1. Introduction
Global climate change has emerged as an unprecedented challenge to human societies and natural systems [
1]. Global average surface temperatures have risen by 1.1 °C since pre-industrial levels, driven primarily by anthropogenic greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions—of which carbon dioxide (CO
2) accounts for nearly 77%, largely from fossil fuel combustion [
2]. In this context, terrestrial ecosystems—especially forests—play a critical role in mitigating climate change. Forests not only store approximately 861 petagrams (Pg) of carbon, representing 40% of the terrestrial carbon pool, but also act as dynamic carbon sinks that annually absorb around 50% of global fossil fuel emissions [
3,
4].
As the world’s largest GHG emitter, China has committed to reaching peak carbon emissions by 2030 and achieving carbon neutrality by 2060 [
5]. In support of this, the country has implemented major renewable energy transitions alongside large-scale ecological initiatives, such as the Three-North Shelter Forest Program and the Grain-for-Green Program [
6]. These efforts have significantly enhanced China’s forest carbon sink, contributing over 1.2 billion tonnes of CO
2 in annual absorption, nearly 10% of the national total. Projections suggest that, with improved forest governance, annual forest carbon sequestration could offset up to 45% of residual fossil fuel emissions by 2060 [
7].
Reaching carbon neutrality requires both emission reduction and carbon sink enhancement. While emission control relies on clean energy and efficiency improvements, carbon sink enhancement depends on afforestation, ecological restoration, and carbon capture [
8,
9,
10]. Forests are the most effective terrestrial carbon sinks, accounting for approximately 62% of total land-based CO
2 absorption [
11].
Forest carbon sink is an effective way to harmonize economic development and reduce GHG emissions. In China, ecological compensation mechanisms have been strengthened to incentivize carbon sequestration through forest conservation [
12]. Recent policies aim to better incorporate ecosystem service values into market-based instruments such as carbon trading [
13]. However, monetizing the value of forest carbon sink remains difficult due to volatile prices, high policy dependence, and fragmented market mechanisms.
The valuation of forest carbon sink involves two main components: carbon stock estimation and carbon price forecasting [
14]. Existing accounting approaches include biomass surveys, volume expansion, and remote sensing [
15]. Recent models incorporate species-specific data and spatial extensions, improving precision [
16,
17,
18]. In forecasting, machine learning, regression, and hybrid models are increasingly applied, while valuation typically uses net present value (NPV) or the Black–Scholes approach [
15,
19]. NPV discounts all expected carbon-credit revenues (or avoided-damage benefits) and lifecycle costs to a common base year, thereby capturing both the time value of money and market-volume dynamics; its applications range from stand-level decisions—such as optimizing rotation age under a carbon price—to national policy assessments. For example, Haight et al. reported that afforestation yielded the highest marginal benefit–cost ratio among three U.S. federal mitigation scenarios for 2015–2050 [
20], whereas Guan et al. showed that Yunnan’s subtropical pine plantations will become profitable once the carbon price exceeds CNY 60 t
−1 CO
2 under China’s dual-carbon strategy [
21]. Comparable provincial studies in Heilongjiang, Liaoning, and Beijing pair GM (1,1) stock forecasts with NPV analysis to probe discount-rate sensitivity. Although the Black–Scholes model—originally designed for financial derivatives—remains robust for valuing carbon assets under high price volatility, NPV is generally preferred by policymakers for its intuitive cost–benefit metric and capacity to incorporate endogenously determined price paths [
22,
23]. Nonetheless, city-scale, market-reflective pricing frameworks are still scarce, underscoring the relevance of the approach advanced in this study.
The GM (1,1) model is well-suited to forecasting forest carbon sinks when only short, noisy time series are available. The model first applies an Accumulated Generating Operation (AGO) to the raw carbon sink time series, which smooths random fluctuations and reveals the underlying exponential growth law of biomass carbon storage [
24]. GM (1,1) then fits a first-order differential equation to the AGO sequence and analytically solves it to obtain closed-form forecasts that can be inverse-transformed to the original scale. This procedure requires as few as four observations and no prior assumptions about data distribution, overcoming the minimum-sample limitations of methods such as ARIMA or machine-learning algorithms that demand larger, stationary datasets. Empirical studies in forest stands and other regions show that GM (1,1) can keep its mean absolute percentage error below 10% with data lengths of 5–8 years, outperforming conventional time series models in equally small samples [
21,
25,
26].
