Next Article in Journal
Research on the Spatial Differences and Convergence Mechanism of Urban Land Use Efficiency under the Background of Regional Integration: A Case Study of the Yangtze River Economic Zone, China
Next Article in Special Issue
Management Policy of Farmers’ Cultivated Land Abandonment Behavior Based on Evolutionary Game and Simulation Analysis
Previous Article in Journal
Recognition Changes of the Concept of Urban Resilience: Moderating Effects of COVID-19 Pandemic
Previous Article in Special Issue
Could Land Abandonment with Human Intervention Benefit Cropland Restoration? From the Perspective of Soil Microbiota
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Land Use Demands for the CLUE-S Spatiotemporal Model in an Agroforestry Perspective

by
Georgios Mamanis
1,*,
Michael Vrahnakis
2,
Dimitrios Chouvardas
3,
Stamatia Nasiakou
2 and
Vassiliki Kleftoyanni
1
1
University of Thessaly, GR-38221 Volos, Greece
2
Department of Forestry, Wood Sciences and Design, School of Technology, University of Thessaly, GR-43131 Karditsa, Greece
3
Department of Forestry and Natural Environment, Faculty of Agriculture Forestry and Natural Environment, Aristotle University of Thessaloniki, GR-54124 Thessaloniki, Greece
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Land 2021, 10(10), 1097; https://doi.org/10.3390/land10101097
Submission received: 18 September 2021 / Revised: 12 October 2021 / Accepted: 12 October 2021 / Published: 16 October 2021

Abstract

:
Rural landscape evolution models are used as tools for the analysis of the causes and impact of land use changes on landscapes. The CLUE-S (the Conversion of Land Use and its Effects at Small regional extent) model was developed to simulate the changes in current land use, by using quantitative relationships between land uses and driving factors combined with a dynamic modeling of land use competition. One of the modules that build the “CLUE-S” is the non-spatial subset of the model that calculates the temporal evolution of the land use/cover under several socio-economic scenarios. The purpose of this research was to estimate the demands of land use in the area of Mouzaki, Thessaly plain, Greece with the ultimate goal of using them in the non-spatial module of the CLUE-S to predict the evolution of land uses in year 2040. These estimations are the quantitative prediction of the spatial change for all land use types at the aggregate level. Three models of forecasting the future land cover in the area were simulated, in order to obtain a clear view of the different land uses in the future. We distinguished three model-scenarios for calculating the demand-forecasts: (a) business as usual (BAU) scenario, that deals with a linear projection of the current land use demands, (b) rapid economic development (RED) scenario, and (c) ecological land protection (ELP) scenario. In the BAU scenario the land use demands for the year 2040 were calculated using linear interpolation utilizing historical data from 1960 to 2020. In the RED scenario, the demands were calculated by maximizing the economic benefit of land uses, and in the ELP scenario the demands were calculated by maximizing the environmental benefit of land uses. Furthermore, a multi-criteria analysis was performed to find the trade-offs between economic benefit maximization and environmental benefit optimization. It was found that the agricultural lands reach their maximum area under the RED scenario, while reaching their lower bound for the ELP scenario. The same goes for agroforestry systems. The grasslands reach their lower bound under the ELP scenario, while they achieve a higher value under the RED scenario. Concerning the silvopastoral woodlands, although an increase is foreseen under the BAU scenario, it appears that they reach their lower bound in the other two scenarios, RED and ELP. Forests receive intermediate values and cover a larger area under the ELP scenario compared with the RED scenario. The expected forest cover under the BAU scenario is higher. Moreover, sparse and dense shrublands receive their lower bound for both optimization scenarios, while the settlements reach the upper bound for the RED scenario and the lower one under the ELP scenario.

1. Introduction

It is well documented that Mediterranean landscapes are undergoing significant changes in land uses (Ambarli et al. [1], Guarino et al. [2]). These changes begin from a socio-economic basis, such as the movement of rural populations to urban centers with the consequent abandonment of the (traditional) use of rural and forest land (Chouvardas [3], Papanastasis [4], Chouvardas et al. [5], Perpiña et al. [6]). The result of these changes in land use is the formation of new landscapes, as they evolve with the succession of natural vegetation. In order to control the succession of natural vegetation and to support rural income, state and regional rural policies promote agroforestry practices. In the European Union for example, agroforestry is frequently reported in the draft Strategic Plan Regulation of the new Common Agriculture Policy (2021–2027), and in the Farm to Fork and Biodiversity Strategies, which are all developed within the general framework of the EU’s Green Deal.
Agroforestry systems can have significant advantages over conventional agriculture, livestock farming or forest tree cultivation, such as increased productivity, economic benefits and greater variety in goods produced and services offered (Vrahnakis et al. [7]). However, agroforestry adoption by farmers seems to be low. Many different factors can influence the decision-making for agroforestry adoption. Aspects related to social capital, economic constraints, labor and land are recorded to play important role in such a decision (Mwase et al. [8], Adesina and Chianu [9], Fischer and Vasseur [10], Neupane et al. [11], Bannister and Nair [12]), while increased land-use flexibility (Djalilov et al. [13]) and awareness of the connection between agroforestry and land quality improvement could lead to increased adoption of the technology (Mwase et al. [8]). Risk and uncertainty also play an important role in the adoption of new agricultural technologies (Marra et al. [14]). It is expected that spatio-temporal modelling tools can help visualizing the projected land use changes towards the adoption of agroforestry, under several socio-economic scenarios.
Rural landscape evolution models are used as tools for the analysis of the causes and impact of land use changes on landscapes. Additionally, they are used towards better understanding of the landscape functions and the development of policies and planning of management (Verburg et al. [15]). The scenario-based forecasts of the evolution of landscapes can be used as early warning systems for the (possible) negative effects of management policies that will result in the development of landscapes (Xiang and Clarke [16], Shearer [17]). The land use/cover evolution models should be able to answer critical diachronic questions, such as what the variables (biophysical and socioeconomic) affecting the evolution of land use/cover units are, where future landscape changes are identified, and at what rate/intensity the land use/cover units are changed (Veldkamp and Lambin [18]).
The CLUE-S (the Conversion of Land Use and its Effects at Small regional extent) model was developed to simulate the changes in current land use, by using quantitative relationships between land uses and driving factors combined with a dynamic modeling of land use competition (Verburg et al. [19]). The “CLUE-S” model consists of two totally distinct modules (Verburg et al. [15]). The first is the non-spatial subset of the model which calculates the temporal evolution of the land use/cover under several socio-economic scenarios. The second is the spatial subset which converts/translates into sections the landscape spatial changes that are numerically calculated from the non-spatial subset, using a geographic, grid-oriented file system (raster). The predictive power, robustness and suitability of CLUE-S have already been proved in several cases (indicatively, Chouvardas and Vrahnakis [20], Zhang et al. [21], Han et al. [22]). However, it is the first time that CLUE-S is used to project spatiotemporal land use changes in an agroforestry perspective.
The purpose of this research was to find the demands of land use in the area of Mouzaki, Thessaly plain, Greece with the ultimate goal of using them in the non-spatial module of the CLUE-S model to predict the evolution of land uses in year 2040. We distinguished three model-scenarios for calculating the demands-forecasts: (a) business as usual (BAU) scenario, that deals with a linear projection of the current land use demands, (b) rapid economic development (RED) scenario, and (c) ecological land protection (ELP) scenario. In the BAU scenario the land use demands for year 2040 were calculated using linear interpolation utilizing historical data from 1960 to 2020. In the RED scenario the demands were calculated by maximizing the economic benefit of land uses and in the ELP scenario the demands were calculated by maximizing the environmental benefit of land uses. Furthermore, a multi-criteria analysis was performed to find the trade-offs between economic benefit maximization and environmental benefit optimization.

2. Scenarios on Land Use Demands

Various models have been proposed to deal with the demands of each land use, from simple trend projections to complex economic models (Reginster and Rounsevell [23], Hoymann [24]). Linear extrapolation of recent land use changing trends in the near future is the most common practice for finding the demands for each land use. For the CLUE-S spatiotemporal model, the results of the unit of demands (non-spatial unit) determine, on an annual basis, the area to be covered by each land use. This information constitutes direct input data for the spatial unit of the CLUE-S. Therefore, we focused on finding the land use requirements that will frame the linear projection of trends in recent land use change in the near future. Recent literature directs to models and methods of operations research for the prediction of land uses demands (Wang et al. [25]).
The most recently used scenarios for the CLUE-S model were proposed by Wang et al. [25]; apart from the typical linear business as usual (BAU) scenario, they proposed the rapid economic development (RED), and ecological land protection (ELP) scenarios. The BAU scenario, which is widely used in such studies, is derived from the historical trends of land use change and serves as the basis of the research, since it does not require the mediation of policies, other than those that already exist. The other two scenarios are based on constrained optimization models, based on different needs for green space and urban development. In particular, the aim of the RED scenario is to optimize the economic benefits generated by the land system (in this case the research area), while the ELP scenario considers the protection of ecosystems or otherwise maximizes the benefits of the ecosystem services produced by the land system. The proposed scenarios elaborate many degrees of freedom. Various parameters need to be defined, which are site-specific. The details of the scenarios, as well as how they were applied in the research area are presented below. Finally, a multi-criteria analysis was performed to calculate trade-offs between the two scenarios (RED and ELP), which facilitates the formulation of a common policy for optimal economic growth and environmental balance as well.

3. Study Area and Forecast Period

The research area is the administrative territory of the Municipality of Mouzaki, central Greece (31,326.97 Ha, Figure 1). The municipality includes 27 village communities populated by more than 13,000 inhabitants. Agricultural lands occupy 11,144.03 Ha (35.57%), silvoarable 556.38 Ha (1.78%), grasslands 2405 Ha (7.68%), silvopastoral woodlands (10–40% tree cover) 3815.39 Ha (12.18%), forests (40–100% tree cover) 10,573.64 Ha (33.75%), sparse shrublands (10–40% shrub cover) 503.74 Ha (1.61%), dense shrublands (>40% shrub cover) 784.99 Ha (2.51%), urban 1457.79 Ha (4.65%) and barren land 86.01 Ha (0.27%) (Figure 1, Nasiakou et al. [26]).

4. Materials and Methods

For predicting land uses demands, that will then be utilized by CLUE-S software to simulate the future land use changes, we rely on a recent study of Wang et al. [25]). In this study a model for projecting land use demand is proposed based on operations research optimization models. This study concerns the implementation of these models in the area of Mouzaki, Karditsa.
Usually, when CLUE-S is applied for a real case three scenarios are developing by researchers. The most recently used scenarios for the CLUE-S model were proposed by Wang et al. [25]; apart from the typical linear business as usual (BAU) scenario, they proposed the rapid economic development (RED), and ecological land protection (ELP) scenarios.
A period of twenty years (2020–2040) was chosen as the most appropriate forecast period for the study. This choice is a compromise between the time it takes to see the results of the forecast (the shorter the forecast time, the smaller the change in land use) and the uncertainty that arises if a large time horizon is chosen. Specifically, we came up with a scenario model that uses optimization theory to (a) maximize financial profit, and (b) maximizes the benefit of ecosystem services. For this purpose, a thorough study of the most suitable method of economic evaluation of ecosystem services was carried out for the area of Mouzaki, Karditsa.

4.1. Business as Usual (BAU) Scenario

In the BAU scenario the land use demands for year 2040 were calculated by using linear interpolation of historical data from 1960 to 2020. Specifically, the historical trend of land use changes was used to find the land use demands for the BAU scenario. Table 1 presents the land uses for years 1960 and 2020, as well as their percentage change (Nasiakou et al. [26]).

4.2. Rapid Economic Development (RED) Scenario

The rapid economic development (RED) scenario is the first of the two optimization models used in this study to calculate the demands. The objective of the RED scenario is to maximize the economic benefits provided by different land use types. An optimization function was constructed for the scenario of maximizing the total economic benefit of land uses (RED), where the areas of each land use (x1x9) serve as variables. Parameters in the optimization function were the economic benefit that results from each land use. The objective function that maximizes the economic benefits provided by different land use types has as follows.
M a x i m i z e   f 1 ( x ,   R E D ) = 3146.1 x 1 + 3914.55 x 2 + 306.74 x 3 + 278.64 x 4 + 340.08 x 5 + 511.68 x 6 + 188.3 x 7 + 45 , 038.35 x 8 + 0 x 9 ,

4.2.1. Parameters Estimation

A thorough analysis was performed to find the parameters, which represent the economic benefit per unit of land (Ha) for each land use.
The economic benefit for agricultural land (x1) was calculated using official state data (HSA [27]). Specifically, the total value of the crop production in Greece amounted to 10,941,730,000 EUR which comes from an area of 3,477,900 Ha. Therefore, the total benefit per unit of Agricultural land is 3146.10 EUR/Ha (first parameter in the RED objective function.
The economic benefit for silvoarable land (parameter of x2) was divided into two terms. The first represents 50% of the economic benefit produced by Agricultural land. To this amount, the economic benefit that results from the forest trees was added. For the latter, an amount of 75,000 EUR was considered in the rotating year (Mantzanas [28]). The rotating time was set equal to 25 years. Then the following formula was used to find the economic benefit:
PMT = (FV × i)/((1 + i)^n − 1),
where FV is the economic benefit of the trees in rotating time (n), i represents the discount rate and PMT the equivalent annual benefit. The discount rate was set at 2%, which was considered a conservative choice as the interest rate on Greece’s 10-year bond is currently around 1%. Thus, the economic benefit of the specific use of the trees is equal to 2341.5 EUR/Ha and the total annual benefit for the silvoarable land is equal to 2341.5 EUR/Ha + 50% × value of Agricultural land (1573.05 EUR/Ha) = 3914.55 EUR/Ha.
To find the economic benefit of forest (x5), grassland (x3), silvopastoral woodland (x4) and shrubland (x6, x7) the data obtained by the Institute of Mediterranean Forest Ecosystems of Athens (Albanis et al. [29]) were adapted to the specific conditions of area of Mouzaki, Karditsa.
The total annual value for forest (x5) is estimated at €760.85 EUR × 106, which is produced by an area of 2,237,239 Ha (Table 2). Thus, the annual financial benefit from the forest is 340.08 EUR/Ha (Table 3).
Τhe total economic benefit from the grassland (x3) is 306.74 EUR × 106, produced by an area of 1000 × 103 Ha (Table 4). Thus, the total annual benefit from the grassland is 306.74 EUR/Ha (Table 3).
The total annual value of the silvopastoral (mostly oak) woodland (x4) for Greece was estimated at 278.88 EUR × 106. The total area that produces grazing values is equal to 1,000,850 Ha (Table 4). Thus, the total annual benefit for silvopastoral woodland is estimated to 278.64 EUR/Ha (Table 3).
The annual economic benefit for sparse shrubland (x6) is € 670.301 × 106 and the total area is 1,309,991.6 Ha (Table 4). Thus, the total annual economic benefit from sparse shrubland is 511.68 EUR/Ha (Table 3).
The annual economic benefit for dense shrubland is 369,955 EUR × 106 and the total area is 1,964,987.4 Ha (Table 4). Thus, the total annual economic benefit for dense shrubland is 188.3 EUR/Ha (Table 3).
To find the economic benefit resulting from the urban land (x8) the total production of the secondary and tertiary sector of Greece was used, proposed by Wang et al. [25], and adapted for the area of Mouzaki, Karditsa. Accordingly, the total turnover of the secondary and tertiary sector in Greece was 54,119,766,393.00 EUR (HSA [27]). The total population of the country according to the 2011 census was 10,816,286 inhabitants. Thus, the turnover per capita amounted to 5003.54 EUR. The turnover for the urban area of Municipality of Mouzaki (13,122 inhabitants), which expresses the economic benefit of the urban land, of the secondary and tertiary sector is 5003.54 EUR × 13,122 = 65,656,451.88 EUR, and the turnover is equal to 65,656,451.88 EUR/1457.79 Ha = 45,038.35 EUR/Ha.
Finally, the annual financial benefit (EUR) is presented in Table 2.

4.2.2. Constraints on the Optimization Model

The following constraints (C) are used in the optimization model:
C1: The constraint considers the total research area, as shown by the sum of the areas of individual land uses for year 2020, i.e.,
C 1 :   x 1 + x 2 + x 3 + x 4 + x 5 + x 6 + x 7 + x 8 + x 9 = 31 , 326.97   Ha
C2: At least 1% of the total area should be allocated to land uses such as pastures (x3, x6, x7) and barren land (x9), as these land types are most likely to be occupied by future urban sprawl, such as proposed by Wang et al. [25]. In this case,
C 2 :   x 3 + x 6 + x 7 + x 9 1 % × 31 , 326.97   Ha
C3: It refers to forest cover that must be maintained for environmental purposes. The coefficients of the following equation were derived from Wang et al. [25] and retained in the model:
C 3 :   0.73 x 2 + 0.49 x 3 + 0.75 x 4 + x 5 + 0.49 x 6 + 0.49 x 7 50 % × 31,326.97   Ha
C4–C12: Finally, upper and lower bounds for each land use in the model area were introduced as follows: If BAU projections show that the trend for a land use is decreasing then its current area becomes upper bound and its forecast for 2040 according to the BAU scenario lower bound. If, on the other hand, the tendency for a land use is increasing then its current area becomes lower bound. A proportional increase for the year 2040 was received as the upper bound, e.g., if for the years 1960–2020 it was observed an increase for a land use by α %, then the value of the area assuming an increase of (α/3) % on its current area was received as upper bound. Like for BAU scenario, the ratio 60/20 = 3 calculated as the ratio between the number of past years (1960–2020, i.e., 60 years) and the number of years projected into the future (2020–2040, i.e., 20 years). For the barren land (x9) the lower bound was set equal to zero, similarly to Wang et al. [25]. As shown in Table 1, the trend is decreasing for Agricultural land (x1), grassland (x3), dense shrubland (x7) and barren land (x9). On the contrary the trend is increasing for silvoarable land (x2), silvopastoral woodland (x4), forest (x5), sparse shrubland (x6) and urban land (x8).
Accordingly, the formulated constraints were:
  • C4: 10,343.15 ≤ x1 ≤ 11,144.03
  • C5: 556.38 ≤ x2 ≤885.53
  • C6: 1988.21 ≤ x3 ≤2405.00
  • C7: 3815.39 ≤ x4 ≤4465.02
  • C8: 10,573.64 ≤ x5 ≤ 14,249.39
  • C9: 503.74 ≤ x6 ≤ 550.03
  • C10: 608.97 ≤ x7 ≤ 784.99
  • C11: 1457.79 ≤ x8 ≤ 1725.68
  • C12: 0 ≤ x9 ≤ 86.01

4.3. Ecological Land Protection (ELP) Scenario

The third scenario of ecological land protection (ELP) concerns finding the distribution–forecast for each land use using the total value of ecosystem services as an objective function. The coefficients of the objective function, i.e., the ecosystem value produced by each land use, were consistent with Costanza et al. [30], but adapted to the Greek condition in year 2020 (Table 5). The values taken from the study of Costanza et al. [30] were translated into Euros, divided by the ratio of the USA’s GDP to Greece’s GDP and compounded till year 2020 with the rate of inflation of Greece from 1997 to 2020. The ecological value for the silvoarable land is not mentioned in the paper of Costanza et al. [30]. As an approximation, to estimate its value we added to the ecological value of agricultural land the 50% of the ecological value of forest.
The objective function is:
Maximize   f 2 ( x ) = 67.75 x 1 + 178.94 x 2 + 170.84 x 3 + 196.61 x 4 + 222.38 x 5 + 170.84 x 6 + 170.84 x 7
The rest constraints in this scenario are the same as for the RED scenario.

4.4. Multiobjective Optimization

Multiobjective optimization consists of finding good solutions from a set of alternatives with respect to multiple objective functions. Usually, these objective functions are in conflict, i.e., when an objective function is improved the other is deteriorated. In the particular study at hand, we have two optimization models and two objective functions. The one derived from the RED scenario (objective function 1, f1(x)) and the other derived from the ELP scenario (objective function 2, f2(x)). For most multiobjective optimization problems, no single solution (in this study, allocation of the entire area into different land uses) exists that simultaneously optimizes each objective function. As it will be evident in the Results section, the land use allocation that gives the maximum economic benefit has the minimum ecological benefit and vice versa). Thus, the notion of optimality changes with respect to single objective (with only one objective function optimized) optimization. Usually, in multiobjective optimization we are interested in the so-called Pareto optimal or nondominated solutions. A solution is called nondominated or Pareto optimal, if none of the objective functions can be improved in value without deteriorating some of the other objective values. Nondominated or Pareto optimal solutions expresses the different trade-offs among the objective functions.
In the particular problem at hand the Pareto optimal solutions reflect the trade-offs between economic and ecological benefits. A solution (an allocation of the entire area into different land uses) that optimizes economic benefits has the worst ecological value and vice versa (i.e., a solution with optimal ecological benefits has the worst economic value). Between the two extremes there are compromised solutions.
Thus, in this study we face the following multiobjective optimization problem:
Maximize [f1(x), f2(x)] subject to the same set of constraints C1:C12. Our goal now is to simultaneously optimize the two objective functions. However, a single solution that simultaneously maximizes objective 1 (f1(x)) and objective 2 (f2(x)) does not exist. In contrast there are “optimal” solutions that trade-off between the two objectives.
For computing the nondominated, Pareto optimal solutions that trade-off between the two objectives, the ε-constraint method is applied. In the ε-constraint method, one objective is optimized and the other is fixed as a constraint in the set of constraints. It does not matter which objective to optimize and which to use as a constraint in the constraint set. Thus, in the particular problem at hand, objective 1 is optimized and objective 2 is used as a constraint as follows. Maximize f1(x) subject to f2(x) = ei, i = 1,…p ^C1:C12, where p is the number of Pareto optimal solutions desired to compute and C1:C12 is the set of constraints defined in Section 4. By parametrical variation of the constraint values ei, an appropriate number of Pareto-optimal solutions are obtained. Thus, in order to properly apply the ε-constraint method, the range of the second objective used as constraint must be computed. One point, that is also Pareto optimal, is the optimal value of objective 2 under constraints C1:C12. This is the biggest point in the range of values. The smallest point is the optimal solution obtained by optimizing the first objective function, evaluated however using the second objective function. In this way, we have the worst value (nadir value) of the second objective function. Setting appropriate right-hand values ei between the nadir value and the maximum value for the second objective function in the constraints set, a number of Pareto optimal solutions are obtained. One Pareto optimal solution for each ei value. For the purposes of this study, nine equidistant values were fixed in the range of possible values of the second objective function.

5. Results

In this section, the experimental results of the optimization models (rapid economic development (RED), ecological land protection (ELP) and the business as usual (BAU)) are presented and analyzed, as well as a trade-off analysis between the two optimized scenarios RED and ELP.

5.1. Results for the Three Scenarios BAU, RED, ELP

In order to find the land use demands for year 2040 (20 years prediction trend), the expected percentage change of each land use was chosen by calculating the 1/3 of the total change trend between the years 1960 and 2020 (60 year trend).
The ratio 1/3 is used because we have a 20 years prediction period and 60 year of historical results; thus, it is expected, under the BAU scenario, that the 20 year period will give a third of the historical trend (60 years/20 years = 1/3).
Finally, an adjustment has been made by applying a proportional reduction of the total predicted area for all land use types that were expected to increase, during the specific period. This reduction was necessary in order for the total sum of the predicted land use areas to equal the total area in the region. The estimated area for each land use for year 2040 under the BAU scenario is presented in Table 1 and Table 6.
As it is seen from Table 1 and Table 6, the biggest increase, under the BAU scenario is predicted for silvoarable land (16.87%), while the biggest decrease is projected for the barren land (27.31%). However, the largest share (37.10% of the total land area of the area Mouzaki, Karditsa) is accounted for the forest land type followed by agricultural land (33.02%). Forest land is expected to increase by 9.92% under the BAU scenario. However, while agricultural land is in the second place considering the share of the total area is expected to decrease by 7.19% under the BAU scenario. From the same tables it is observed that silvoarable land is expected to have the biggest percentage increase (16.87%) under this scenario, while barren land the biggest percentage decrease (27.31%).
The results of the three scenarios (BAU, RED, ELP) are presented in Table 6. For the RED scenario, the biggest increase is predicted for silvoarable land (59.16%), while the biggest decrease is projected for the Barren land (100%). The biggest share (35.57%) of the total land area of the area Mouzaki, Karditsa) is accounted for the agricultural land followed by forest (33.89%). Under the RED scenario, agricultural land is expected to remain the same while forest land is expected to increase by 0.41%. Finally, under the RED scenario, urban land is expected to increase by 18.38% (second biggest percentage increase after silvoarable land).
For the ELP scenario the biggest increase is predicted for forest land (13.99%), while the biggest decrease is projected for the barren land (100%). The lion’s share (38.48%) of the total land area of the area Mouzaki, Karditsa, is accounted for the forest land followed by Agricultural land (33.02%). Silvoarable land is expected to remain the same under this scenario.
As shown in Table 6, under the RED scenario, the silvoarable land attains its upper bound as in the BAU scenario. Since in this study we approach land use modelling in agroforestry perspective, the question arises as to what grade this result can be improved? For this reason, we relax constraint C5 and eliminate the upper bound for the silvoarable land. The results are shown in Table 7.
It is shown that silvoarable land increases 99.7% at the expense, mainly, of agricultural land which approaches its lower bound. The improvement in objective function (economic value) is 901,200 EUR. Moreover, if we let the lower bound for the agricultural land to decrease further till zero, the remaining land is totally allocated to silvoarable land i.e., the silvoarable land obtains the value 12,333.37 Ha, while agricultural land that of zero. This is very important since silvoarable land is competing agricultural land. This way the improvement in economic value is 7,948,193.62 EUR.
Under the ELP scenario, silvoarable land obtains its lower bound, so a relaxation of its upper bound is not expected to increase the area allocated to this land.

5.2. Trade-Offs between Economic and Ecological Benefits

The Pareto diagram reflects the trade-offs between economic and ecological benefits (Figure 2). The Pareto optimal solutions are generated by solving nine optimization problems (in addition to the two problems RED and ELP described above), where the total economic benefit is maximized subject to a constraint on the second objective function value (which was fixed at nine equidistant values) from the maximum value achieved by solving the ELP model and the value of the f2(x) where x is obtained by the solution of the RED scenario. Furthermore, the same constraints used in the RED and ELP scenarios were utilized here without upper bound for the silvoarable land. It is observed that point 6 offers a good alternative to points 1 and 11 which are the results of the RED and ELP scenarios, respectively (Table 8). It is observed that point 6 has an increase of 10.59% or 11,277,600.00 EUR in relation to the value that can be achieved of the expected profit when we only maximize the ecological benefit (point 11), but with a minor decrease of only 1.18% or 56,107.50 EUR in the environmental profit in relation to the environmental value f2(x) of point 11. From point 6 onwards the expected economic benefit further increases without a significant decrease in the ecological benefit. That is, from point 6 to point 1 the economic benefit increases further by 4.27% or 5,028,200.00 EUR with a decrease of the ecological benefit of only 1.12% or 56,107.50 EUR.
These points are important for policy makers as they present the trade-off between economic benefit f1(x) (Objective 1) and ecological benefit f2(x) (Objective 2). Knowing these values, policy makers are better informed as they can find a compromise solution between the two criteria and not just apply either the maximization of one criterion (point 1) or the maximization of the ecological one (point 11). They may, for example, choose point 6 which has an increase of 10.54% or 11,277,600.00 EUR in relation to the value that can be achieved of the expected profit when we only maximize the ecological benefit (point 11), but with a decrease of only 1.18% or 56,107.50 EUR in the environmental profit in relation to the environmental value f2(x) of point 11. The policy maker can observe the optimal areas for different points and choose his/her optimal policy in favor of one or the other area.

6. Conclusions

In the present research, three scenarios/models for finding the land use requirements for Mouzaki area were developed: i business as usual (BAU), ii. rapid economic development (RED), and iii. ecological land protection (ELP).
This research’s purpose was to find the Demands for use of the CLUE-S model. For this reason, we used, beyond the classical BAU scenario, two operations research optimization models for predicting the required demands. In the BAU scenario the requirements are calculated by applying linear interpolation of historical data from 1960 to 2020. Specifically, the historical trend of land use change was used to find the land use requirements for the BAU scenario. For the RED scenario an objective maximization function was constructed, where the variables are the extent of each land use. Parameters in this function were the economic benefit for each land use. Finally, in the ELP scenario, which is also a maximization problem, the distribution–forecast for each land use has been taken into account using the total value of ecosystem services as an objective function. The coefficients of the objective function, i.e., the ecosystem value generated by each land use, were in line with the widely accepted work of Costanza et al. [30], adapted to the Greece for year 2020.The two optimization models was applied in the Area of Mouzaki, Karditsa. Several aspects of the models needed to be defined. For example, the input parameters used by the model. These parameters include the financial benefit and ecological benefit (in money terms) for the two distinct models (RED, ELP). A thorough analysis was performed to find the parameters, which represent the economic and ecological benefit per unit of land (Ha) for each land use.
Furthermore, a trade-off analysis was performed between economic and ecological benefits. As shown a solution obtained by the optimization models are in conflict. The solution that attains the maximum financial benefit has the worst ecological benefit and vice versa. Between these two extremes
Furthermore, a multi-criteria analysis was performed to find intermediate values of the two scenarios RED and ELP. As shown, a solution obtained by the optimization models are in conflict. The solution that attains the maximum financial benefit has the worst ecological benefit and vice versa. It was observed that there are trade-offs for these two extreme scenarios. Optimizing function f1(x) produces the smallest value for the other function, and vice versa. The Pareto front gives significant advantages to policymakers. It appears that point 8 has a decrease of 2.66% in the expected profit, but an increase of 3.26% in the ecological profit compared to the RED scenario. On the other hand, point 6 has an increase of 10.59% or 11,277,600.00 EUR in relation to the value that can be achieved of the expected profit when we only maximize the ecological benefit (point 11), but with a minor decrease of only 1.18% or 56,107.50 EUR in the environmental profit in relation to the environmental value f2(x) of point 11. Policy makers need to know all the values of the Pareto front and not just the extremes (point 1 (RED scenario) and point 11 (ELP scenario)). The calculated demands will be used in future research by the CLUE-S model for their spatial distribution and validation.
The present study, as a part of the project entitled “Perspective of Agroforestry in Thessaly region: A research on social, environmental and economic aspects to enhance farmer participation”, provides useful input in terms of successful design of applying Agroforestry in the area. Results from the present study will be used to enrich the development of a Good Practice Guide resulting from the project, which will provide valuable instructions for proper implementation of Agroforestry in Thessaly region. Furthermore, methodology applied in this study could be fruitfully used in different areas of Greece. Results could be useful for policy makers, especially the trade-off analysis between economic and ecological benefits. Notably, Greece has still not adopted the Agroforestry Measure 8.2 provided by the updated EU’s Common Agriculture Policy, and this model-study may be proved as valuable to this adoption. The policy makers have the potential to enhance the utilization of one or another land use in order to achieve a balance between economic and ecological benefits, thus to assess potential effects of land management choices, and guide the design of more informed decisions. The trade-off analysis could rise their awareness about the potential trade-offs that arise from their decisions. The proposed models could be extended to other areas of Greece, by specifying the parameters of the optimization models. Especially for Greece, the models can directly be applied to other areas by only adjusting the parameters of the optimization models for urban land. The results of this study can be used as input to the CLUE-S model in order to predict the future change on different land uses in the area of Mouzaki. For future research, we plan to apply the models in other areas of Greece and compare the results.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.V., V.K.; methodology, G.M., M.V., D.C., S.N. and V.K.; software, G.M.; validation, G.M., M.V., D.C., S.N. and V.K.; formal analysis G.M., M.V., D.C., S.N. and V.K.; investigation, G.M., M.V., D.C., S.N. and V.K.; resources, G.M., M.V. and D.C.; data curation, G.M., M.V., D.C., S.N. and V.K.; writing—original draft preparation, G.M., M.V., D.C., S.N. and V.K.; writing—review and editing, G.M., M.V., D.C., S.N. and V.K.; visualization, G.M., M.V., D.C., S.N. and V.K.; supervision, M.V. and V.K.; project administration, V.K.; funding acquisition, V.K. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the General Secretariat for Research and Innovation (GSRI) and the Hellenic Foundation for Research and Innovation (HFRI) with funding number 2610, and “The APC was funded by the General Secretariat for Research and Innovation (GSRI) and the Hellenic Foundation for Research and Innovation (HFRI)”.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data and material is available upon request.

Acknowledgments

The present study is part of the project entitled “Perspective of Agroforestry in Thessaly region: A research on social, environmental and economic aspects to enhance farmer participation”. The project is funded by the General Secretariat for Research and Innovation (GSRI) and the Hellenic Foundation for Research and Innovation (HFRI).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Ambarli, D.; Vrahnakis, M.; Burrascano, S.; Naqinezhad, A.; Pulido Fernández, M. Grasslands of the Mediterranean Basin and the Middle East and their management. In Grasslands of the World: Diversity, Management and Conservation; Squires, V.R., Dengler, J., Feng, H., Hua, L., Eds.; CRC Press: Boca Raton, FL, USA, 2018; ISBN 9781498796262. [Google Scholar]
  2. Guarino, R.; Vrahnakis, M.; Rodriguez Rojo, M.P.; Giouga, L.; Pasta, S. Grasslands and shrublands of the Mediterranean region. In Encyclopedia of the World’s Biomes. Volume 3: Forests—Trees of Life; Goldstein, M.I., DellaSala, D.A., DiPaolo, D.A., Eds.; Grasslands and Shrublands—Sea of Plants; Elsevier: Amsterdam, NL, USA, 2020; ISBN 978-012-8160-96-1. [Google Scholar]
  3. Chouvardas, D. Estimation of Diachronic Effects of Pastoral Systems and Land Uses in Landscapes with the Use of Geographic Information Systems (GIS). Ph.D. Thesis, School of Forestry and Natural Environment, Aristotle University of Thessaloniki, Thessaloniki, Greece, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  4. Papanastasis, V.P. Land use changes. In Mediterranean Mountain Environment; Vogiatzakis, I., Ed.; John Wiley & Sons Ltd.: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2012; pp. 159–184. [Google Scholar]
  5. Chouvardas, D.; Ispikoudis, I.; Mitka, K.; Evangelou, C.; Papanastasis, V.P. Diachronic evolution of land use/ cover changes in pastoral landscapes of Greece. In Dry Grasslands of Europe: Grazing and Ecosystem Services; Vrahnakis, M., Kyriazopoulos, A.P., Chouvardas, D., Fotiadis, G., Eds.; Hellenic Range and Pasture Society: Thessaloniki, Greece, 2013; pp. 277–282. [Google Scholar]
  6. Perpiña, C.; Kavalov, B.; Diogo, V.; Jacobs-Crisioni, C.; Batista e Silva, F.; Lavalle, C. Agricultural Land Abandonment in the EU within 2015–2030; European Commission 2018; Joint Research Centre (Seville Site): Seville, Spain, 2018; p. JRC113718. [Google Scholar]
  7. Vrahnakis, M.; Nasiakou, S.; Kazoglou, Y.; Blanas, G. Business model for agroforestry consulting company. Agrofor. Syst. 2016, 90, 219–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Mwase, W.; Sefasi, A.; Njoloma, J.; Nyoka, B.I.; Manduwa, D.; Nyaika, J. Factors affecting the adoption of Agroforestry and evergreen agriculture in southern Africa. Environ. Nat. Resour. Res. 2015, 5, 148–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Adesina, A.; Chianu, J.N. Determinants of farmers’ adoption and adaptation of alley farming technology in Nigeria. Agrofor. Syst. 2002, 55, 99–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Fischer, A.; Vasseur, L. Smallholder perceptions of agroforestry projects in Panama. Agrofor. Syst. 2002, 54, 103–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Neupane, R.P.; Sharma, K.R.; Thapa, G.B. Adoption of agroforestry in the hills of Nepal: A logistic regression analysis. Agric. Syst. 2002, 72, 177–196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Bannister, M.E.; Nair, P.K.R. Agroforestry adoption in Haiti: The importance of household and farm characteristics. Agrofor. Syst. 2003, 57, 149–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Djalilov, B.M.; Khamzina, A.; Hornidge, A.-K.; Lamers, J.P.A. Exploring constraints and incentives for the adoption of agroforestry practices on degraded cropland in Uzbekistan. J. Environ. Plan. Manag. 2015, 59, 142–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Marra, M.C.; Pannell, D.J.; Amir, A.G. The economics of risk, uncertainty and learning in the adoption of new agricultural technologies: Where are we on the learning curve? Agric. Syst. 2003, 75, 215–234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Verburg, P.H.; Schot, P.; Dust, M.; Veldkamp, A. Land use change modelling: Current practice and research priorities. GeoJournal 2004, 64, 309–324. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Xiang, W.-N.; Clarke, K.C. The use of scenarios in land-use planning. Environ. Plan. B Plan. Des. 2003, 30, 885–909. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Shearer, A. Approaching scenario-based studies: Three perceptions about the future and considerations for landscape planning. Environ. Plan. B Plan. Des. 2005, 32, 67–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Veldkamp, A.; Lambin, E.F. Predicting Land Use Change. Agric. Ecosyst. Environ. 2001, 85, 1–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Verburg, P.H.; Soepboer, W.; Veldkamp, A.; Limpiada, R.; Espaldon, V.; Mastura, S. Modeling the spatial dynamics of regional land use: The CLUE-S model. Environ. Manag. 2002, 30, 391–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Chouvardas, D.; Vrahnakis, M.S. A semi-empirical model for the near-future evolution of the lake Koronia landscape. J. Environ. Prot. Ecol. 2009, 10, 867–876. [Google Scholar]
  21. Zhang, P.; Liu, Y.; Pan, Y.; Yu, Z. Land use pattern optimization based on CLUE-S and SWAT models for agricultural non-point source pollution control. Math. Comput. Model. 2013, 58, 558–595. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Han, H.; Yang, C.; Song, J. Scenario Simulation and the Prediction of Land Use and Land Cover Change in Beijing, China. Sustainability 2015, 7, 4260–4279. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Reginster, I.; Rounsevel, M. Scenarios of future urban land use in Europe. Environ. Plan. B Urban Anal. City Sci. 2006, 33, 619–636. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Hoymann, J. Quantifying demand for built-up area—A comparison of approaches and application to regions with stagnating population. J. Land Use Sci. 2012, 7, 67–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Wang, Y.; Li, X.; Zhang, Q.; Li, J.; Zhou, X. Projections of future land use changes: Multiple scenarios-based impacts analysis on ecosystem services for Wuhan city, China. Ecol. Indic. 2018, 94, 430–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Nasiakou, S.; Chouvardas, D.; Vrahnakis, M.; Kleftoyianni, V. Temporal changes analysis of Mouzaki’s landscape, western Thessaly, Greece (1960–2020). In Proceedings of the 10th Panhellenic Rangeland Congress of the Hellenic Range and Pasture Society, Florina, Greece, 2021; p. 6, in press. (In Greek with English Summary). [Google Scholar]
  27. HSA. State’s Statistical Data; Hellenic Statistic Authority: Athens, Greece, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  28. Mantzanas, K. Forest Species with Short Rotation Time and Agroforestry. In Forest Wood Species Plantations of Short Rotation Time for Biomass Production and Thermal Uses; Centre for Renewable Energy Sources and Saving (CRES), Department of Biomass, AGROTICA: Thessaloniki, Greece, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  29. Albanis, Κ.; Xanthopoulos, G.; Skouteri, A.; Theodoridis, N.; Christodoulou, A.; Palaskas, D. Methodology for Estimating the Value of Forest Land in Greece—Detailed Manual; Institute of Mediterranean Forest Ecosystems and Forest Products Technology, Ministry of Environment and Energy: Athens, Greece, 2015.
  30. Costanza, R.; d’Arge, R.; de Groot, R.; Farberk, S.; Grasso, M.; Hannon, B.; Limburg, K.; Naeem, S.; O’Neill, R.V.; Paruelo, J.; et al. The value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Nature 1997, 387, 253–260. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Land use map of Mouzaki Municipality, Greece for 2020.
Figure 1. Land use map of Mouzaki Municipality, Greece for 2020.
Land 10 01097 g001
Figure 2. The Pareto front as formed for objectives 1 and 2 (functions f1(x) and f2(x), respectively).
Figure 2. The Pareto front as formed for objectives 1 and 2 (functions f1(x) and f2(x), respectively).
Land 10 01097 g002
Table 1. Historical, current and predicted area (Ha) in 2040 for the BAU scenario (Municipality of Mouzaki, Greece).
Table 1. Historical, current and predicted area (Ha) in 2040 for the BAU scenario (Municipality of Mouzaki, Greece).
VariableLand Use TypeArea in 1960 (Ha)Area in 2020 (Ha)Difference (%)Predicted Area in 2040 (Ha)
x1Agricultural land14,206.5211,144.03−21.5610,343.15
x2Silvoarable land200.51556.38177.48650.26
x3Grassland5009.692405−51.991988.21
x4Silvopastoral woodland (10–40% tree cover)2525.423815.3951.084000.68
x5Forest (40–100% tree cover)5175.810,573.64104.2911,622.04
x6Sparse shrubland (10–40% cover)394.88503.7427.57516.94
x7Dense shrubland (40–100% cover)2398.44784.99−67.27608.97
x8Urban land939.721457.7955.131534.20
x9Barren land475.9986.01−81.9362.52
TOTAL:31,326.9731,326.97-31,326.97
Table 2. Value (EUR) of forest per service and forest species.
Table 2. Value (EUR) of forest per service and forest species.
Services and ExternalitiesFirSprucePineBeechOakTotal
Total area (Ha)548,0702754878,786336,640470,9892,237,239
Wood production (×106 €)29.060.7227.9615.2212.6785.63
Non-Wood Forest Products (×106 €)
Mushroom0.82 0.420.500.712.45
Honey5.610.0289.003.4515.0733.16
Christmas trees0.62 0.62
Resin 9.58 9.58
Pine seeds 0.55 0.55
Total (NTFPs)7.050.0319.553.9515.7846.36
Livestock grazing (×106 €)16.630.0826.8910.300.0053.90
Hunting (×106 €)0.540.000.860.330.462.19
Recreation (×106 €)51.680.2682.8731.7544.41210.97
Soil protection (×106 €)57.550.2992.27035.35103.03288.49
C sequestration (×106 €)2.860.0175.692.193.0113.77
Biodiversity (×106 €)46.040.2373.8228.2839.56187.93
Losses (wildfires) (×106 €)21.180.1248.6412.4346.03128.40
Total annual value (×106 €)190.231.52281.27114.94172.89760.85
Table 3. Value (EUR/Ha) of ecosystem services per land use category in the area of the Municipality of Mouzaki, adapted from Albanis et al. [29].
Table 3. Value (EUR/Ha) of ecosystem services per land use category in the area of the Municipality of Mouzaki, adapted from Albanis et al. [29].
VariableLand Use TypeAnnual Financial Benefit (€/Ha)
x1Agricultural land3146.10
x2Silvoarable land3914.55
x3Grassland306.74
x4Silvopastoral woodland (10–40% tree cover)278.64
x5Forest (40–100% tree cover)340.08
x6Sparse shrubland (10–40% cover)511.68
x7Dense shrubland (40–100% cover)188.3
x8Urban land45,038.35
x9Barren land0.0
Table 4. Value (EUR) of grassland, silvopastoral woodland and sparse and dense shrubland per service and product.
Table 4. Value (EUR) of grassland, silvopastoral woodland and sparse and dense shrubland per service and product.
Services and ExternalitiesGrasslandSilvopastoral WoodlandSparse ShrublandDense Shrubland
Total area (Ha)1,000,0001,000,8501,309,9921,964,987
Wood production (×106 €) 12.671.5082.262
Mushrooms (×106 €) 1.500.0350.015
Honey (×106 €)10.2410.2520.11813.412
Heath (Erica) roots (x 106) 0.0040.002
Livestock grazing (×106 €)125.0045.04211.12852.782
Hunting (×106 €)0.980.982.2400.960
Recreation (×106 €)91.0094.38199.37649.840
Soil protection (×106 €)67.9851.5168.776275.100
C sequestration (×106 €)1.221.501.1481.720
Biodiversity (×106 €)48.0084.07220.08055.020
Losses (wildfires) (×106 €)37.6823.0254.11281.170
Total annual value (×106 €)306.74278.88670.301369.955
Table 5. Value (EUR/Ha) of ecosystem services by land use category in the area of the Municipality of Mouzaki, adapted from Constanza et al. [30].
Table 5. Value (EUR/Ha) of ecosystem services by land use category in the area of the Municipality of Mouzaki, adapted from Constanza et al. [30].
VariableLand Use TypeAnnual Financial Benefit (€/Ha)
x1Agricultural land67.75
x2Silvoarable land178.94
x3Grassland170.84
x4Silvopastoral woodland (10–40% tree cover)196.61
x5Forest (40–100% tree cover)222.38
x6Sparse shrubland (10–40% cover)170.84
x7Dense shrubland (40–100% cover)170.84
x8Urban land0.0
x9Barren land0.0
Table 6. Estimated area in 2040 (Ha) under the three scenarios (BAU, RED, ELP).
Table 6. Estimated area in 2040 (Ha) under the three scenarios (BAU, RED, ELP).
VariableLand Use TypeEstimated Area in 2040 (Ha)
BAUREDELP
x1Agricultural land10,343.1511,144.0310,343.15
x2Silvoarable land650.26885.53556.38
x3Grassland1988.212026.211988.21
x4Silvopastoral woodland (10–40% tree cover)000.683815.393815.39
x5Forest (40–100% tree cover)11,622.0410,617.4512,053.37
x6Sparse shrubland (10–40% cover)516.94541.71503.74
x7Dense shrubland (40–100% cover)608.97608.97608.97
x8Urban land1534.21725.681457.79
x9Barren land62.5200
TOTAL31,326.9731,326.9731,326.97
Table 7. Estimated area in 2040 (Ha) under RED scenario, after relaxing constraint C5.
Table 7. Estimated area in 2040 (Ha) under RED scenario, after relaxing constraint C5.
VariableLand Use TypeEstimated Area in 2040 (Ha)
RED
x1Agricultural land10,343.15
x2Silvoarable land1768.22
x3Grassland1988.21
x4Silvopastoral woodland (10–40% tree cover)3815.39
x5Forest (40–100% tree cover)10,573.64
x6Sparse shrubland (10–40% cover)503.74
x7Dense shrubland (40–100% cover)608.97
x8Urban land1725.68
x9Barren land0
TOTAL31,326.97
Table 8. Results of the Pareto front, optimal areas for economic and ecological benefits (F1 and F2, respectively).
Table 8. Results of the Pareto front, optimal areas for economic and ecological benefits (F1 and F2, respectively).
Point 1Point 2Point 3Point 4Point 5Point 6Point 7Point 8Point 9Point 10Point 11
X110,343.1510,343.1510,343.1510,343.1510,343.1510,343.1510,343.1510,343.1510,343.1510,343.1510,343.15
X21768.191509.881251.56993.23734.91556.38556.38556.38556.38556.38556.38
X31988.211988.211988.211988.211988.211988.211988.211988.211988.211988.211988.21
X43815.393815.393815.393815.393815.393815.393815.393815.393815.393815.393815.39
X510,573.6410,831.9511,090.2711,348.6011,606.9211,801.0411,851.5011,901.9611,952.4212,002.8812,053.34
X6503,74503.74503.74503.74503.74503.74503.74503.74503.74503.74503.74
X7608.97608.97608.97608.97608.97608.97608.97608.97608.97608.97608.97
X81725.681725.681725.681725.681725.681710.091659.631609.171558.711508.251457.79
X90.000000000000
F1122,825,300.00121,902,000.00120,978,600.00120,055,300.00119,131,900.00117,797,100.00115,541,500.00113,286,000.00111,030,500.00108,775,000.00106,519,500.00
F24,648,419.004,659,640.504,670,862.004,682,083.504,693,305.004,704,526.504,715,748.004,726,969.504,738,191.004,749,412.504,760,634.00
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Mamanis, G.; Vrahnakis, M.; Chouvardas, D.; Nasiakou, S.; Kleftoyanni, V. Land Use Demands for the CLUE-S Spatiotemporal Model in an Agroforestry Perspective. Land 2021, 10, 1097. https://doi.org/10.3390/land10101097

AMA Style

Mamanis G, Vrahnakis M, Chouvardas D, Nasiakou S, Kleftoyanni V. Land Use Demands for the CLUE-S Spatiotemporal Model in an Agroforestry Perspective. Land. 2021; 10(10):1097. https://doi.org/10.3390/land10101097

Chicago/Turabian Style

Mamanis, Georgios, Michael Vrahnakis, Dimitrios Chouvardas, Stamatia Nasiakou, and Vassiliki Kleftoyanni. 2021. "Land Use Demands for the CLUE-S Spatiotemporal Model in an Agroforestry Perspective" Land 10, no. 10: 1097. https://doi.org/10.3390/land10101097

APA Style

Mamanis, G., Vrahnakis, M., Chouvardas, D., Nasiakou, S., & Kleftoyanni, V. (2021). Land Use Demands for the CLUE-S Spatiotemporal Model in an Agroforestry Perspective. Land, 10(10), 1097. https://doi.org/10.3390/land10101097

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop