Germany) are more significant than those of Asian economies—they adopt a non-synchronous development strategy. However, Asian economies (i.e., Japan, Korea, China (Mainland), and Taiwan) develop nine sub-fields nearly simultaneously—they adopt a synchronous development strategy.
The growth rates of Asian economies (Japan, Korea, Taiwan, and China (Mainland)) are over 10%. Japan has a faster growth rate than Western economies; Korea and Taiwan have higher growth rates than Japan, and China (Mainland) has the fastest growth rate—nearly twice that of Korea and Taiwan. These economies accumulate technological capabilities through adoption, assimilation, and rapid learning from mature foreign technologies and grow quickly to catch up with Western economies.
These four Asian economies are typical catching-up economies, as we defined catching-up economies as those whose patent growth rates are higher than those of the first mover (the US). However, it is noteworthy that these economies still have technology gaps in terms of current accumulative patent numbers and ceiling values compared to the US, indicating low technological vitality due to insufficient accumulation at the emerging and growth stages.
By contrast, European economies have the same growth rate as the US in COM, ESW, DTV, RFID, MOB, and ROB, indicating that they are standing still in these six sub-fields. They had a lower growth rate than the US in terms of SOC, NET, and SOL, indicating that they fell behind in these three sub-fields. There is no catching-up sub-field in European economies.
Combining the take-off time and growth rate in a simple logistic model (see Figure 3, Figure 4, Figure 5, Figure 6, Figure 7, Figure 8, Figure 9, Figure 10 and Figure 11), the catching-up pattern presents a flying geese paradigm [58,59,60]. This paradigm postulates that Asian economies will catch up with Western economies as part of the regional hierarchy. The underdeveloped economies in the region could be considered to be “aligned successively behind the advanced economies in the order of their different stages of growth in a wild geese-flying pattern”. The leading geese in this pattern are Japan, a second-tier economy consisting of South Korea and Taiwan, followed by China (Mainland). It may be argued that China (Mainland) is currently benefiting from flying geese patterns, as it takes up manufacturing activities that were formerly undertaken in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan.

4.2. Analysis of Two Catching-Up Processes Based on a bi-Logistic Model

Using the bi-logistic model, we calculated the take-off time, growth rate, time, and ceiling value of two curves for two catching-up processes among seven economies (except the US) in nine sub-fields (see Appendix B, Table A4, Table A5 and Table A6). Figure 12, Figure 13, Figure 14, Figure 15, Figure 16, Figure 17, Figure 18, Figure 19 and Figure 20 show the TLC characteristics of the first and second curves for the seven economies in each sub-field separately. The horizontal axis denotes the take-off time of the first and second curves, and the vertical axis denotes the growth rate of the first and second curves.
We observed distinct patterns in China (Mainland), Korea, and Taiwan. Their take-off time for both curves (imitation and indigenous innovation process) is considerably later than that of the other economies. High growth rates in the first phase reflect rapid imitation. In the second curve (indigenous innovation process), the growth rate of China (Mainland) displays a dramatic increase, which is more than 1 in eight sub-fields (except for ESW, with a growth rate of 0.95, which is slightly less than 1). As higher growth rates imply shorter growth times, the observations suggest that China (Mainland) has difficulty achieving sustainable development because of insufficient accumulation in their imitation stage.
Korea and Taiwan showed dramatic increases in the growth rates of DTV and SOL, which were twice the growth rate of the first curve. In addition, Korea showed an increase in NET and RFID, and Taiwan showed a rise in MOB. For Asian economies, catching up occurs not only in the imitation process but also in the indigenous innovation process. However, although they have higher growth rates than the US, they have shorter growth times. Thus, they must pay more attention to sustainable growth in DTV, SOL, NET, and RFID in Korea, and DTV, SOL, and MOB in Taiwan.
The pattern for Japan is more similar to that of European economies: earlier take-off times (with Great Britain being slightly earlier in the imitation stage) and lower growth rates that do not decrease or increase dramatically, such as China (Mainland), Korea, and Taiwan. Notably, the three European economies are catching up in SOL, with an increased growth rate from the first to the second process. Germany increased its growth rate from the first to the second process in four sub-fields (SOC, NET, ESW, and RFID), whereas Great Britain increased only SOC and NET, and France increased MOB, indicating more positive development trends. The three European economies are standing still in other sub-fields. However, compared to China (Mainland), Korea, and Taiwan, European economies have a longer growth time in both in the first and second processes, presenting sustainable growth.
From the imitation process to the indigenous innovation process, China (Mainland) showed a significant increase in its growth rate in all nine sub-fields. Korea and Taiwan have priority strategies in choosing prior sub-fields for their indigenous innovation processes. Owing to technology fusion and interaction between different sub-fields, advantageous development in a few sub-fields could bring about development in other sub-fields, leading to development in the overall domain. For European economies, there was no significant increase in growth rate from the first to the second process. Considering that it is difficult to develop all sub-fields simultaneously, Europe may need to select priority sub-fields for development. Sub-fields that exhibit higher growth rates in indigenous processes may be preferred.