On the policy front, carbon sink mechanisms like ecological compensation, carbon credits, and forest-based offsets have shown promise but remain underdeveloped in much of inland China [
27]. The Loess Plateau, while a key ecological zone, faces challenges in sustaining restoration gains due to limited financial inputs, uneven benefit distribution, and weak project governance [
28,
29,
30,
31]. These issues weaken long-term restoration outcomes and hinder the economic realization of ecological benefits.
Shenmu City, located in the northern Loess Plateau, is a typical resource-based city, assessing its forest carbon sink potential and economic value, which is particularly significant. Between 2000 and 2020, carbon sequestration capacity increased due to afforestation efforts. Yet, the economic value of FCS in the region remains largely unrealized. Major constraints include high costs, low and unstable carbon prices, and a lack of localized valuation systems and trading mechanisms. Thus, there is an urgent need to establish regionally adaptive, market-based carbon pricing and compensation mechanisms, such as the guaranteed government procurement of carbon sink services.
This study aims to address these challenges through three key innovations: (1) the development of an integrated evaluation framework that includes forest carbon sink quantification, regional carbon pricing, and economic valuation using the NPV method; (2) the introduction of a dynamic pricing model that incorporates a government-guaranteed minimum transaction price to enhance market stability; (3) the application of the framework to Shenmu City, using the GM (1,1) gray forecasting model to predict carbon sink trends (2024–2060) and assess economic value under three policy scenarios with different offset ratios (5%, 10%, and 15%). The findings aim to support regional policy design, facilitate low-carbon transitions in resource-based cities, and contribute to SDGs 13 and 15.
2. Materials and Methods
2.1. Study Area
Shenmu City (38°13′–39°27′ N, 109°40′–110°54′ E) lies at the Qin–Jin–Mongolian tri-provincial junction in northern Shaanxi (
Figure 1), overlapping the western margin of the Loess Plateau and the southeastern fringe of the Maowusu Sandy Land, therefore straddling both the Yellow River Basin and the Great Wall geomorphic belt [
32]. The administrative area covers 7635 km
2, making it the largest county-level administrative unit in Shaanxi Province. The city has a variety of landforms, including hills and gullies in the south (49%) and sandy grasslands in the north (51%), covering a wide range of landscapes such as plateaus, hills, sands, plains, and lakes, which represent the typical geographic pattern of arid and semi-arid regions in northern China. The average annual temperature is 9.2 °C, the average annual precipitation is 441.9 mm, and the evaporation is as high as 1338.4 mm. The spatial distribution of rainfall and water resources is uneven, and the overall regional water resource supply is tense. The soil type is dominated by sandy and loess soils, and the transition between steppe and forest–steppe characterizes the vegetation distribution. As of 2023, Shenmu had a population of approximately 579,800. Land use is split between intensive resource extraction and ecological conservation. The city holds abundant coal, gas, and quartz sand reserves, making it the largest coal-producing county-level region in China. In 2023, its coal output reached 331 million tonnes, generating CNY 365.45 billion in industrial output. Its strong energy sector ranks it among the most competitive counties in western China.
Shenmu has promoted forest and grassland restoration through afforestation, forest closure, and erosion control. By 2023, its forested area reached 3301.65 km2, with 43.2% forest coverage and 63.35% grassland vegetation cover. Afforestation and erosion control covered 473.17 km2 and 442.22 km2, respectively. As it modernizes its coal-based industries and expands clean energy such as solar and wind, Shenmu’s green transformation coexists with a legacy of heavy industry. This structural tension makes Shenmu a representative case for studying carbon-neutral strategies and the economic valuation of forest carbon sink.
2.2. Carbon-Stock Accounting Framework
2.2.1. Data Sources
Carbon sink accounting in this study followed the 2006 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories, which classify land types based on the Land Use and Land Use Change (LULUCF) framework [
33]. The estimation of carbon sinks covered six types of carbon pools: above- and below-ground biomass, dead wood, litter, soil organic carbon, and harvested wood products. The relevant primary data mainly came from the Shenmu City Statistical Yearbook (2010–2023), Annual Statistical Bulletins (2010–2023), local GHG inventories, forestry department archives, afforestation and forest management plans, and the relevant scientific literature. Key indicators included forest area, dominant species, standing volume, and forest stock. To improve estimation accuracy, measured growth parameters of local tree species (e.g., camphor pine, oil pine) were combined with biomass conversion factors from published studies. Carbon density and biomass parameters followed technical specifications issued by the State Forestry and Grassland Administration and provincial GHG inventory guidelines. As this study focused on vegetation-based sequestration, the biomass estimation method under the IPCC framework was adopted to support the quantitative evaluation of forest carbon sink and the design of regionally adapted carbon pricing mechanisms.
Our carbon emissions accounting made comprehensive use of Shenmu City’s socio-economic and energy statistics for the period 2010–2023, including population, urbanization rate, GDP, energy mix and consumption, electricity use, and industrial structure. The data were mainly taken from the Shenmu City Statistical Yearbook, annual statistical bulletins, and information released by the National Bureau of Statistics, Shaanxi Provincial Bureau of Statistics, and other authoritative organizations. To improve the accuracy and representativeness of the emission data, this study also collected annual average energy consumption and energy intensity data for industry, construction, transportation, services, agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, fishery, and residential life, which were mainly derived from local surveys and departmental data submissions. The carbon emission data for 2024–2060, derived from the authors’ unpublished modeling framework, were incorporated as an anticipatory extension of the empirical dataset, enabling forward-looking analysis under a unified accounting paradigm.
The cost of forest carbon sink mainly includes the afforestation cost, maintenance cost, and development costs of forest carbon sink projects. The afforestation cost data came from the research statistics of Shenmu municipal government’s investment in forestry projects, and the initial input per mu of afforestation was estimated by combining the local seedling and labor costs. The cost of forestry care and maintenance was based on the forest ecological benefit compensation standard of Shaanxi Province and the empirical values presented in related studies [
34]. Based on operational data from afforestation projects in Shenmu City, the annual cost of forestry care and maintenance is approximately CNY 299,850.28/km
2 during the young forest stage, CNY 89,955.02/km
2 during the growth stage, and CNY 29,985.01/km
2 during the maturity stage. The carbon sink development cost is the processing cost of forest carbon increment to form tradable carbon credits. Referring to the relevant research data [
35], the development cost of forest carbon sink projects in the national carbon market under the CCER methodology accounts for about 3% to 5% of the carbon sink trading amount. Considering that the regional carbon market process in Shenmu City is more straightforward, we assumed that the development cost was about 1–3% of the afforestation cost. For carbon price data, the China carbon quota market pilot price and the EU carbon market price provided reference prices for the model. It was assumed that the initial value of the regional carbon price in Shenmu City was slightly lower than the average price in the national carbon market and would increase over time. In the scenario analysis, different clearing caps and offset ratio conditions, as well as guaranteed price mechanisms, affected the effective carbon price, which is detailed in the methodology section below.
2.2.2. Measurement of Carbon Stocks
The measurement of forest carbon sink in this study mainly followed the IPCC 1996 Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories and Guidelines for the Preparation of Provincial Greenhouse Gas Inventories in China. Additionally, it incorporated the parameters and technical pathways for terrestrial carbon sequestration estimation outlined in the Second National Communication [
33,
36,
37,
38]. In the carbon accounting process, three major carbon pools were considered the primary targets for estimation: above-ground biomass, below-ground biomass, and soil organic carbon. Because SOC gains are not creditable under prevailing forest-offset protocols, the valuation ultimately focused on the two biomass pools (UNFCCC. 2006). For above-ground biomass, stand area, dominant species, age class, and mean growing stock were extracted from Shenmu’s 2010–2023 continuous-inventory plots and converted to biomass with species-specific expansion factors. For below-ground biomass, species-level root-to-shoot ratios (e.g., Pinus tabulaeformis, Betula platyphylla) were applied to the calibrated above-ground totals to obtain below-ground estimates.
Emission factors were selected based on the principle of conservatism to avoid overestimation. Region-specific parameter adjustments were made according to the local forest characteristics in Shenmu City, including forest area, dominant tree species composition, age structure, and standing volume. These regional calibrations enhanced the representativeness and accuracy of the carbon sink estimates. The change in biomass carbon stock was calculated using the IPCC (1996) methodology:
where
ΔCbiomass refers to the net change in biomass carbon stocks in forests and other woody biomass (measured in tonnes of carbon);
ΔCarboreal refers to carbon sink in the biomass growth of arboreal forests (tonnes of carbon);
ΔCbamboo/economic/shrub refers to a change in biomass carbon stocks of bamboo forests (or economic forests, or special shrub forests) (tonnes of carbon);
ΔCloss refers to biomass carbon loss from disturbances, harvesting, or consumption (tonnes of carbon).
Due to the confidentiality policies of the relevant authorities, disaggregated data on the carbon stocks of arboreal forests, economic forests, bamboo forests, special shrublands, and biomass losses are not publicly available. However, aggregated results—namely the total forest area and corresponding carbon stock estimates—are provided in
Table A3.
2.2.3. Carbon Sink Forecast
In this study, the GM (1,1) gray model was employed to forecast forest carbon sink trends in Shenmu City due to its strong adaptability to small-sample, poor-information systems [
39]. Unlike traditional models such as ARIMA, which require long, stationary time series, GM (1,1) is well-suited to the short, structurally trending data typical of regional carbon sink assessments [
40,
41]. Comparative analysis shows that GM (1,1) achieved a lower average relative error (5.45%) than exponential smoothing (9.87%), confirming its superior predictive accuracy. The model constructs a first-order differential equation based on the Accumulated Generating Operation (AGO), which smooths random fluctuations and reveals the system’s inherent dynamics. Parameter estimation was performed using the least squares method, and predictions were derived through a time response function. Accuracy testing followed standard thresholds: a relative error < 5% indicated high precision, 5–10% was acceptable, and >10% was unreliable. Overall, GM (1,1) proved to be an effective tool for forecasting forest carbon sink trajectories in data-limited, ecologically complex regions. The model’s basic formulation involves the following first-order differential equation:
where χ
(1) is the accumulated series of the original data χ
(0), t is the time variable, and a, u are the developmental and endogenous control gray numbers.
2.3. Regional Carbon-Pricing Model
2.3.1. Market Context and Cost Structure
The economic value of forest carbon sink is primarily realized through monetization and value redistribution, with regional carbon markets and supportive policy frameworks serving as essential channels. Using Shenmu City as a case study, this research developed a localized valuation system centered on a regional trading mechanism. While international voluntary markets (e.g., VCS), national schemes (e.g., CCER), and ecological compensation channels exist, their relevance in Shenmu remains limited due to policy, quantification, and market constraints [
42,
43]. Therefore, this study focused on market-based valuation driven by local carbon pricing.
In the regional forest carbon market of Shenmu City, the government serves as buyer of last resort. When market prices fall below marginal sequestration costs, the government ensures viability by purchasing at a guaranteed minimum price. This supports afforestation, expands carbon sink capacity, and allows regulated enterprises to use forest carbon sink as offset credits. Based on labor value and equilibrium price theory, the forest carbon sink price (P
i) includes four components: the cost of afforestation (
CF), the cost of maintenance (
CM), the cost of development (
CD) and the premium coefficient (r):
where the guaranteed base price P
g, i is the sum of cost components:
where
Pi: Market price in year i (CNY/tCO2);
Pg, i: Guaranteed price in year i (CNY/tCO2);
CF, i: Cost of afforestation in year i (CNY/tCO2);
CM, i: Cost of conservation and management of forestry in year i (CNY/tCO2);
CD, i: Cost of development tradable carbon sink credits in year i (CNY/tCO2);
ri: Premium reflecting supply–demand dynamics in year i (dimensionless).
The estimated values of CF, CM, and CD were derived from forestry fiscal investments and carbon stock data in Shenmu City between 2011 and 2023. Based on these cost components, the Pg is calculated as the value of the labor invested by forest farmers and other forest carbon sink producers in producing FCS. The r is the proportion of the premium of the FCS transaction price relative to the current guaranteed transaction price caused by changes in the demand and supply of FCS. Historical fiscal data on afforestation investment and forest establishment area were processed using a three-year moving average to ensure robustness.
2.3.2. Forest Carbon Sink Price Model in Regional Carbon Market
This study assumed that the FCS price in the regional forest carbon sink trading market in Shenmu City is the result of free and full quotes from buyers and sellers, and that its transaction price follows the theory of price equilibrium between supply and demand. The market price in year i combines the floor price with a demand-driven premium:
Therefore, we calculated the relationship between FCS price and its supply and demand in a certain trading period (
Figure A1,
Table A1).
- (1)
FCS Demand Curve
Under the carbon neutrality framework, FCS demand at any point in time is assumed to be inelastic and defined as a fixed proportion of total carbon emissions, i.e., the carbon neutrality rate. Since the maximum FCS clearance volume is pre-set, demand remains constant regardless of price fluctuations, represented as a vertical demand curve:
where
Qr, i is the FCS demand in period
i, and
ci is the upper limit (constant) of the FCS offset caps in period
i.
- (2)
FCS Supply Curve
Supply is price-elastic. As prices rise, afforestation becomes more profitable, encouraging greater participation and increasing FCS supply. The supply function is expressed as
where
Qr, i is the supply of FCS in period
i,
Pi is the price of FCS in period
i, and
f is a transformation function reflecting the effect of price on supply. This function is influenced by the average social return on investment, the direct and opportunity costs of carbon sink production, and other factors. Based on the incentive effect of the guaranteed transaction mechanism, the study constructed the FCS price–supply curve (
Figure A2,
Table A2) by numerically fitting the guaranteed price to the historical data for carbon sink, which is used to predict the future trend of supply changes.
It follows that, at the current measure, the . It follows that (f′ is the inverse function of f).
- (3)
Supply–Demand Equilibrium and Premium Coefficient
On the FCS price–supply–demand volume curve, the intersection point of the supply curve and the demand curve represents the equilibrium state of supply and demand in the market at a certain point in time. The corresponding price is the market-transacted price of FCS for the current period, and the quantity is the transacted volume (
Figure 2,
Table A1). The intersection point is denoted as (
P,
Q), where
P denotes the price and
Q denotes the quantity traded, which is equal to both supply and demand.
If
, the market is oversupplied, the guaranteed price is lower than the equilibrium price, and the FCS is sold at a price higher than the guaranteed price. At this point, the FCS premium coefficient
r is positive, indicating the percentage premium of the market price compared to the guaranteed price. Since
P0,
Q0, and
c are known quantities at a certain defined point in time, the premium coefficient can be calculated as follows:
If
, supply exceeds demand in the market, the guaranteed price is higher than or equal to the equilibrium price, and the seller chooses to sell at the guaranteed price, the premium coefficient r = 0. Therefore, the expression for the FCS premium coefficient r is
2.3.3. Scenario Design and Price Trajectories
To simulate FCS market evolution under the dual-carbon goal, we assumed that Shenmu City peaks in terms of carbon emissions by 2035 and reaches neutrality by 2060. The carbon neutrality rate increases linearly from 2031 to 2060. Based on a stable technological baseline and the CCER framework, three scenarios of clearing ratio caps were considered: 5%, 10%, and 15%. These scenarios allow the prediction of future FCS price trajectories under different policy and market conditions.
2.4. Economic Valuation of Forest Carbon Sink
Forest carbon sink value is calculated as the product of carbon stocks and unit price. To reflect local ecological conditions, a pricing model tailored to Shenmu was developed. Each year’s newly established forest land was treated as an independent carbon sink project and evaluated using the NPV method. Future cash inflows from carbon sales and establishment costs were discounted to obtain annual NPV, which was then divided by the afforested area to calculate the per-unit value. The value series from 2024 to 2060 reflects the evolution of forest carbon sink under carbon neutrality.
Assumptions: (1) Revenue derives solely from carbon credit sales (no timber income); (2) unit sequestration cost stabilizes over time; (3) the main species are camphor and oil pine with 50-year cycles; (4) a 2.57% discount rate, reflecting China’s 30-year Treasury bond (Code: 019742, 2024).
NPVi: The current net present value of the forest carbon sink project in year i (CNY);
J: The final number of years that the forest carbon sink projects will generate carbon sink;
Pt: The price per unit of regional carbon sink in year t (CNY/tCO2);
Qt: The quantity of carbon sink generated in year t by the forest projects initiated in year i (tonnes CO2);
Ci: The total cost of establishing and maintaining forest carbon sink projects in year i (CNY);
npvi: The current net present value per unit area of forest carbon sink projects in year i (CNY/km2);
Si: The afforestation area established in year i (km2).
These scenarios were designed to align with Shenmu City’s implementation of China’s “dual-carbon” strategy and support regional goals for energy structure optimization and efficiency improvement.
All data processing and calculations were performed using Microsoft Excel 2019 (Microsoft Corporation, Redmond, WA, USA).
4. Discussion
4.1. Mechanisms of Forest Carbon Sink Variation and Regional Strategies for Sink Enhancement
This study shows that the forest resources and carbon sink capacity of Shenmu City will increase significantly under the continuation of the established afforestation and management policies. By leveraging historical data from 2010 to 2023, we validated the predictive accuracy of the GM (1,1) gray forecasting model, which achieved a mean relative error of only 5.45%. This high level of accuracy highlights the model’s applicability for forecasting forest carbon sink dynamics under data-scarce conditions. Forest carbon sink in Shenmu City shows a steady growth trend between 2010 and 2023, and is expected to reach 20.67 million tonnes of carbon sinks by 2060. This steady growth trend aligns with the nationwide trajectory identified in China’s Ninth National Forest Resource Inventory, reflecting the cumulative effects of sustained afforestation efforts and a younger forest stand age structure [
7,
44,
45]. If current forestry policies remain unchanged, the GM (1,1) model forecasts that forest coverage in Shenmu will approach 50% around 2035 (
Figure 3). However, substantial regional heterogeneity affects the carbon sink potential, particularly due to differences in water availability and vegetation types. In arid and semi-arid areas such as the Loess Plateau, where annual precipitation often falls below 400 mm, limited hydrological conditions and high evapotranspiration suppress vegetation growth and slow the rate of carbon accumulation. As a result, forest carbon sink growth in these regions is relatively constrained compared to more humid zones [
46,
47]. Empirical evidence confirms that regional climate change exerts differentiated impacts on forest succession and carbon storage capacity, underscoring the importance of incorporating localized ecological baselines into carbon sink assessments [
48,
49,
50].
It should be acknowledged that the current forest carbon sink in Shenmu and the broader Loess Plateau remains insufficient to offset regional fossil fuel emissions. A considerable gap persists between the scale of existing forestry development and the demands of China’s “dual-carbon” strategy. Achieving carbon peaking by 2035 and net-zero emissions by 2060 will require scaling up both forest coverage and carbon density per unit area. Given land constraints, Shenmu City must optimize its land use structure and prioritize areas most suitable for afforestation and ecological restoration. Forest succession—from middle-aged to mature stands—will naturally enhance sink efficiency, as is reflected in the exponential growth pattern forecasted in this study.
Furthermore, measures such as promoting mixed forest cultivation and forest closure should maximize the use of natural means of sink enhancement, while attention should also be paid to the role of artificial interventions (e.g., rainwater harvesting and utilization, soil improvement) in enhancing the survival rate of afforestation and the efficiency of carbon sink. Studies have shown that stand-structure complexity (e.g., multi-layered canopies and tree-size diversity) is often a stronger predictor of long-term carbon storage than species richness alone [
51]. A global meta-analysis covering 84 experimental sites confirmed that mixed-species plantations of conifers and broadleaves exhibit, on average, 70% higher above-ground biomass carbon density compared to monocultures in the same region [
52].
Our findings align with national trends in China, confirming a positive trajectory in FCS growth due to persistent afforestation efforts. Compared to studies from Europe [
53] and Latin America [
54], which emphasize climatic gradients and biodiversity effects, Shenmu’s relatively constrained growth is predominantly attributed to its semi-arid climate and limited water resources. Similar climatic constraints were observed in China’s Inner Mongolia region [
55], indicating a regional consistency in challenges faced. Conversely, European studies noted higher carbon sink potentials driven by more favorable hydrological conditions, emphasizing the climatic dependency of carbon sequestration efficacy.
Notably, forest carbon sink development is inherently long-term and requires sustained policy support and investment continuity. Shenmu’s experience illustrates that large-scale ecological restoration yields substantial carbon sink benefits only after decades of accumulation. In assessing sink potential, cost-effectiveness must be a critical consideration: as marginal afforestation costs rise, the per-unit cost of new carbon sink will inevitably increase. Policymakers must therefore determine how to strategically allocate limited public and private capital to optimize sink enhancement pathways.
Despite the large growth potential of forest carbon sink, it is still difficult to offset the emissions pressure brought by high-carbon industries through the growth rate of forest carbon sink. The structural tension between industrial growth and ecological conservation heightens the scarcity and value of carbon sink. Scenario simulations in this study reveal that policy-driven increases in the offset ratio can elevate carbon sink economic value by 18–22%. However, suppose industrial emission reduction, energy transition, and technological pathways (e.g., CCUS, soil carbon sink) are not taken in tandem. In that case, there is still a high degree of uncertainty in achieving carbon neutrality by 2060. This issue has been emphasized in several studies, suggesting that constructing a composite carbon sink system is a key guarantee for realizing regional carbon neutrality targets [
56,
57].
The findings of this study directly contribute to SDG 13 (Climate Action) and SDG 15.3 (Land Degradation Neutrality). By quantifying economically viable carbon sink strategies in ecologically fragile regions, the proposed forest carbon sink pricing and compensation model supports the development of low-carbon pathways tailored for arid and semi-arid zones. Specifically, the afforestation and land restoration policies modeled for Shenmu City promote sustainable land use practices, addressing both carbon mitigation and land rehabilitation, thereby offering actionable insights for the localized implementation of the UNCCD Land Degradation Neutrality target.
4.2. Applicability and Uncertainty Analysis of Regional FCS Pricing Model
This study presents an integrated economic valuation of FCS in Shenmu City, highlighting significant implications for carbon neutrality strategies in resource-based cities on the Loess Plateau. As a nature-based climate change mitigation pathway, forest carbon sink is playing an increasingly prominent role in regional carbon-neutral strategies. Shenmu City, as a resource-based city with a heavy industrial structure and high energy consumption intensity, has a forest carbon sink that provides a vital avenue for achieving negative emissions. Based on the GM (1,1) prediction model with 2010–2023 historical data, this study predicts that the carbon sink in Shenmu City will continue to grow and reach 7.04 million tonnes in 2060, with forest cover expanding to nearly 50% by 2035. Our marginal abatement cost analysis revealed that implementing dynamic carbon pricing mechanisms, particularly with guaranteed minimum prices, substantially increases the economic viability and stability of carbon market transactions. Specifically, raising policy offset ratios from 5% to 15% resulted in an increase in economic value due to heightened market scarcity. This predicted trend is in line with the development direction of the national forest carbon sink, which further proves the key role of expanding forest area, optimizing structure, and strengthening management in enhancing the potential of carbon sink [
58,
59].
The regionally adapted forest carbon sink pricing model and NPV-based valuation framework proposed in this study account for afforestation, maintenance, and project development costs. Coupled with the introduction of a government-guaranteed purchase mechanism, the model provides a viable pathway for realizing the economic value of forest carbon sink under market-based conditions. While the model is theoretically sound and policy-relevant, its practical applicability and inherent uncertainties warrant careful consideration.
Internationally, commonly applied valuation frameworks for FCS include the opportunity cost method, NPV method, market equilibrium modeling, and dynamic optimization techniques. Among them, the opportunity cost method is suitable for areas where the value of alternative land uses is clear, especially under the condition of land resource scarcity [
60,
61], whereas the NPV method used in this paper has been widely used in the economic benefit analysis of long-term ecological projects [
19,
62,
63]. The model’s integration of market equilibrium theory adds analytical depth by capturing the dynamic interplay between supply and demand, which is pivotal for forecasting carbon credit prices [
64,
65,
66,
67].
The model adopted in this study combines the NPV and market equilibrium theories, fully considers the regional ecological and economic characteristics and the special characteristics of resource-based regions, and reflects high regional applicability. Especially in the Loess Plateau region, the fragile ecology and special industrial structure determine the necessity of government market intervention (e.g., guaranteed price mechanism), which is closely in line with the regional reality. Although the price model and the methodology for assessing the value of forest carbon sink in this study have good regional applicability, there may be uncertainties that affect their accuracy and long-term reliability. There is uncertainty in market demand and the policy environment. The cost of afforestation and maintenance per unit of carbon sink continues to rise, and this study predicts that the cost per unit of carbon aggregation will be close to 832 CNY/tCO2 in 2060, which constitutes rigid support for the formation of a carbon sink trading price. However, in practice, the actual realization of carbon sink prices will also be influenced by changes in the intensity of future carbon emission constraint policies and the supply–demand dynamics of the carbon market.
Secondly, there is uncertainty about cost measurement and technological progress. Long-term forecasts of afforestation costs, management costs, and development costs rely on historical data and existing technology levels, ignoring future technological advances, inflation changes, and fluctuations in market conditions. Therefore, the cost assumptions in this paper may overestimate future costs, thus affecting the accuracy of carbon sink pricing. The NPV method is extremely sensitive to changes in discount rate, and the discount rate in this study adopts the risk-free interest rate, but in the real economic environment, inflation and changes in macro interest rates will significantly affect the level of the discount rate, which may bring about prediction errors. Lastly, the model assumes ideal ecological conditions. Forest carbon sink is highly susceptible to climatic shocks, pest outbreaks, and wildfires, which can substantially diminish actual sequestration outcomes. These risks from extreme climates, ecological disasters, and land use are not fully captured in the current framework.
The regional carbon pricing model presented demonstrates considerable practical applicability for Shenmu, particularly through integrating guaranteed transaction prices. Comparable applications in Europe reveal similar governmental interventions effectively stabilizing market prices [
68]. However, our model faces uncertainties similar to those identified in Brazilian carbon offset initiatives [
69], where policy volatility substantially influenced carbon market dynamics. The predictive uncertainties in long-term afforestation costs parallel those in Eastern European carbon projects, where inflation and technological advancements caused significant cost variances [
70]. In summary, while the regional pricing model proposed here demonstrates strong contextual relevance and theoretical coherence, its limitations should be addressed in future applications through parameter sensitivity testing, multi-scenario simulation, and hybrid model refinement.
4.3. Regional Carbon Market Design and Policy Recommendations
This study quantifies the dynamic evolution of forest carbon sink prices and NPV under varying policy offset ratios by introducing a guaranteed floor price mechanism and simulating a low-carbon scenario. The results indicate that raising the offset ratio significantly enhances the marginal economic value of the forest carbon sink. Under a 15% offset scenario, the peak NPV per unit reaches CNY 7095 in 2044, substantially higher than the CNY 4115 observed under a 5% scenario (
Table 3).
Our results advocate for targeted ecological restoration initiatives supported by market-based instruments in resource-based regions, ensuring sustainability in both ecological and economic domains. Nevertheless, the proposed pricing model is susceptible to uncertainties arising from ecological disturbances, fluctuating market demands, and policy volatility, indicating a need for ongoing refinement through advanced forecasting methods and broader scenario analyses. This result quantitatively verifies the incentive effect of the offset ratios on the formation of the economic value of the carbon sink. While the initial gains from a higher offset ratio are substantial, returns diminish over time due to the limited incremental capacity of the forest carbon sink. Notably, the slight decline in value in the middle and late stages of the higher offset ratio scenario does not mean that the forest carbon sink becomes unprofitable, but rather that the growth is saturated and the value is maintained at a high level. Importantly, economic value remains high across all scenarios, even when carbon emissions are kept constant, emphasizing the great potential of forest carbon sink as a “carbon asset” in the coming decades.
Our policy simulations support a moderate increase in offset ratios to maximize economic returns from FCS projects. This conclusion aligns with practices in the EU Emissions Trading System (ETS), which similarly demonstrates increased economic benefits through enhanced market flexibility [
71]. Contrastingly, restrictive offset policies in Latin American carbon markets (e.g., Brazil’s early REDD+ initiatives) resulted in lower market liquidity and investment uncertainty [
72].
Several policy actions are recommended to unlock this potential for building a regional carbon market. Firstly, a clear policy and supporting management mechanism should be formulated, including standardized rules for accounting, trading, and compliance auditing in order to ensure market transparency and credibility. Secondly, the FCS offset ratio cap should be raised moderately to guide more enterprises to fulfill compliance obligations and broaden their participation in the carbon market. Thirdly, the guaranteed purchase mechanism of carbon sink prices should be strengthened, with the government or a designated platform acting as a bottoming buyer to stabilize revenue streams and mitigate market risk for FCS stakeholders. These mechanisms have demonstrated efficacy in pilot regions and offer replicable pathways for broader application.
Furthermore, integration with the national carbon market should be accelerated to harmonize methodologies, certification systems, and trading platforms. A regional monitoring and evaluation system should also be established to continuously assess forest sink outputs and value realization, ensuring adaptive policy adjustment.
5. Conclusions
This study takes Shenmu City, a typical resource-based city in China, as a case to explore three key dimensions: (1) the dynamic evolution of forest carbon sinks, (2) a localized carbon pricing mechanism, (3) the economic valuation of forest-based carbon assets. Based on historical data (2010–2023), the GM (1,1) gray model was used to project carbon sink trends through 2060. A regional pricing model, incorporating labor value and cost structures, was developed to simulate economic returns under different compliance offset ratios. Although forest coverage and carbon sequestration capacity continue to increase—averaging 9.98% annually—the growth remains insufficient to fully offset industrial emissions. This highlights the strategic importance of enhancing forest carbon sinks in long-term carbon neutrality pathways. The study proposes a “guaranteed transaction price” mechanism that integrates cost accounting and labor value theory. This approach enhances price stability and market viability for forestry projects. Scenario analysis shows that higher offset ratios significantly increase the economic value of carbon sinks, even under conservative low-carbon scenarios. These findings suggest that establishing a well-regulated regional carbon market—supported by institutional frameworks, fiscal incentives, and proactive governance—can facilitate ecological product monetization and green transformation in resource-dependent areas. Shenmu’s experience provides a replicable model for similar high-emission regions such as the Loess Plateau. Looking forward, efforts should focus on real-time carbon sink monitoring through remote sensing, dynamic accounting, and market innovations. Integrating forest carbon assets into land use planning, rural revitalization, and green finance will help unlock their full ecological and economic potential.