1. Introduction
The main challenge faced by agriculture is to provide the population with the food and other bio-products necessary for their development while protecting natural capital, which means using it in a sustainable way [
1]. Improvements in sustainability at the farm level are the basic driver of agricultural sustainability at the macro level [
2], which means performing stable, economically viable, socially accepted and environmentally sound production activity. Hence, sustainable farm development depends on three main factors: economic, environmental and social factors. The attainment of sustainability at the farm level is largely based on economic sustainability, which is expressed by actions such as investing and reaping the related economic outcomes (which drive improvements in sustainability). However, as Savickienė and Miceikienė [
3] emphasize, when dealing with farm sustainability, researchers mostly focus on the environmental and social aspects while neglecting the impact of the economic factor. Nevertheless, as shown by the literature review [
4,
5], the economic factor is of key importance to sustainable farm development because the other two factors depend on it. Ensuring an adequate level of production profitability is the only way to encourage farmers to take better care of the environment which, in turn, can translate into improvements in the population’s standards of living, as emphasized by Savickienė and Miceikienė [
3]. This is a challenge that can only be met by farms which efficiently process inputs into products [
6]. Improvements in productivity—i.e., greater output per unit of input—result in reducing harmful pressures on the environment and improving profitability either by enhancing productivity or by reducing costs [
7]. Many countries rely on a broad spectrum of intervention instruments to support the sustainable development of the agricultural sector because of its particularities.
In European Union countries, government intervention in agriculture is underpinned by the Common Agricultural Policy, which was designed primarily to ensure sustainable agricultural development by pursuing social, economic and environmental goals [
6], and the farms are covered by a series of its intervention mechanisms. Since 2000, the Common Agricultural Policy has been composed of two pillars. The objectives of the first one include supporting farm incomes and promoting environmental sustainability and animal welfare. The second pillar involves structural measures (mostly including investment support) which take into account the particularities and rural development requirements of each EU member country [
8]. In that context, a highly important outcome of investment measures taken under the CAP is the implementation of state-of-the-art technologies which contribute to environmental protection and counteract adverse climate change; this is how they meet the priority goals sought by the Community, which intends to stop adverse climatic changes. The European Union encourages farmers to employ environmentally friendly solutions [
9], rewarding environmental enhancements with investment subsidies.
European Union countries differ from each other in the size and structure of their agricultural output, including crop yields, unit livestock productivity ratios and the size and structure of inputs. As a consequence, they also differ in economic performance [
10]. There are many reasons behind the differences in the resource, production and economic situations of farms [
11,
12]. According to many authors [
13,
14,
15,
16], Common Agricultural Policy instruments are increasingly often the cause of these gaps between countries. In this context, it is worthy of note that member countries differ in how long they have been covered by CAP instruments (depending on when they joined the EU). The newest members (who joined the Community after 2000) mainly include Central and Eastern European countries, who differ from the “old” Union in terms of their agricultural policies and the economic developments experienced in recent years [
17]. They have now been covered by the implementation of CAP measures for more than ten years. The above situation makes it even more imperative to assess the effectiveness of these mechanisms on the changes in the economic situation of farms in these countries.
Structural measures which promote farm modernization and restructuring play an important role in member countries who joined the EU in 2004. This is because, as regards the techniques and technologies employed and the advancement of structural transformation processes [
18,
19,
20], they lag considerably behind countries who underwent the necessary changes in the post-war period [
21,
22,
23]. The objective of investment support under the CAP is to overcome the many factors that restrict the farms’ capacity to incur significant investment expenditure. Therefore, since the implementation of pre-accession mechanisms to this day, support for farm development investments has been among the key instruments of the agricultural transformation process [
24]. This enables a faster implementation of technical, biological and organizational advancements which, in turn, contribute to increasing the agricultural production potential and driving improvements in the farms’ economic performance [
25,
26,
27]. The expected outcome of investment mechanisms available under the second pillar of the CAP is an improvement in productivity and economic performance at farm level [
28]. This is because modern agriculture requires capital [
29]. Investment decisions affect both current and future production [
30]. Taking into consideration the limited access to capital due to the unique characteristics of agricultural sectors throughout the world [
31,
32,
33], many governments see it as their responsibility to assist farmers in obtaining capital. Agricultural programs in developed market economies, such as Western Europe, have evolved over the years and have been rationalized as interventions to correct market failures [
29]. Similarly, Barry and Robinson [
32] assume that the policy element of agricultural finance considers the role of governments in filling the gaps and resolving imperfections in the agricultural finance markets and in providing targeted assistance to designated recipients. The importance of CAP investment mechanisms to the development of farms was also emphasized by Guastella et al. [
34] and Czubak and Sadowski [
35]. For instance, in Poland, agricultural investments doubled after the accession to the EU. This contributed to improving the availability of fixed assets in farms [
36]. However, the countries differ considerably in how they implement CAP investment measures [
37] which, in turn, can affect the possible impacts of interventions on the renewal and development of the farms’ technical assets.
A situation in which the farms become highly dependent upon subsidies could undermine the improvements in productivity and efficiency; that fact also makes it reasonable to address the impacts of intervention mechanisms designed to promote investments [
38]. The metrics of efficiency include technical efficiency—a concept which means that an enterprise should seek to maximize output under the assumption that a defined level of input is available [
39]. As shown by a literature review, that aspect was addressed by several researchers who endeavored to determine the relationship between agricultural subsidies and technical efficiency; however, they ended up with contrasting findings [
40]. For instance, in their meta-analysis comprising 70 different studies spanning over a period of circa 30 years, Minviel and Latruffe [
41] demonstrated that agricultural subsidies had a significant negative impact on the farms’ technical efficiency. However, on the other hand, a number of papers exist that confirm the positive effect of subsidies on farm efficiency [
42,
43,
44]. These contradictions could result from differences in agricultural characteristics between the countries, and from structural differences between intervention mechanisms [
45]. The dual impact of subsidies on changes in efficiency is particularly noticeable in the case of payments decoupled from production volumes [
46]. Various types of subsidies can result in different impacts on farms, and hence can have different effects on their efficiency and profitability [
47].
The diverse impacts are also confirmed in studies by Bonfiglio [
40], who found that the effect of subsidies on the farms’ technical efficiency can differ in terms of the function of factors, including their type of farming. Despite these highly interesting findings, the authors point to certain imperfections in their studies. First of all, there are some reservations as to the analysis period, which was only one year. The authors believe that a longer time perspective could yield more reliable findings [
40]. Therefore, unlike their research project, the analysis presented in this paper covers a broader time frame (12 years) and a larger territory (eight countries). According to some studies, while subsidies can drive an increase in input productivity, this mainly depends on their nature [
45]. Therefore, this paper focuses on investment mechanisms which can enhance productivity and reduce costs (and, as a consequence, improve profitability), as confirmed by numerous studies, including those by Boulanger and Philippidis [
47] and Dudu and Kristkova [
48].
This paper relied on micro-data from the Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) operated by DG-AGRI. According to Michalek [
49], FADN is the only data source suitable for research based on the counterfactual approach, including the Propensity Score Matching used in this study. The European FADN was established in European Economic Community countries upon the implementation of Common Agricultural Policy mechanisms. Note that only commercial farms are monitored by the system. While findings from research based on FADN micro-data (such as this paper) are available, they relate solely to single regions or countries [
49,
50]. Importantly, the authors cited above consider the counterfactual method used in this paper to be suitable for assessing the Rural Development Programs implemented by the EU, including the intervention measures taken to promote investments. In practice, the following four alternative methods, referred to as naïve methods, are generally used in evaluating the EU programs [
49]: (1) observing only the beneficiaries of aid prior to, and following the receipt of, subsidies (this approach fails to take account of other impacts on the change in the situation); (2) comparing the group of beneficiaries with all other operators; or (3) comparing the group of beneficiaries with an averaged group composed of beneficiaries and non-beneficiaries (these approaches fail to take account of comparability between groups which may be composed of operators with different characteristics); and (4) a method which consists of comparing the beneficiary group with a random control group (without matching, which also makes the groups non-comparable). Unlike the above methods, PSM enables the examination of the net effect of interventions by comparing two groups (the beneficiaries and the control group) which share similar characteristics based on the selected variables.
This paper contributes to the literature by determining the changes in the production and income efficiency of farms resulting from the implementation of investment mechanisms under the CAP. Despite many attempts and a number of dedicated studies, scientific discussion is still ongoing because no clear answer has yet been provided to the question of the impacts of intervention mechanisms (including investment measures) on the broadly defined economic condition of farms. This study was designed to answer the following research questions: what is the impact of investment intervention mechanisms on the situation of farms as regards changes in productive inputs (labor, land and capital), the relationships between them and the production and income performance? Are there any significant differences between the beneficiaries of investment support programs and farms which do not access these programs? Are there any significant differences between the countries in terms of the production and income-related effects of the implementation of investment mechanisms under the second pillar of the CAP? Answers to these questions are sought through an analysis of productivity and profitability indicators of labor, land and capital.
The paper is organized as follows:
Section 2 describes the unique FADN source data and the research methods employed.
Section 3 presents and discusses the key findings. Finally,
Section 4 presents the summary, conclusions, relevant political implications and guidelines for further research.
2. Materials and Methods
Unpublished FADN microdata provided by the European Commission’s DG AGRI were used as the source material. The study presented in this paper is unique in that the research tasks are based on unpublished microdata of selected Central and Eastern European farms. The microeconomic nature of this data also makes it possible to carry out dynamic analyses [
51]. Formal guidelines for working with extremely sensitive data are highly restrictive, and therefore this paper only presents aggregated results for 15 farms. The research covered selected Central and Eastern European countries: Czech Republic, Estonia, Lithuania, Latvia, Poland, Slovakia, Slovenia and Hungary. For the purposes of this research, the countries were selected because of their geographic location and (mostly) because they joined the EU in the same year. Of the countries who joined the EU in 2004, Cyprus and Malta were excluded because (as shown by previous own research and a study of the relevant literature) their agriculture is substantially different and unique. The study period was 2004–2015. The initial year marks the first enlargement of the EU with CEE countries, while the last year corresponds to the most recent data from FADN resources. Agricultural accounting data are subject to a multi-stage verification process at farm, national and European Commission levels and are therefore made available only after a delay. Hence, 2015 was the last period surveyed.
The implementation of agricultural policies entails heavy expenditure, and public funds must therefore be disbursed to provide investment support. The implementation of relevant measures needs to be evaluated to determine the actual benefits brought by specific instruments. The main purpose of the evaluation is to improve the effectiveness, quality and coherence of the implemented programs [
52]. Support to the investment and modernization of agricultural holdings is a capital subsidy that aims to encourage agricultural firms to undertake more gross investment in plants, machinery, and new production equipment on the assumption that this results in increased productivity and output [
25]. Hence, it is important to determine the outcomes brought by the implementation of these instruments, which is the main research goal of this paper.
In practice, the evaluation of political interventions proves to be a difficult task [
53]. The analytical difficulty is the assessment of the causative link, i.e. the attribution of changes to the implemented policy. The problem of causality was addressed by a number of researchers, including Fisher, Neyman, Cochran, Cox, Heckman, Roy, Quandt and Rubin [
54]. The randomized controlled experiment is a recognized method for the assessment of causative links [
55]. However, in economic analyses, experiments seem to be extremely difficult, if not impossible, because of numerous technical, social or ethical restrictions. In such cases, efforts should be made to assign the characteristics of an experimental set to the available dataset. This can be done by combining data, in particular by using the Propensity Score Matching method [
56,
57].
When interpreting the results of economic analyses, it is very helpful to compare the figures with reference entities or to make a time comparison (from 2004 onwards) or a regional comparison (within eight CEE countries). In this research, the above is of key importance in order to answer the question of how the selected agricultural interventionism mechanisms affect the microeconomic situation of farms in different countries. In other words, the purpose of the analysis was to determine the net effect of selected measures in particular countries (
Figure 1).
This effect may be estimated by comparing the average economic performance of farms covered by structural support with that recorded in the control group. The reference group included similar operators selected based on their resources of productive inputs: labor, land and capital. The analysis was based on Propensity Score Matching (PSM). As a consequence, it was possible to compare microeconomic data between beneficiaries of structural funds and their counterparts from the control pool.
All farms covered were divided into the beneficiaries’ pool and the control pool as per the formula below
where
Accordingly, the control pool was composed of farms which did not access any investment support under the second pillar of the CAP in the entire study period (2004–2015) but, at the same time, they met the minimum requirements for investment support measures (including the minimum economic size or maximum acreage). This is how the second methodological assumption was met, which requires that each farm have equal opportunities in applying for investment subsidies. In turn, experimental farms were those which accessed support for the first time in year t
1, with the total amount of support in the following 5 years being no less than EUR 5,000. A large proportion of farms was eliminated because of the unavailability of continuous records in the FADN database within a period of no less than 6 years. This study used a 6-year analysis period, which is consistent with program requirements for the minimum sustainability of investment, plus one year preceding the investment. The population of the experimental and control pools was as follows (
Table 1).
The initial situation of, and the differences between, the two groups of farms (the beneficiaries and the control group) were determined for the year before the use of pro-investment funds (t0). This allowed us to avoid the distorting impact of the pro-investment subsidies received on the farms’ economic standing (which is an essential part of this research). The input variables of the PSM vector were set as utilized agricultural area in hectares (SE025), labor input in AWU (Annual Work Unit, SE010) and gross fixed assets other than land (SE441–SE446). As a consequence, the paired farms had a similar production potential (a similar value of productive inputs) in year t0. In year t1, one of them started to access pro-investment funds (the experimental group) while the other one (the control group) did not. This resulted in the creation of two equally sized groups for each country. The difference in the size of the groups between the countries is mostly due to the difference in the continuous presence of respective farms in the FADN database. For instance, the Polish FADN includes 3964 farms with continuous entries from 2004 to 2015, whereas in Lithuania, continuous data were available only for 23 farms. The number of farms which have been keeping records in the FADN database for a 6-year period reached the required minimum (15) in all countries. Hence, it is possible to present the results for all of them.
The matching-based estimation consists of analyzing the counterfactual conditions, i.e., the hypothetical values of the outcome variable. When considering the impact of a treatment on the outcome variable, calculating the magnitude of that impact means determining the effect one treatment would have had on a unit which, in fact, received some other treatment [
58]. Therefore, in the counterfactual approach, the outcome variable may be defined as [
59,
60]
where
Yi: the value of the outcome variable for unit i;
Yi1, Yi0: the values of the outcome variable in the case where unit i either received a treatment or did not receive it (respectively);
Di: a Boolean variable, which is 0 if unit i did not receive the treatment, or 1 otherwise.
The effect of the treatment on the outcome variable considered may be determined at the level of a single observation as per the following formula
In fact, variable D may only have one of two possible values, and therefore only one of the outcomes may be observed (Y
i1 or Y
i0). Under the assumption that Y
i1 is known, no information is available on Y
i0. This situation is referred to by Rubin et al. [
61] and Heckman et al. [
62] as the missing data problem. One way to solve this is to consider the counterfactual conditions, i.e., the estimations which approximate the non-observable values of the variables
where
and
are the estimated potential values of the outcome variable in the case where unit i either did not receive a treatment or did receive it (respectively).
Many authors, including Holland [
63], refer to the static solution, which consists of shifting from the unit level to the level of the population to which that unit belongs. Let W
ATE be the average treatment effect (ATE) for population I. In accordance with earlier assumptions for the unit causal effect, the following is true
Or
where E(Y
1) is the average effect in a situation where all units across the population received the treatment, and E(Y
0) is the average effect in a situation where all units are included in the control group. In order to assess specific actions, a researcher must focus only on the effect experienced by units subject to intervention. In this situation, the treatment on treated effect (Average Treatment of Treated) is sought, and may be expressed as follows [
60]
where
E(Y1 | D = 1): the average outcome of the intervention in the group of units which received the treatment.
E(Y0| D = 1): the average outcome of the absence of intervention in the group which received the treatment.
E(Y0| D = 1) is the non-observable (counterfactual) effect, which, however, may be estimated. In fact, (Y0| D = 0) is known. This is the average effect experienced after intervention by units who were not covered by it. Under the assumption that all the units of the population are identical, the following is true: E(Y0| D = 0) = E(Y0| D = 1). In this situation, the causal effect would be the difference between the outcome of the unit who received the treatment and the outcome of any unit from the control pool.
In the matching-based estimation, the basic problem is the multidimensionality of empirical data. Paired units should demonstrate identical or similar characteristics [
57].
Once the variables characterizing the experimental group and the control group are established; the next step is the estimation of the propensity score (P(Xi)), which is the probability that an entity will access the investment support program, determined based on the selected variables for the period prior to accessing the program. Next, farms from the experimental and control groups are paired based on similar P(Xi) values. While P(X
i) may be estimated in different ways, logit and probit models are cited in the literature as the most useful methods (with logit being the preferred one) [
64]. Logistic regression is the most frequently used procedure [
57].
Once the data are combined, the variables covered by actions performed in the experimental group and in the control group were checked for balanced distribution. In accordance with the procedure proposed by P. Rosenbaum and D. Rubin [
58], the selection was assessed by analyzing the changes in standard loadings of variables, i.e., the degree of variation in the distributions of specific variables in the experimental group and in the control group.
In summary, the impact of pro-investment support on farm incomes was measured as per the diagram below [
57] (
Figure 2).
Two approaches to determining the growth rate were considered. The first one consisted of using the geometric mean of chain indexes and would actually mean taking the initial and final datapoints of the time series into consideration. However, that approach was found to be poorly substantiated, especially as the processes studied did not follow a steady (upward or downward) trend. As shown by a preliminary analysis of empirical data, the growth rates of the phenomena concerned did not always follow a clear trend. As a consequence, in order to determine the growth rate, the authors used an approach which was based on all datapoints of the time series and, thus took into account the diverse changes throughout the study period. Following this, the average growth rate served as a basis for determining the dynamics of selected farm variables in both groups in the period t
0–t
5, as per the formula below [
65]
where
4. Conclusions
The purpose of this study was to determine the net effect of implementing pro-investment instruments available under the second pillar of the CAP in selected Central and Eastern European countries. With regard to developing production potential (i.e., the availability of productive inputs), structural funds disbursed under the CAP clearly provided an investment incentive for farms. In many countries, they actually made development investments possible. In addition to increasing the value of their fixed assets, farms which accessed investment funds also expanded their resources of agricultural land. When assessing the changes, it is important to note that most countries saw a positive net effect because the beneficiaries reported a greater increase in fixed asset value and in farm area (except for Slovakian beneficiaries, who experienced a decline in both fixed asset value and land resources, and for Czech beneficiaries, who witnessed a reduction in their land resources). The comparative analysis of countries covered by this study failed to clearly confirm that labor is substituted with capital to a significant extent.
Regarding the productivity and profitability of productive inputs, the characteristic finding is that in the year preceding access to funds (t0), the results recorded by beneficiary farms were slightly better than, or comparable to, what was found in the control group. This is true for all countries except Poland, where the control group had significantly better levels of all productivity ratios in the initial period, while beneficiary farms had higher levels of land and capital profitability. Therefore, the beneficiaries of investment funds disbursed under the second pillar of the CAP were farms at a (slightly) higher or similar level of productivity of inputs. It is important to note, however, that the countries covered by this study differed in the observed net effects of investment mechanisms implemented. Every country covered by this study experienced a noticeable negative net effect on both the productivity and profitability of capital. In the 5th year of the analysis, statistically significant differences in capital productivity and profitability (testifying to the advantage of the control group) were found in all countries except Czech Republic and Slovakia. Although beneficiary farms had higher capital growth rates than the control group, they were not accompanied by a pro-rated increase in output value and income. When considering all the countries, the beneficiary group has no clear advantage over the control group in terms of changes in land productivity and profitability (a statistically significant positive effect was recorded for land productivity and profitability in Slovenia). This was similar for labor: a statistically significant positive net effect (a difference in growth rate between the beneficiary group and the control group) was recorded in Slovenia, but also in Poland where beneficiary farms reported a greater increment in labor profitability and reduced the negative difference in labor productivity. Beneficiary farms were able to maintain or increase labor profitability in the first years following the implementation of the investment. In can be reasonably expected (knowing the particularities of agricultural investments) that farms which access funds under the second pillar of the CAP implement diverse investments that develop their production potential; the outcomes (improvements in productivity and profitability) will emerge in different periods, often in the long term, which goes beyond the first years following the completion of the investment.
This study can provide guidelines for CAP decision makers, especially in the context of the new EU financial perspective for 2021–2027. The differences in the net effects of pro-investment measures between the countries suggest that subsidies should be aligned as much as possible with the characteristics of the local agricultural sector, which undoubtedly determine the outcomes of intervention mechanisms. As a consequence, the allocated funds will be used as efficiently as possible, resulting in the improved effectiveness, quality and cohesion of programs implemented. Furthermore, taking into account the long-term rate of return on agricultural investments could also provide some guidelines for agricultural policy regarding investment support mechanisms. Due to the particularities of agricultural production, farm investments are of a long-term nature (the buildings, constructions, machinery and equipment have a years-long lifecycle). Considering the above, it may be expected (though caution must be exercised) that the outcomes of investments, depending on their type, will also come to light with different delays, which will often be longer than the initial years following the completion of the investment. If the above hypothesis can be deemed true, it is worth considering whether the application documents related to investment support mechanisms should require the beneficiaries to outline the expected outcomes of investments over a longer period (e.g., a ten-year period).
Keeping the above in mind, the authors intend to extend the analysis period by several years in their further research. This will allow us to carry out more in-depth research on the impact of investments on economic sustainability, which is often attained as a long-term outcome. Moreover, it seems useful to carry out a similar analysis which, rather than considering all the farms together, would focus on representatives of the same type of farming or farms with a similar acreage and to make an attempt to determine the impact of the investment type on how fast the outcomes emerge.