5. Technological Convergence Analysis

The above research makes a preliminary analysis of the technological catching up of different ICT economies through the technology life cycle model and shows that different economies show differences in the process of technological catching up in the long run. To reflect the catching-up trends and driving factors of different economies in different sub-fields dynamically and comprehensively, we further tested the convergence of different economies in different sub-fields with the help of the β -convergence model, which is used in economic growth convergence analysis.
Convergence research is an important means of studying the distribution of economic growth between economies [10,11], and the most commonly used model is β -convergence. The β -convergence coefficient refers to the speed at which some latecomer indicators catch up with those of first movers. The so-called β -convergence means that if the latecomer grows faster than the first mover, the latecomer will catch up, and there is β -convergence. This study applies β -convergence of economic growth to the distribution of technological growth. The regression equation of β -convergence is:
1 T log y i ,   t y i ,   t T = α + β log y i ,   t T + μ i
Furthermore, the regression equation of β -conditional convergence is:
1 T log y i ,   t y i ,   t T = α + β log y i ,   t T + β i X i + μ i
where i is economy; t is time; T is the length of the observation time; yi,t and yi, t-T represent the number of patents at the end and beginning of the observation period, respectively; and β is the convergence rate. Xi represents the control variables.
Based on previous research, we take corruption (measured by control of corruption, legal environment (measured by rule of law), investment climate (measured by portfolio investment), trade (measured by merchandise trade of GDP), FDI (measured by foreign direct investment, net inflows), education (measured by mean years of schooling), financial development (measured by domestic credit to private sector of GDP), and absorptive capacity (measured by researchers in R&D per billion people) as control variables [61,62,63,64,65,66,67]. All the data were obtained from the World Bank (WDI and WGI) and UNESCO. Owing to the availability of data, the period was 1996–2014.
Table 3 shows the empirical results of β -convergence. It can be seen that eight economies have technological convergence in SOC, COM, DTV, SOL, MOB, and ROB. Asian economies and the United States are also experiencing technological convergence in SOC, COM, DTV, SOL, MOB, and ROB. However, there is no technological convergence between European economies and the US. Thus, it can be seen that Asian economies, as latecomers, tend to converge with the United States in the growth of technological capability through rapid technological development. Table 4, Table 5 and Table 6 show the regression results of conditional convergence with the control variables. Table 4 shows the convergence results for all economies, Table 5 shows the convergence results for the US and European economies, and Table 6 shows the convergence results for the US and Asian economies. Thus, we can conclude that conditional convergence exists among economies in SOL. Education level is an important driver of convergence between European economies and the United States, whereas the legal environment is an important factor in the convergence between Asian economies and the United States.

6. Conclusions, Policy Implications, and Limitations

Based on TLC theory and logistic modeling, this study analyzed the catching-up characteristics of latecomer economies (with the US as the first mover), including take-off time, growth time, growth rate, and ceiling values. The results are summarized as follows.
First, along the take-off timeline, European economies and the US developed first, followed by Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, with China (Mainland) coming later. European economies have non-synchronous ICT development strategies, whereas Asian economies have synchronous ones. In terms of growth rate, Asian economies have a higher growth rate than European economies, showing a flying geese pattern.
Second, China (Mainland) has an increased growth rate from the first to the second process, and Korea and Taiwan have achieved an increase in several sub-fields in the indigenous process. Korea and Taiwan have prioritized strategies when selecting indigenous innovation sub-fields in the second process. In contrast, European economies are standing still from the first to the second process, and a few sub-fields are catching up in the second process.
Third, the technological growth rates of Asian economies are higher than those of the United States and European economies, and there is an obvious convergence with the United States. There is also an obvious catching up between Asian economies and the US in many sub-fields. In the field of SOL, European economies, Asian economies, and the United States have conditional convergence, among which education level is an important factor in the convergence between European economies and the United States, while laws and regulations are important factors in the convergence between Asian economies and the United States.
These findings have several policy implications for latecomers. Asian economies are catching up with Western economies. However, they should pay more attention to sustainability as they have a shorter growth time than Western economies. European economies did not fall behind and could still catch up. Like Korea and Taiwan, they may benefit from paying attention to advantageous sub-fields in the indigenous innovation process.
Some of the limitations inspire further research on this topic. First, this study did not point out the advantageous sub-fields to develop first in European economies in the second process. Further studies could aim to detect the comparative advantage index of each sub-field for European economies and choose the advantageous technology sub-fields as a priority development. Second, this study focused only on the catching-up characteristics in ICT. However, the extent to which these findings are valid for other fields has not yet been discussed. ICT is an enabling technology that can promote the development of other areas within their development trajectories. Thus, the findings might translate to a later take-off time for technology fields highly dependent on or related to ICT, as more time is required to apply and assimilate ICT in their areas. Other fields unrelated to, or enabled by, ICT may present completely different patterns. According to the resource-based view, if an economy focuses on specific fields, it may have fewer resources to develop other fields. Further research should examine catching-up characteristics and timing in other sub-fields related and unrelated to ICT.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, N.Z.; methodology, C.S.; software, C.S. and M.X.; validation, X.W. and J.D.; data curation, C.S. and J.D.; writing—original draft preparation, N.Z.; writing—review and editing, N.Z., C.S. and M.X.; visualization, N.Z.; supervision, N.Z. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by a program of the National Natural Science Foundation of China, grant numbers 72002021 and 42030409, and the China Postdoctoral Science Foundation, grant number 2021M690499.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. The take-Off time for each economy in nine sub-fields (simple logistic model).
Table A1. The take-Off time for each economy in nine sub-fields (simple logistic model).
Take-Off TimeSOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROBStandard
Deviation
United StatesT0.119971995200719871992200820001983196811.79
rank356545432
Great BritainT0.119861971200119751978199819841972195812.80
rank113211211
FranceT0.120011979198919711978200419801977197111.42
rank521114123
GermanyT0.12001198419991979198020011991199019749.57
rank532333354
JapanT0.11996199120011986199720002001198819826.65
rank243452545
KoreaT0.12002200420071999200820102007200619964.29
rank776666766
TaiwanT0.11999200320062002200820102006200720053.14
rank465766677
China (Mainland)T0.12012200920102011201020112010201020081.10
rank888888888
Note: Ranks are based on take-off time of eight economies in each sub-field.
Table A2. The growth rate and time for each economy in nine sub-fields (simple logistic model).
Table A2. The growth rate and time for each economy in nine sub-fields (simple logistic model).
Growth Rate
(Growth Time)
SOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROBAvg.
United Statesb0.130.080.150.080.080.180.080.080.080.11
(34)(54)(30)(54)(54)(25)(54)(54)(53)(46)
Great Britainb0.080.080.090.080.080.180.080.080.080.09
(54)(54)(47)(53)(53)(25)(53)(53)(54)(50)
Franceb0.080.080.080.080.100.120.080.080.080.09
(52)(53)(53)(53)(46)(38)(53)(54)(54)(51)
Germanyb0.090.080.090.080.080.160.080.080.080.09
(51)(53)(52)(54)(53)(27)(53)(53)(54)(50)
Japanb0.160.130.130.140.120.160.110.120.110.13
(28)(35)(34)(32)(38)(28)(41)(36)(39)(35)
Koreab0.230.190.270.200.180.290.260.160.170.22
(20)(23)(16)(22)(24)(15)(17)(28)(26)(21)
Taiwanb0.250.290.410.330.320.290.370.340.290.32
(18)(15)(11)(13)(14)(15)(12)(13)(15)(14)
China (Mainland)b0.550.590.660.400.650.700.750.470.540.59
(8)(8)(7)(11)(7)(6)(6)(9)(8)(8)
Note: Growth times are in parentheses. b is the growth rate.
Table A3. The ceiling values for each economy in nine sub-fields (simple logistic model).
Table A3. The ceiling values for each economy in nine sub-fields (simple logistic model).
Ceiling ValueSOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROB
United StatesK251,748703,141331,80266,859385,901527,474372,802281,31131,309
rank111111111
Great BritainK324870119577163110,0342854714778891268
rank874465564
FranceK88988671389497154693064498882741226
rank557674655
GermanyK18,54021,3029145184210,852237810,52127,3834124
rank445356433
JapanK69,438105,15441,3999300223,35432,55172,28570,10013,327
rank222222222
KoreaK23,77133,80614,327162184,841806718,93825,4751193
rank333533346
TaiwanK5750839593361716,104183928173971469
rank668847877
China (Mainland)K5013620747587134916145131262701410
rank786788788

