1. Introduction
As a pivotal sector of China’s national economy, the construction industry is instrumental in advancing urbanization and modernization. Enterprise qualification, traditionally a cornerstone of qualification management in China’s construction sector, has long regulated the qualifications of practicing units. However, with economic growth, the absence of personal behavioral restrictions on practitioners has increasingly exposed issues within the building industry. The supervisory authority can enhance its ability to regulate practitioners’ credibility in the engineering construction field by increasing the transparency of decision-making processes among stakeholders.
Most studies concentrate on the credit regulation game between the government and construction companies [
1,
2,
3], with China’s present credit regulation of the construction sector primarily reliant on corporate credentials. The integrity system, social credit system, and regulatory mechanism of China’s building sector are the main subjects of this study. The Construction Contractor Credit Scoring (CCCS) system does not significantly enhance companies’ credit scores, yet the credit ratings of high-branch offices improve more rapidly. It suggests that the policy’s adoption requires time to have a cumulative effect [
4]. By reducing information asymmetry and enhancing internal governance, the social credit system dramatically increases the effectiveness of corporate investment. This impact is particularly noticeable for monopolies and non-state-owned businesses [
5,
6]. Government incentives and disincentives are important in encouraging the sustainable development of small and medium-sized businesses (SMEs) and lowering the risk of default [
7,
8]. The trust mechanism holds considerable significance in preventing opportunistic behavior in construction projects [
9], which is primarily led by the government. The government may successfully direct and control business conduct and support the long-term growth of the construction sector by strengthening the credit system, streamlining the regulatory approach, and establishing a trust mechanism. Many researchers have put forth techniques for evaluating credit in the context of personal credit that are based on approaches like tree models and XGBoost (v2.0) [
10,
11,
12,
13]. The government serves as the primary regulatory authority, while construction companies and practitioners constitute the regulated entities, and stakeholders engage in games centered around regulatory matters to form the credit system of the construction sector. In order to investigate the mechanisms of interaction between contractor groups, owners, and other business subjects, evolutionary game approaches and system dynamics theory have been frequently employed. Therefore, the evolutionary game method has been extensively used in research related to construction and is currently primarily utilized to analyze the dynamic interactive behavioral relationship between the government and construction enterprises’ unsafe behaviors, green innovations, etc. By coordinating the low regulatory costs and high penalties for breach of trust, the government can promote the sustainable development of the construction industry [
14]. Meanwhile, researchers have discovered that corporate breach of trust is significantly impacted by reputation difficulties, and that stringent regulations and a strong company reputation may assist in reducing the breach of trust of multinational engineering firms [
15,
16]. Furthermore, the complex regulatory framework of the construction industry and the variable rewards and punishments imposed by government agencies lead practitioners to develop nonlinear risk preferences and base their decisions on loss aversion.
Market participants’ decision-making behavior can be explained by behavioral finance theory, which has been extensively researched in relation to anchoring bias, loss aversion, and herd prejudice [
17]. Real estate finance [
18], project bidding, and behavioral finance are the starting points for researchers studying the institutional aspects of construction industry regulation. Researchers also proposed a project pricing framework based on cumulative prospect theory [
19], which takes into account the psychology of contractors’ risk appetite and demonstrates that the theory is also well-suited to the majority of the construction market. Prospect theory has been applied to the problem of multi-expert group decision-making by more researchers, and the results demonstrate how well it describes risk-averse profits and risk-seeking losses in uncertain decision-making processes [
20]. Practitioners’ decision-making habits are influenced by the market environment, contractual conduct, and opportunistic thinking. Contractual behavior and opportunistic behaviorism are not distinct systems, formal contracts have little impact on weak forms of opportunistic behavior. Penalties should be added to discourage opportunistic behavior among construction practitioners; relational governance among multiple actors can aid in dealing with such opportunistic behavior [
21]. Behavioral finance plays a crucial role in analyzing the irrational behaviors of multiple agents in the theoretical construction market. Overconfidence, herd behavior, and availability bias are key behavioral factors contributing to fluctuations in China’s real estate market [
22]. Scholars have employed behavioral finance to study the strategic interactions between governments and practitioners, effectively evaluating the impact of incentives, penalties, standards, and certifications in curbing dishonest practices [
23]. However, most existing studies focus on the macro level, making it difficult to capture the dynamic changes in practitioners’ psychological expectations.
Expected utility theory is a fundamental approach for assessing decision-making under risk. However, it fails to account for the influence of subjective experience and cognitive biases in construction processes. It struggles to describe scenarios where individuals, facing uncertain prospects, make decisions based on risk preferences that deviate from traditional expected value calculations. The emergence of prospect theory, grounded in psychological and economic principles, addresses these limitations. Prospect theory posits that decision-makers exhibit different preferences when facing gains versus losses. Since individuals do not operate under conditions of full rationality, their behavior deviates significantly from theoretical assumptions. Specifically, prospect theory suggests that individuals display a stronger preference for certain gains while experiencing asymmetric psychological effects when gaining or losing equivalent value. Decision-makers tend to exhibit risk aversion in the face of certain gains but demonstrate risk-seeking behavior when confronting potential losses.
Prospect theory has been extensively studied both domestically and internationally and is widely applied in multi-agent decision-making research. In terms of the methodological aspect, scholars have developed a heterogeneous multi-attribute group decision-making approach based on prospect theory, incorporating both positive and negative ideal solutions. By integrating individual prospect values to determine overall prospect values, this approach provides new insights into the application of prospect theory [
24]. Building upon this foundation, subsequent research has introduced value functions within prospect theory to propose intuitive fuzzy scoring functions [
25] and linguistic variable inverse prospect functions [
26], offering a more explicit representation of priority relationships in decision-making. Additionally, new numerical computation methods have been developed to address decision problems under cumulative prospect theory, optimizing utility under practical constraints [
27].
At the applied research level, scholars have extended prospect theory to explore interactions between social media and financial markets [
28]. Studies indicate that decision-makers exhibit behaviors such as reference dependence, loss aversion, and diminishing marginal utility [
29]. Loss aversion and reduced sensitivity contribute to systemic anomalies, and these psychological factors are quantifiable. Furthermore, increases in the risk–reward coefficient and loss aversion coefficient in prospect theory facilitate the evolution of game outcomes toward theoretical equilibrium [
30,
31].
Prospect theory uncovers the mechanism underlying trustworthy behaviors of practitioners in the construction business under government supervision and facilitates an understanding of the restricted rationality characteristics of practitioners from perception to decision-making process [
32]. The steady state of the government-firm game is significantly impacted by the expense of regulation, the severity of penalties, and the mechanism for third-party involvement [
33,
34].
The principles of prospect theory, including the certainty effect, reflection effect, and loss aversion, provide valuable insights into the behavior of construction industry practitioners and government regulatory actions. For practitioners, when a project progresses steadily over the long term and yields significant interim benefits, they tend to exhibit risk-averse behavior. However, in adverse situations such as cost overruns or schedule delays, practitioners are more likely to develop a risk-seeking preference, potentially resorting to opportunistic misconduct to avoid project losses. Practitioners highly value the certainty of benefits associated with compliance, as it ensures stable income and a good professional reputation. This stability incentivizes them to adopt honest strategies. Conversely, when considering dishonest actions, they may focus excessively on immediate economic gains while overlooking potential long-term risks, highlighting the significant interaction between project characteristics and practitioners’ strategic choices. Both government authorities and construction practitioners exhibit distinct risk preferences when evaluating gains and losses. Their decision-making is primarily influenced by changes in existing wealth rather than absolute final wealth, and they experience the pain of losses more acutely than the pleasure of equivalent gains. Their behavior is largely shaped by reference points. From the government’s perspective, regulatory bodies tend to adopt proactive oversight strategies to prevent economic and reputational losses. In response, practitioners are inclined to comply with regulations, demonstrating loss-averse tendencies on both sides.
Additionally, the isolation effect in prospect theory influences practitioners’ decision-making by causing them to filter out complex information and decompose problems into distinct features using a structured framework. The way regulatory policies are framed can significantly impact practitioners’ decisions, leading them to focus only on short-term, quantifiable differences while neglecting broader contextual or long-term consequences, which may result in irrational choices. Therefore, in regulatory communication, it is crucial to optimize the framing of issues and avoid overly rigid or structured expressions that might inadvertently contribute to suboptimal decision-making.
In conclusion, the construction market credit scoring system and social credit mechanism have established a solid research foundation, while emphasizing the crucial role of the government in directing and regulating corporate behavior. Additionally, the evolutionary game method has also been better applied in the government’s research regarding the construction industry to encourage corporate sustainability innovation and regulate unsafe behaviors [
16,
35,
36,
37]. Previous studies have been carried out using static research methodologies, which can merely examine behavioral outcomes, failing to delve into the dynamic evolution of practitioners’ behavior in the construction sector. Construction workers’ safety behavior will also be impacted by the interaction and competition amongst practitioners as well as the level of government regulation, incentives, and penalties. The development of the credit behavior model for practice qualification personnel significantly enriches the research on credit deficiency in the engineering and construction sectors, addressing the evident gap in current studies regarding the enhancement of individual practice qualifications. Accordingly, this paper shifted its focus from regulating businesses to regulating individual licensed personnel. It also examined the subject’s decision-making law using evolutionary game theory in conjunction with prospect theory, investigated the subject’s strategic choice in the face of uncertainty, and compensated for the evolutionary game’s shortcomings in terms of the excessively stringent requirements of limited rationality. A methodical framework was established for research on credit regulation, facilitating the exploration of credit regulation mechanisms, the dynamics of multi-agent interactions, and the establishment of virtuous cycles. Furthermore, this framework promotes self-development among practitioners in engineering and construction fields, encouraging adherence to credibility and high performance. Additionally, it also provides valuable insights for regulatory authorities’ decision-making processes.
This article distinguishes itself from the existing literature in three ways. The paper object first shifted from regulating companies to regulating individual practitioners to support individual practice certification in the industrial environment. Second, a research strategy based on prospect theory and evolutionary games was employed to conduct the article on the issue of decision-making laws. This article imaginatively integrated prospect theory to the subject decision-making behavior in the engineering and construction domains, thereby addressing the limitations of the evolutionary game theory stemming from its overly stringent assumptions of bounded rationality. It also examined the strategic decision-making of the subject under uncertainty. A design scheme of the credit regulation framework was proposed to optimize engineering construction, minimize resource wastage, and achieve efficient allocation of regulatory resources. The overall objective is to empower practitioners with good credit to achieve self-promotion and self-development, and to integrate into a virtuous cycle of growth, all while sustaining high performance and preserving their reputation.
2. Model Building
2.1. Prospect Theory
Tversky and Kahneman [
38] suggested prospect theory as a psychological improvement on anticipated utility theory. According to the notion, individuals possess a personal value reference point, and their perception of value is anchored to this reference point. Instead of considering the actual value of various strategies, people base their decisions on their perception of their worth. Under dangerous circumstances, people’s actions are impacted by intricate psychological processes and may not always adhere to utility maximization. Individual behavioral traits cannot be well explained by anticipated utility theory. As a result, this paper presented the prospect theory. The two decision-making parties based their choice of strategy on the prospect theory’s value function and decision weight function, using the value reference point as a foundation. Prospect theory states that the relative worth of the greater reference point is what individuals perceive as profit and loss, i.e.,
. The reference point of profit and loss perception
was selected based on the current regulatory research background. The following is an expression for a prospective value:
where
is the objective probability of occurrence of the event
, the weighting function
, which is monotonically increasing in the interval
. Prospect theory suggests that low probability events are usually overestimated, while high probability events are usually underestimated. Specifically, when
is small,
; in the case of a large
,
. In the field of engineering construction, it is reflected that practitioners tend to underestimate the high probability events, such as the probability of accidents, the probability of inspection, and the probability of reporting, when they have a speculative mentality. In addition, there are
,
.
The value function
represents the subjective perceived value of the decision-maker. Tversky and Kahneman [
38] proposed the value function as a power function:
.
denotes the risk attitude coefficient, which indicates the marginal decreasing degree of the perceived value of the game subject to the profit and loss, with a higher value representing a greater marginal decreasing degree.
for the loss aversion coefficient, the higher its value, the higher the sensitivity of the subject of the game to losses; if
, it represents that the subject of the game is more sensitive to losses than gains.
2.2. Problem Description and Model Assumptions
There are two types of key credit subjects in the registration stage of the engineering and construction market practice: government regulators and individual practitioners. The government represents the interests of society. Since the 18th National Congress of the Party, government departments have focused more on the coordinated development of the national economy and the social and environmental benefits brought about by healthy operation. The social benefits include improving people’s lives, generating more employment opportunities, preserving social stability, and boosting government credibility. Environmental benefits include reducing energy consumption, minimizing pollutant emissions, and fostering the growth of sectors linked to green management and operation. The government can implement policies such as project subsidies and rent concessions to encourage participating entities to choose reliable strategies and implement best practices for achieving the market’s healthy and quick development. These policies can facilitate reducing resource wastage, protect the environment, and promote economic development. Additionally, practitioners desire to increase their own utility. The conflicting objectives of both parties cannot be resolved by the regulatory body through the creation of a well-structured and well-written contract.
Practitioners’ risk preferences are shaped by a complex interplay of multiple factors, including legal and regulatory compliance risks, economic and financial risks, operational and technical risks, market competition risks, credit and reputational risks, environmental and social risks, and institutional risks [
39,
40,
41,
42]. The risks to practitioners’ choice of behavior are shown in
Table 1. The impact of these factors is assessed based on a comprehensive evaluation of both the probability of occurrence and the severity of consequences. Specifically, risks are categorized as high when the probability exceeds 50% or potential losses surpass 10% of the contract value; moderately high when the probability ranges from 30% to 50% or losses amount to 5–10% of the contract value; moderate when the probability falls between 10% and 30% or losses range from 1% to 5% of the contract value; and low when the probability is below 10% or losses remain under 1% of the contract value.
During the professional registration phase, practitioners’ decision-making is shaped by the combined influence of cognitive biases, institutional constraints, economic incentives, and industry characteristics. From a behavioral finance perspective, their decision-making mechanisms are primarily governed by cognitive biases within the framework of prospect theory, including loss aversion, risk attitude coefficients, and the isolation effect. When the combination of penalty severity () and inspection probability () results in an expected loss exceeding short-term gains, loss aversion tends to suppress dishonest behavior, while the risk attitude coefficient determines the diminishing marginal sensitivity to gains and losses. Institutional and environmental factors serve as external drivers of risk selection. When the expected benefits of strict regulation outweigh enforcement costs, governments tend to adopt proactive regulatory strategies. Moreover, industry characteristics significantly influence practitioners’ risk choices—issues such as collusive bidding, lack of information transparency, and absence of third-party oversight distort risk perceptions, leading to an adverse selection effect where dishonest actors outcompete ethical practitioners, highlighting the regulatory shortcomings in risk governance. Practitioners’ professional experience and ethical values shape their risk tolerance by affecting their ability to assess risks and their ethical judgment thresholds. A higher discount factor indicates a stronger emphasis on long-term reputation. The root cause of dishonest behavior lies in the fundamental drive to maximize individual benefits. Strict enforcement by regulatory authorities, through investigations and crackdowns, generally reduces the occurrence of dishonest practices. However, the effectiveness of such enforcement depends on the success rate of investigations, the scope and intensity of regulatory actions, and specific enforcement measures.
When regulatory intensity is insufficient, the success rate of government investigations remains low, making it difficult to effectively control the credibility of industry entrants. In the absence of regulatory intervention, some practitioners may perceive their short-term gains as outweighing expected losses, leading them to persist in dishonest behavior for additional profits. However, those who opt for dishonest strategies also bear the increased risk of engineering failures and the associated response costs. If a government investigation successfully identifies violations and the expected additional profits are not realized, individuals engaging in dishonest practices will face economic losses and reputational damage. Meanwhile, governments utilize fines collected from violators to sustain regulatory operations. In the context of credit regulation in the construction sector, when the cost of strict regulation significantly exceeds that of relaxed regulation and budget constraints exist, regulatory failure may also occur.
Long-term profits and losses are valued differently by practitioners. In this paper, the notion of the discount factor, characterized as an individual’s assessment of current period long-term profits and losses, was introduced. People are more inclined to choose short-term profits from trustworthiness when the discount factor is low, as long-term benefits are discounted to a smaller value of benefits in the current era. In contrast, when the discount factor is large, they may be more skewed toward the long-term advantages of trustworthiness, since these benefits are discounted to a higher value of benefits in the present. Given that an excessive focus on short-term gains can readily lead to breaches of trust, it is reasonable to posit that practitioners’ initial credit level is characterized by the discount factor.
Based on the above industry status quo, the following basic assumptions were hereby proposed:
- (1)
In the registration stage, in the credit supervision of practitioners in the field of engineering and construction, the supervisory department (governmental department of housing and construction)
and the practitioners are both limited rational groups. Their strategy selection is based on their own psychological perception of the value of strategy gains and losses, independent of the direct gains and losses of the strategy itself. In this paper, the perceived values of gains and losses were calculated based on prospect theory.
- (2)
The set of strategies for government subjects is {positive regulation, negative regulation} and the set of strategies for practitioner subjects is {trustworthiness, trustworthiness}. The government subject chooses the positive regulation strategy by the proportion of and the negative regulation strategy by the proportion of . Practitioner subjects choose the trustworthy strategy with the proportion of , and the trustworthy strategy with the proportion of , where and are functions of time .
- (3)
The goal of government regulatory efforts is to maximize total governmental benefits, which in this case combines quantifiable economic benefits and difficult-to-quantify social benefits. In contrast, practitioners aim to maximize their personal utility.
2.3. Model Buildings
Herein, the individual criteria were established based on the actual conditions of the registration phase for practitioners in the engineering construction industry, as detailed in
Table 2.
It is clear from the prospect theory that psychological feelings, experience, other ambiguous costs, and advantages of the final computation forge the foundation for the decision-making process. In other words, there is a psychological impression of utility. The actual value is utilized because the cost of positive or negative regulation, honest or dishonest tactics, can be precisely assessed for government departments and practitioners. This is a deterministic expense free from perceptual bias. Since it is challenging to evaluate distant accident costs and other reputation damage that are tied to the subject’s perception, the benefit matrix adopts the prospective value. Presumably, there is .
In addition, the discount factor () for setting practitioners is a function of the time preference of the subject of interest and can be considered as a characterization of the initial credit level. For the government, the discount factor is 1. For individuals, a greater emphasis on short-term gains and losses results in a lower discounted value of long-term gains and losses in the current period, thereby lowering the initial credit level.
The matrix of perceived benefits for both sides of the behavioral evolution game of practitioners in engineering and construction in the registration stage was hereby constructed based on the aforementioned assumptions and discussions, as indicated in
Table 3.
In the case of a positive regulatory strategy adopted by a government department, for example, when a practitioner adopts a trustworthy strategy, the perceived benefit to the government is the psychological perceived benefit of positive government regulation, , with the cost of the regulatory process denoted by , and the perceived benefit to the practitioner recorded as . When the practitioner adopts a trustworthy strategy, the perceived benefit to the government is divided into three parts, including the cost of positive regulation, , the perceived benefit of the successful case of an investigation and prosecution, . The perceived benefit of the practitioner is divided into four parts, including the cost of the bad faith strategy , the perceived benefit of successful investigation by the government , the perceived benefit of unsuccessful investigation by the government , and the perceived benefit of unsuccessful investigation by the government and a safety incident .
Based on the perceived returns of the strategy portfolios in
Table 3, the expected prospective value of active supervision and management of the government sector, negative supervision, and the average expected prospective value can be derived:
The expected prospective value of a practitioner’s trustworthiness, the prospective value of a breach of trustworthiness, and the average expected prospective value of a practitioner’s trustworthiness can be obtained, respectively:
Based on the Malthusian equations, the following equations for the replication dynamics are obtained:
Prospect theory is an effective tool for portraying the cognition and decision-making of limited rational actors in uncertain situations. When the probability of the government department choosing positive regulation is 1, the social benefit obtained by the government department is ; when adopting a negative regulation strategy, the social benefit obtained is 0. Therefore, the prospect value of is .
When the practitioner chooses the bad faith strategy, the probability of successful government investigation is and a penalty is imposed. When the practitioner chooses a trustworthy strategy, the penalty is 0. Thus, there are , and .
The same applies to the foreground values of and . Substituting the values of the profit and loss prospects into (5) and (6), respectively, the replication dynamic equations for the two sides of the game choosing an active strategy can be obtained:
From Equation (6), , and (denoted as ) are the roots of . According to the stability principle, when ,, is ESS (Evolutionary Stability Solution), i.e., the government can achieve local stability by choosing active regulation. When , , at this time for all are stable; when , meets the necessary conditions and is the evolutionary stability point; when , meets the necessary conditions and is the evolutionary stability point. Similarly, for the practitioner subject, , , and (denoted as ) are the roots of . When is , it is a stable state for all ; when is , it satisfies the necessary conditions and is an evolutionary stable point; when is , it satisfies the necessary conditions and is an evolutionary stable point.
3. Evolutionary Stability Analysis
Two-dimensional nonlinear replicated dynamical systems for government agencies and practitioners are derived from the aforementioned analysis.
There are five equilibrium points in the game between the two types of subjects, government departments and practitioners:
,
,
,
, and
; where:
According to the Jacobi matrix stability judgment condition, when
, and
, it is a stable point (ESS). The Jacobi matrix of this game system is shown in
Table 4. To ensure the conciseness of the presentation, let the eigenvalues of
satisfy:
Based on the above expressions of each equilibrium point corresponding to Jacobi matrix, the eigenvalues of the five equilibrium points corresponding to Jacobi matrix can be obtained, as shown in
Table 5. Given that practitioners’ malpractice in real life is driven by the fact that their perceived short-term profit exceeds their perceived long-term risk of accidents, it is assumed that
. In the case of
and
, the stability of each equilibrium point can be discussed in six scenarios according to the range of values of each parameter in the expression, as shown in
Table 6. For the convenience of representation,
is
,
is
,
is
,
is
.
Scenario 1-1: When the conditions
and
are satisfied, i.e., the benefit of positive regulation by the government department is smaller than that of negative regulation, and the benefit of trustworthiness of the practitioners is smaller than that of bad faith under positive regulation. As shown in
Table 6, only the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix corresponding to
are all less than 0, indicating an evolutionary stability point. At this point, corresponding to the strategy combination of (negative regulation, breach of trust), the practitioners’ credit level is low, and market operations face significant risks. This scenario is clearly undesirable in the context of construction market credit regulation.
Scenario 1-2: When the conditions
and
are satisfied, i.e., the benefit of positive regulation by government departments is smaller than that of negative regulation, and the benefit of trustworthiness of practitioners is larger than that of dishonesty in the case of positive regulation. As shown in
Table 6, only
represents the evolutionary stability point, the practitioners’ credit level is low, the market operation entails higher risks. This scenario should be avoided in construction market credit regulation.
Scenario 2-1: When the conditions
and
are satisfied, i.e., when practitioners choose trustworthy strategies, the benefit of positive regulation from the government department is smaller than that of negative regulation. Meanwhile, when practitioners choose trustworthy strategies, the benefit of positive regulation from the government department is higher, and the benefit of trustworthy practitioners is smaller than that of trustworthy practitioners. As shown in
Table 6, only the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix corresponding to
are all less than 0, indicating an evolutionary stability point. At this time, corresponding to the strategy combination of (positive regulation, breach of trust), the practitioners’ credit level is low, and the effect of regulation cannot be realized. Given that practitioners can still reap greater benefits from breach of trust strategies despite high levels of supervision, such behavior remains an optimal choice. This scenario is undesirable and should be avoided in the credit supervision of the construction market.
Scenario 2-2: When the conditions
and
are satisfied, i.e., when the practitioners’ compliance level is higher, the benefit of active regulation by the government department is smaller than that of negative regulation. Conversely, when the practitioners’ compliance level is lower, the benefit of active regulation by the government department is higher. Additionally, the benefit of compliance for practitioners under active regulation exceeds that associated with breach of trust. As shown in
Table 6, only the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix corresponding to
are all less than 0, indicating an evolutionary stable point. This suggests that the
proportion of regulators among practitioners chooses the trustworthy strategy and the regulatory effect is reflected.
Scenario 3-1: When the conditions
and
are satisfied, i.e., the benefit of positive regulation by government departments is greater than that of negative regulation, while the benefit of trustworthy strategies by practitioners is less than that of untrustworthy strategies. As shown in
Table 6, only the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix corresponding to
are all less than 0, indicating an evolutionary stable point. At this point, corresponding to the strategy combination of (active regulation and breach of trust), the practitioners’ credit level is low, and the regulatory effect cannot be realized. For practitioners, the breach of trust strategy remains optimal and yields higher benefits, even under stringent supervision. This scenario is undesirable and should be mitigated in construction market credit regulation.
Scenario 3-2: When the conditions
and
are satisfied, i.e., the benefit of positive regulation by government departments is greater than that of negative regulation, while the benefit of trustworthiness by practitioners in the case of positive regulation is greater than that under untrustworthy strategies. As shown in
Table 6, only the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix corresponding to
are all less than 0, indicating an evolutionary stable point. At this point, the strategy combination corresponding to (active regulation and trustworthiness) corresponds to a high level of practitioner creditworthiness, while also necessitating the constraints imposed by governmental regulation.
The evolutionary game analysis reveals the following stability points: for scenarios 1-1, 2-1, 2-2, and 3-1, the stability points are
,
,
, and
, respectively (
Figure 1). In these scenarios, practitioners opt for breach of trust, and government regulation is highly ineffective. For scenario 3-2, the stability point is
, where practitioners partially choose to breach trust, resulting in a moderate level of group compliance with trustworthiness. For scenario 1-2, the stability point is
, indicating that active government regulation is required to achieve a high level of practitioner creditworthiness.
As a result, the credit regulation of practitioners in the registration stage was hereby divided into three stages: the ineffective stage, the effective stage, and the efficient stage. The ineffective stage corresponds to scenarios 1-1, 1-2, 2-1, and 3-1, featuring extremely low regulatory effect of government departments, higher perceived benefits of practitioners’ credit failure strategies, and frequent malpractice. It is necessary to improve the perceived benefits of active regulation by government departments through in-depth institutional reform, change in work methods, and improvement of work capacity. The effective stage corresponds to scenario 2-2, where the government department’s strategy choice is adjusted according to the practitioners’ trustworthiness level. The eventual evolutionary outcome is that some practitioners will adopt trustworthy strategies, while malpractice remains extant. The binary system is in a dynamic game process. The efficient stage of government regulation is promoted through system reform measures and the effective adjustment of relevant parameters on this basis. The efficient stage corresponds to scenario 3-2, characterized by higher perceived benefits of practitioners’ trustworthiness and a significant regulatory impact from the government sector, driving the system’s evolution toward a positive outcome.
In the theoretical analysis, when the parameters satisfy conditions of and , the two-party evolutionary game system of government regulators and practitioners reaches a (1,1) stable state. This is also the optimal strategy of the system and is the construction goal of the credit system in engineering construction. As a limited rational individual, the game subject cannot maximize the use of existing information to support decision-making, presenting subjective differences in terms of profit and loss reference points, risk preferences, etc., which can easily lead to systematic bias in their behaviors.
When the actual project is constructed, the line regulator subject’s low perceived gain of social benefit causes , making it difficult to satisfy the condition of ; while the practitioner tends to underestimate the large probability event, which leads to , the high perceived gain of governmental departmental fines ; and the practitioner overestimates the small probability event that the governmental regulator’s daily supervision does not find malpractice, which leads to . Thus, while the regulator actually controls the and conditions, it cannot fully guarantee the satisfaction of the and stability conditions in the value perception condition due to subjects’ limited rationality and risk preferences. As a result, various types of malpractices such as qualification lending persist, and the system evolves from scenario 3-2 to scenarios 1-1 and 2-1.
From the viewpoint of the external environment, the rules of the construction market have not yet been perfected. Information asymmetry leads to inconsistent information holdings and difficulty in fully guaranteeing the authenticity of each subject during transactions in the construction market. This may further induce various types of opportunistic behaviors. Due to the extended project cycle and substantial capital flow, the additional benefits from breach of trust behavior are high, making it difficult to meet the conditions of practitioners’ behavioral parameters.