Appendix B

Table A4. The take-off time in the first and second processes for each economy in nine sub-fields.
Table A4. The take-off time in the first and second processes for each economy in nine sub-fields.
Ceiling ValueSOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROB
United StatesFC196519621974196119671977196419661962
SC199719932002199519932005199719931993
Great BritainFC197519681975196519741978196519711965
SC200119932003198919972004199320001990
FranceFC197019671974196619701976196919691966
SC200219962000199619992006199819971992
GermanyFC197519781976197719751979197719781978
SC200319992005199520032005200319971994
JapanFC199719941996199619941998198319941991
SC200720072010200620082011201020081990
KoreaFC199919972004200219921997200419932002
SC200820082009200920102011201020102009
TaiwanFC199619952006199719961998199619961997
SC201320122013201320122013201220122011
China (Mainland)FC196519621974196119671977196419661962
SC199719932002199519932005199719931993
Note: FC and SC represent the first and second curves, respectively.
Table A5. The growth rate and growth time in two processes for each economy in nine sub-fields.
Table A5. The growth rate and growth time in two processes for each economy in nine sub-fields.
Growth Rate
(Growth Time)
SOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROB
Great Britaind0.18
(24)
0.17
(26)
0.17
(26)
0.18
(25)
0.17
(26)
0.19
(23)
0.17
(26)
0.17
(26)
0.18
(24)
f0.21
(21)
0.17
(26)
0.25
(18)
0.19
(23)
0.18
(25)
0.45
(10)
0.18
(24)
0.18
(25)
0.17
(25)
Franced0.18
(25)
0.17
(27)
0.18
(25)
0.21
(21)
0.17
(26)
0.2
(22)
0.17
(26)
0.17
(26)
0.2
(23)
f0.18
(24)
0.18
(25)
0.18
(25)
0.17
(25)
0.18
(24)
0.35
(13)
0.17
(26)
0.20
(22)
0.18
(25)
Germanyd0.17
(26)
0.17
(26)
0.18
(25)
0.17
(25)
0.17
(26)
0.18
(24)
0.18
(25)
0.17
(26)
0.19
(23)
f0.28
(16)
0.18
(24)
0.21
(21)
0.24
(19)
0.18
(25)
0.44
(10)
0.24
(19)
0.19
(23)
0.17
(26)
Japand0.18
(25)
0.23
(19)
0.20
(22)
0.21
(21)
0.18
(25)
0.19
(23)
0.21
(21)
0.24
(18)
0.23
(19)
f0.32
(14)
0.25
(18)
0.32
(14)
0.22
(20)
0.27
(16)
0.41
(11)
0.30
(15)
0.20
(22)
0.18
(24)
Koread0.51
(9)
0.41
(11)
0.39
(11)
0.44
(10)
0.35
(13)
0.45
(10)
0.21
(21)
0.45
(10)
0.33
(13)
f0.48
(9)
0.45
(10)
0.74
(6)
0.36
(12)
0.51
(9)
0.75
(6)
0.68
(6)
0.40
(11)
0.34
(13)
Taiwand0.58
(8)
0.51
(9)
0.72
(6)
0.58
(8)
0.31
(14)
0.42
(10)
0.78
(6)
0.32
(14)
0.59
(7)
f0.51
(9)
0.55
(8)
0.66
(7)
0.67
(7)
0.78
(6)
0.79
(6)
0.61
(7)
0.75
(6)
0.64
(7)
China (Mainland)d0.35
(12)
0.34
(13)
0.81
(5)
0.41
(11)
0.36
(12)
0.43
(10)
0.38
(12)
0.35
(13)
0.51
(9)
f1.46
(3)
1.35
(3)
1.53
(3)
0.95
(5)
1.55
(3)
1.19
(4)
1.49
(3)
1.33
(3)
1.17
(4)
Note: d and f are the growth rates of the first and second curves, respectively. Growth times are in parentheses. d is growth rate for the first process; f is growth rate for the second process.
Table A6. The ceiling values in the first and second processes for each economy in nine sub-fields.
Table A6. The ceiling values in the first and second processes for each economy in nine sub-fields.
Ceiling ValueSOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROB
Great BritainK14372176681407227147111192473744
K215474393260010155338142642464319580
FranceK1588196371625222262059472827376
K2294743882441560300666828064831659
GermanyK1124835716734282864303119334431090
K2406711,297257787171161032373311,6562366
JapanK111,67218,7914082205226,8084277586312,5073931
K237,75559,09515,613625594,83213,41519,52643,3788852
KoreaK1402238991665345552657419492006366
K212,64114,354530198220,954233773638454801
TaiwanK1219115711872801894129587445100
K232975295589309707260618171628262
China (Mainland)K1325108563551.273720957236063.9
K21592337623263052438104919281172235

References

  1. Laursen, K.; Meliciani, V. The role of ICT knowledge flows for international market share dynamics. Res. Policy 2010, 39, 687–697. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. OECD. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2017: The Digital Transformation; OECD: Paris, France, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  3. Sun, Y.; Grimes, S. China and Global Value Chains: Globalization and the Information and Communications Technology Sector; Routledge: London, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  4. Tseng, C.Y. Technological innovation and knowledge network in Asia: Evidence from comparison of information and communication technologies among six countries. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2009, 76, 654–663. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Solow, R.M. A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Q. J. Econ. 1956, 1, 65–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Romer, P.M. Increasing returns and long-run growth. J. Political Econ. 1986, 5, 1002–1037. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Lucas, R. Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? Am. Econ. Rev. 1990, 2, 92–96. [Google Scholar]
  8. Aghion, P.; Howitt, P. A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 1992, 2, 323–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Jones, C.I. R&D-based models of economic growth. J. Political Econ. 1995, 4, 759–784. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Barro, R.J. Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Q. J. Econ. 1991, 2, 407–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Barro, R.J.; Sala-i-Martin, X.X. Technological Diffusion, Convergence, and Growth. J. Econ. Growth 1997, 2, 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Comin, D.A.; Hobijn, B. Cross-country technology adoption: Making the theories face the facts. J. Monet. Econ. 2004, 1, 39–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Aghion, P.; Howitt, P. Joseph Schumpeter lecture: Appropriate growth policy: A unifying framework. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2006, 2–3, 269–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Lee, K.; Lim, C. Technological regimes, catching-up and leapfrogging: Findings from the Korean industries. Res. Policy 2001, 30, 459–483. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Hu, M.C. Technological innovation capabilities in the thin film transistor-liquid crystal display industries of Japan, Korea, and Taiwan. Res. Policy 2012, 41, 541–555. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Lee, K.; Malerba, F. Catch-up cycles and changes in industrial leadership: Windows of opportunity and responses of firms and countries in the evolution of sectoral systems. Res. Policy 2017, 46, 338–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Shin, J. Dynamic catch-up strategy, capability expansion and changing windows of opportunity in the memory industry. Res. Policy 2017, 2, 404–416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Kang, H.; Song, J. Innovation and recurring shifts in industrial leadership: Three phases of change and persistence in the camera industry. Res. Policy 2017, 2, 376–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Li, D.; Capone, G.; Malerba, F. The long march to catch-up: A history-friendly model of China’s mobile communications industry. Res. Policy 2019, 48, 649–664. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Szczygielski, K.; Grabowski, W.; Pamukcu, M.T.; Tandogan, V.S. Does government support for private innovation matter? Firm-level evidence from two catching-up countries. Res. Policy 2017, 46, 219–237. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Cimoli, M.; Pereima, J.B.; Porcile, G. A technology gap interpretation of growth paths in Asia and Latin America. Res. Policy 2019, 48, 125–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Guo, L.; Zhang, M.Y.; Dodgson, M.; Gann, D.; Cai, H. Seizing windows of opportunity by using technology-building and market-seeking strategies in tandem: Huawei’s sustained catch-up in the global market. Asia Pac. J. Manag. 2019, 36, 849–879. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Cantwell, J. Innovation and international business. Ind. Innov. 2017, 24, 41–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Castellacci, F. Innovation, diffusion and catching up in the fifth long wave. Futures 2006, 38, 841–863. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  25. Huang, Y.; Li, R.; Zou, F.; Jiang, L.; Porter, A.L.; Zhang, L. Technology life cycle analysis: From the dynamic perspective of patent citation networks. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2022, 181, 121760. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Malhotra, A.; Zhang, H.; Beuse, M.; Schmidt, T. How do new use environments influence a technology’s knowledge trajectory? A patent citation network analysis of lithium-ion battery technology. Res. Policy 2021, 50, 104318. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Choung, J.Y.; Hwang, H.R.; Choi, J.K. Post catch-up system transition failure: The case of ICT technology development in Korea. Asian J. Technol. Innov. 2016, 24, 78–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Ryu, J.; Byeon, S.C. Technology level evaluation methodology based on the technology growth curve. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2011, 78, 1049–1059. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Wittfoth, S.; Berger, T.; Moehrle, M.G. Revisiting the innovation dynamics theory: How effectiveness-and efficiency-oriented process innovations accompany product innovations. Technovation 2022, 112, 102410. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Huenteler, J.; Schmidt, T.S.; Ossenbrink, J.; Hoffmann, V.H. Technology life-cycles in the energy sector—Technological characteristics and the role of deployment for innovation. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2016, 104, 102–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Malerba, F.; Nelson, R. Learning and catching up in different sectoral systems: Evidence from six industries. Ind. Corp. Chang. 2011, 20, 1645–1675. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  32. Guennif, S.; Ramani, S.V. Explaining divergence in catching-up in pharma between India and Brazil using the NSI framework. Res. Policy 2012, 41, 430–441. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Park, K.H.; Lee, K. Linking the technological regime to the technological catch-up: Analyzing Korea and Taiwan using the US patent data. Ind. Corp. Chang. 2006, 15, 715–753. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Kim, L. Imitation to Innovation: The Dynamics of Korea’s Technological Learning; Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  35. Yap, X.; Truffer, B. Shaping selection environments for industrial catch-up and sustainability transitions: A systemic perspective on endogenizing windows of opportunity. Res. Policy 2019, 48, 1030–1047. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Wong, C.Y.; Goh, K.L. The sustainability of functionality development of science and technology: Papers and patents of emerging economies. J. Inf. 2012, 6, 55–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Daiyue, H.; Chao, L.; Puel, G. Spatial Environmental Balance to Information and Communication Technology products in different regions of China by using LCA. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 91, 128–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Colecchia, A.; Schreyer, P. The contribution of information and communication technologies to economic growth in nine OECD countries. OECD Econ. Stud. 2002, 2003, 153–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Bassanini, A.; Scarpetta, S. Growth, technological change, and ICT diffusion: Recent evidence from OECD countries. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 2002, 18, 324–344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Carayannis, E.G.; Sagi, J. Exploiting opportunities of the new economy: Developing nations in support of the ICT industry. Technovation 2002, 22, 517–524. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Little, A.D. The Strategic Management of Technology. Arthur D. Little: Cambridge, UK, 1981. [Google Scholar]
  42. Kalthaus, M. Knowledge recombination along the technology life cycle. J. Evol. Econ. 2020, 30, 643–704. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Andersen, B. The hunt for S-shaped growth paths in technological innovation: A patent study. J. Evol. Econ. 1999, 9, 487–526. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Kucharavy, D.; De Guio, R. Logistic substitution model and technological forecasting. Procedia Eng. 2011, 9, 402–416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  45. Liu, C.Y.; Wang, J.C. Forecasting the development of the biped robot walking technique in Japan through S-curve model analysis. Scientometrics 2010, 82, 21–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Kwasnicki, W. Logistic growth of the global economy and competitiveness of nations. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2013, 80, 50–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Sood, A.; James, G.M.; Tellis, G.J.; Zhu, J. Predicting the path of technological innovation: SAW vs. Moore, Bass, Gompertz, and Kryder. Mark. Sci. 2012, 31, 964–979. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Lin, D.; Liu, W.; Guo, Y.; Meyer, M. Using technological entropy to identify technology life cycle. J. Inf. 2021, 15, 101137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Adamuthe, A.C.; Thampi, G.T. Technology forecasting: A case study of computational technologies. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2019, 143, 181–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Byun, J.; Sung, T.E.; Park, H.W. Technological innovation strategy: How do technology life cycles change by technological area. Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag. 2018, 30, 98–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Soete, L.; Wyatt, S. The use of foreign patenting as an internationally comparable science and technology output indicator. Scientometrics 1983, 5, 31–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Chen, Y.H.; Chen, C.Y.; Lee, S.C. Technology forecasting and patent strategy of hydrogen energy and fuel cell technologies. Int. J. Hydrog. Energy 2011, 36, 6957–6969. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Ernst, H. The use of patent data for technological forecasting: The diffusion of CNC-technology in the machine tool industry. Small Bus. Econ. 1997, 9, 361–381. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Rezaeian, M.; Montazeri, H.; Loonen, R.C. Science foresight using life-cycle analysis, text mining and clustering: A case study on natural ventilation. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2017, 118, 270–280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. International Telecommunication Union (ITU). Measuring the Information Society: The ICT Development Index; International Telecommunication Union: Geneva, Switzerland, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  56. Lee, S.; Kim, M.S.; Park, Y. ICT Co-evolution and Korean ICT strategy—An analysis based on patent data. Telecommun. Policy 2009, 33, 253–271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Lee, H.; Lee, S.; Yoon, B. Technology clustering based on evolutionary patterns: The case of information and communications technologies. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2011, 78, 953–967. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Linden, G.; Hart, J.; Lenway, S.A.; Murtha, T.P. Flying geese as moving targets: Are Korea and Taiwan catching up with Japan in advanced displays? Ind. Innov. 1998, 1, 11–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Kiyoshi, K. The “flying geese” model of Asian economic development: Origin, theoretical extensions, and regional policy implications. J. Asian Econ. 2000, 11, 375–401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Wong, C.Y.; Goh, K.L. Modeling the behaviour of science and technology: Self-propagating growth in the diffusion process. Scientometrics 2010, 84, 669–686. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Ahmad, N. Corrupt clubs and the convergence hypothesis. J. Econ. Policy Reform. 2008, 11, 21–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Khan, F.A.; Hudson, J. Initial human capital or the rule of law: What matters for the income convergence of poor countries? Appl. Econ. 2014, 46, 179–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  63. Ben-David, D. Trade liberalization and income convergence: A comment. J. Int. Econ. 2001, 55, 229–234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Choi, C. Foreign direct investment and income convergence. Appl. Econ. 2004, 36, 1045–1049. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Demetriades, P.O.; Hussein, K.A. Does financial development cause economic growth? Time-series evidence from 16 countries. J. Dev. Econ. 1996, 51, 387–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Bartkowska, M.; Riedl, A. Regional convergence clubs in Europe: Identification and conditioning factors. Econ. Model. 2012, 29, 22–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  67. Li, J.; Kozhikode, R.K. Knowledge management and innovation strategy: The challenge for latecomers in emerging economies. Asia Pac. J. Manag. 2008, 25, 429–450. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. S-curve of TLC.
Figure 1. S-curve of TLC.
Sustainability 15 09038 g001
Figure 2. The patent numbers of eight economies in nine sub-fields.
Figure 2. The patent numbers of eight economies in nine sub-fields.
Sustainability 15 09038 g002
Figure 3. TLC characteristics in SOC. Note: US, FR, GB, DE, JP, KR, CN, and TW are short for the United States, France, Great Britain, Germany, Japan, Korea, China (Mainland), and Taiwan, respectively.
Figure 3. TLC characteristics in SOC. Note: US, FR, GB, DE, JP, KR, CN, and TW are short for the United States, France, Great Britain, Germany, Japan, Korea, China (Mainland), and Taiwan, respectively.
Sustainability 15 09038 g003
Figure 4. TLC characteristics in COM.
Figure 4. TLC characteristics in COM.
Sustainability 15 09038 g004
Figure 5. TLC characteristics in NET.
Figure 5. TLC characteristics in NET.
Sustainability 15 09038 g005
Figure 6. TLC characteristics in ESW.
Figure 6. TLC characteristics in ESW.
Sustainability 15 09038 g006
Figure 7. TLC characteristics in DTV.
Figure 7. TLC characteristics in DTV.
Sustainability 15 09038 g007
Figure 8. TLC characteristics in SOL.
Figure 8. TLC characteristics in SOL.
Sustainability 15 09038 g008
Figure 9. TLC characteristics in RFID.
Figure 9. TLC characteristics in RFID.
Sustainability 15 09038 g009
Figure 10. TLC characteristics in MOB.
Figure 10. TLC characteristics in MOB.
Sustainability 15 09038 g010
Figure 11. TLC characteristics in ROB.
Figure 11. TLC characteristics in ROB.
Sustainability 15 09038 g011
Figure 12. TLC characteristics in the two curves in SOC. Note: The first and second curves are represented by blue circles and red diamonds, respectively; growth times are in parentheses. The dotted arrows represent the shift from the first to the second curve.
Figure 12. TLC characteristics in the two curves in SOC. Note: The first and second curves are represented by blue circles and red diamonds, respectively; growth times are in parentheses. The dotted arrows represent the shift from the first to the second curve.
Sustainability 15 09038 g012
Figure 13. TLC characteristics in two curves in COM.
Figure 13. TLC characteristics in two curves in COM.
Sustainability 15 09038 g013
Figure 14. TLC characteristics in the two curves in NET.
Figure 14. TLC characteristics in the two curves in NET.
Sustainability 15 09038 g014
Figure 15. TLC characteristics in two curves in ESW.
Figure 15. TLC characteristics in two curves in ESW.
Sustainability 15 09038 g015
Figure 16. TLC characteristics in the two curves in DTV.
Figure 16. TLC characteristics in the two curves in DTV.
Sustainability 15 09038 g016
Figure 17. TLC characteristics in two curves in SOL.
Figure 17. TLC characteristics in two curves in SOL.
Sustainability 15 09038 g017
Figure 18. TLC characteristics in the two curves in RFID.
Figure 18. TLC characteristics in the two curves in RFID.
Sustainability 15 09038 g018
Figure 19. TLC characteristics in two curves in MOB.
Figure 19. TLC characteristics in two curves in MOB.
Sustainability 15 09038 g019
Figure 20. TLC characteristics in the two curves in ROB.
Figure 20. TLC characteristics in the two curves in ROB.
Sustainability 15 09038 g020
Table 1. Summary of all indicators.
Table 1. Summary of all indicators.
SymbolIndicatorMeaning of Indicator
KCeiling valueCarrying capacity
bGrowth rateMaximum development speed
T0.1Starting time of the
growth stage
Take-off time of the technology
T0.5Starting time of the maturity stage
T0.9Starting time of the recession stage
T0.1–0.9The time of the growth stage and maturity stageGrowth time
K1Ceiling values for the first process
K2Ceiling values for the second process
dGrowth rate for the first process
fGrowth rate for the second process
Table 2. ICT sub-fields and USPC concordance.
Table 2. ICT sub-fields and USPC concordance.
ICT Sub-FieldAbbreviationUSPC Classes
Mobile telecom/telematicsMOB340, 375, 379, 701
Broadband/home networkNET370
Digital television/broadcastingDTV345, 348, 349, 353, 367, 381, 382, 386
Computing/auxiliariesCOM235, 361, 365, 700, 708, 710, 713, 714, 719
Intelligent robotROB318, 706
Radio frequency identificationRFID342, 343, 455
ubiquitous sensor network
Information technology system on chip/united partsSOC438, 711, 716
Embedded softwareESW341, 712
Digital content/software solutionsSOL705, 707, 715, 717
Table 3. Regression results based on β -convergence model.
Table 3. Regression results based on β -convergence model.
Economies SOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROB
β−0.009 **−0.024 ***0.016 ***−0.000−0.007 *−0.021 **−0.002−0.021 ***−0.009 *
(−2.28)(−4.09)(2.77)(−0.00)(−1.89)(−2.29)(−0.44)(−3.79)(−1.73)
AllConstant0.209 ***0.271 ***0.0080.085 ***0.141 ***0.344 ***0.133 ***0.215 ***0.098 ***
(9.15)(6.76)(0.26)(4.06)(5.77)(7.17)(4.26)(6.26)(4.09)
Observations126126126126126126126126126
R-squared0.0400.1190.0580.0000.0280.0400.0020.1040.024
β0.0040.0080.038 ***0.0060.009 ***−0.0120.0070.009 *0.013 *
(0.87)(1.63)(5.28)(1.02)(2.72)(−1.13)(1.00)(1.91)(1.70)
US, Constant0.113 ***0.006−0.166 ***0.051 *0.0060.269 ***0.032−0.008−0.017
European (4.53)(0.17)(−4.11)(1.80)(0.31)(4.76)(0.73)(−0.27)(−0.50)
economiesObservations727272727272727272
R-squared0.0110.0360.2850.0150.0960.0180.0140.0500.040
β−0.017 ***−0.031 ***0.005−0.003−0.016 ***−0.024 **−0.008−0.028 ***−0.017 ***
(−3.83)(−4.56)(0.92)(−0.49)(−3.82)(−2.22)(−1.51)(−4.29)(−3.16)
US, Constant0.291 ***0.371 ***0.126 ***0.106 ***0.240 ***0.393 ***0.205 ***0.293 ***0.155 ***
Asian (9.71)(7.63)(3.88)(3.87)(7.83)(6.25)(5.95)(6.91)(5.80)
economiesObservations727272727272727272
R-squared0.1740.2290.0120.0030.1720.0660.0310.2080.125
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 4. Regression results based on β -conditional convergence model among all economies.
Table 4. Regression results based on β -conditional convergence model among all economies.
SOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROB
β0.013 *0.0160.029 ***0.0180.031 ***−0.083 ***0.029 ***0.0020.007
(1.73)(1.62)(2.93)(1.52)(4.33)(−4.61)(2.80)(0.13)(0.60)
Corruption−0.090 **−0.113 ***−0.112 ***−0.107 **0.045−0.554 ***−0.109 ***0.012−0.071 *
(−2.50)(−2.83)(−2.64)(−2.55)(1.49)(−7.80)(−2.64)(0.24)(−1.79)
Legal environment−0.014−0.155 ***−0.095 *0.035−0.088 **0.0740.035−0.203 ***−0.087
(−0.34)(−2.81)(−1.75)(0.71)(−2.49)(0.76)(0.64)(−3.28)(−1.63)
Investment climate0.000−0.000−0.0000.0000.000−0.000 *0.000−0.000−0.000
(0.36)(−1.06)(−0.33)(0.62)(1.54)(−1.77)(1.39)(−0.02)(−0.43)
Trade−0.001−0.0000.002 **0.0000.002 ***−0.007 ***0.003 ***0.001−0.000
(−1.15)(−0.37)(2.19)(0.02)(2.81)(−4.00)(2.99)(0.58)(−0.30)
FDI0.000−0.0000.000−0.000−0.0000.0000.0000.0000.000
(0.36)(−0.19)(1.33)(−0.61)(−0.01)(1.10)(0.45)(1.10)(0.07)
Education0.026 **0.061 ***0.040 ***0.042 ***−0.0090.229 ***0.0040.036 **0.051 ***
(2.19)(4.98)(3.08)(3.06)(−0.93)(10.19)(0.28)(2.13)(3.40)
Financial development−0.001 ***−0.001 ***0.000−0.0010.000−0.003 ***0.000−0.000−0.001 *
(−2.99)(−2.82)(0.03)(−1.51)(1.31)(−3.80)(0.62)(−0.69)(−1.88)
Absorptive capacity−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000−0.000 *−0.000−0.000 **
(−2.74)(−2.72)(−0.82)(−4.40)(−3.28)(−1.44)(−1.85)(−0.67)(−2.44)
Constant0.222 ***−0.067−0.332 ***−0.0790.0630.393 ***−0.033−0.052−0.112
(3.67)(−0.86)(−4.19)(−1.09)(1.25)(6.25)(−0.42)(−0.58)(−1.45)
Observations126126126126126126126126126
R-squared0.5200.5880.5740.3470.5660.5770.4510.4090.350
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 5. Regression results based on β -conditional convergence model among European economies and the US.
Table 5. Regression results based on β -conditional convergence model among European economies and the US.
SOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROB
β0.017−0.029 ***0.009−0.0130.017 *−0.106 ***0.042 *0.0090.001
(1.58)(−2.92)(0.44)(−1.03)(1.91)(−6.20)(1.79)(0.72)(0.05)
Corruption0.0770.0130.091−0.0220.034−0.267 ***0.202 *0.099 *0.024
(1.21)(0.37)(0.93)(−0.39)(0.91)(−2.73)(2.00)(1.68)(0.25)
Legal environment−0.185−0.136−0.1670.192 *0.117 *0.165−0.060−0.199 *−0.238
(−1.56)(−1.54)(−0.99)(1.80)(1.72)(0.91)(−0.34)(−1.97)(−1.48)
Investment climate0.0000.000−0.000−0.0000.000−0.0000.0000.0000.000
(1.39)(0.40)(−0.02)(−0.09)(0.59)(−1.41)(1.42)(0.85)(0.41)
Trade0.001−0.001−0.000−0.004 ***−0.001−0.014 ***0.005 **0.0020.001
(0.76)(−0.92)(−0.19)(−2.67)(−1.16)(−5.29)(2.14)(1.36)(0.55)
FDI0.0000.0000.0000.000−0.0000.0000.0000.000−0.000
(0.56)(0.91)(1.44)(0.21)(−0.09)(1.06)(1.33)(1.22)(−0.36)
Education−0.0020.047 ***0.0190.045 ***0.0010.204 ***−0.055 **0.0140.037
(−0.08)(5.92)(0.76)(2.82)(0.09)(8.43)(−2.09)(0.80)(1.21)
Financial development0.0000.0010.000−0.001−0.001−0.003 ***0.0010.0000.001
(0.39)(1.36)(0.09)(−1.65)(−1.44)(−2.72)(1.51)(0.72)(0.69)
Absorptive capacity−0.000 ***−0.000 *0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 *−0.000−0.000−0.000−0.000 **
(−2.66)(−1.71)(2.86)(−4.32)(−1.72)(−1.27)(−0.78)(−0.68)(−2.37)
Constant0.357 ***−0.079−0.502 ***−0.109−0.090−0.583 ***−0.019−0.1270.042
(3.06)(−0.95)(−2.96)(−1.00)(−1.26)(−3.18)(−0.10)(−1.21)(0.26)
Observations727272727272727272
R-squared0.2930.5690.4960.6090.4170.7680.1400.3710.263
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 6. Regression results based on β -conditional convergence model among Asian economies and the US.
Table 6. Regression results based on β -conditional convergence model among Asian economies and the US.
SOCCOMNETESWDTVSOLRFIDMOBROB
β0.026 *0.037 *0.058 ***0.074 ***0.038 ***−0.061 **0.047 ***0.0290.049 ***
(1.82)(1.91)(5.42)(3.31)(2.90)(−2.17)(3.52)(1.13)(2.70)
Corruption−0.065−0.070−0.131 **−0.108 *−0.013−0.375 ***−0.194 ***−0.014−0.076
(−1.21)(−0.84)(−2.55)(−1.78)(−0.23)(−3.14)(−3.54)(−0.14)(−1.28)
Legal environment0.0140.050−0.0830.067−0.0690.348 *−0.022−0.0510.049
(0.17)(0.39)(−1.07)(0.75)(−0.82)(1.93)(−0.25)(−0.33)(0.55)
Investment climate0.000−0.0000.0000.0000.000−0.0000.000−0.000−0.000
(0.57)(−0.32)(0.37)(0.56)(0.61)(−0.02)(0.44)(−0.09)(−0.47)
Trade−0.001−0.0020.002 **−0.0000.001−0.0020.002 *−0.001−0.001
(−1.31)(−0.95)(2.18)(−0.03)(0.46)(−1.01)(1.67)(−0.47)(−0.39)
FDI0.0000.000−0.000 *−0.0000.0000.001−0.0000.0000.000
(0.50)(0.42)(−1.68)(−0.96)(0.39)(1.51)(−1.62)(0.59)(0.42)
Education−0.002−0.0440.050 *−0.018−0.0160.0970.041−0.042−0.029
(−0.05)(−0.86)(1.71)(−0.50)(−0.50)(1.49)(1.26)(−0.67)(−0.88)
Financial development−0.002 ***−0.003 ***0.000−0.002 ***−0.000−0.005 ***0.000−0.002−0.002 ***
(−3.67)(−3.44)(0.31)(−3.15)(−0.25)(−3.72)(0.41)(−1.39)(−3.74)
Absorptive capacity−0.0000.000−0.000 ***−0.000−0.000−0.000−0.000 ***0.0000.000
(−1.00)(0.37)(−3.34)(−1.21)(−0.79)(−0.18)(−2.68)(0.63)(0.23)
Constant0.504 **0.848 **−0.394 *0.3970.1760.275−0.2850.6040.531 **
(2.04)(2.27)(−1.75)(1.47)(0.73)(0.53)(−1.11)(1.32)(2.13)
Observations727272727272727272
R-squared0.6300.5930.7000.5280.5340.7000.6740.3830.533
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhang, N.; Sun, C.; Xu, M.; Wang, X.; Deng, J. Catching Up of Latecomer Economies in ICT for Sustainable Development: An Analysis Based on Technology Life Cycle Using Patent Data. Sustainability 2023, 15, 9038. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15119038

AMA Style

Zhang N, Sun C, Xu M, Wang X, Deng J. Catching Up of Latecomer Economies in ICT for Sustainable Development: An Analysis Based on Technology Life Cycle Using Patent Data. Sustainability. 2023; 15(11):9038. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15119038

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhang, Na, Chao Sun, Min Xu, Xuemei Wang, and Jia Deng. 2023. "Catching Up of Latecomer Economies in ICT for Sustainable Development: An Analysis Based on Technology Life Cycle Using Patent Data" Sustainability 15, no. 11: 9038. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15119038

APA Style

Zhang, N., Sun, C., Xu, M., Wang, X., & Deng, J. (2023). Catching Up of Latecomer Economies in ICT for Sustainable Development: An Analysis Based on Technology Life Cycle Using Patent Data. Sustainability, 15(11), 9038. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15119038

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop